-
1
-
-
33947362165
-
-
For a brief overview of commonly identified sources of rising health care expenditures, see (attributing rising expenditures to the stimulation of demand through third-party payment, rising provider compensation, the aging of the American population, malpractice litigation, and (especially) the growth of expensive new technologies)
-
For a brief overview of commonly identified sources of rising health care expenditures, see Henry J. Aaron, Serious and Unstable Condition 38-53 (1991) (attributing rising expenditures to the stimulation of demand through third-party payment, rising provider compensation, the aging of the American population, malpractice litigation, and (especially) the growth of expensive new technologies).
-
(1991)
Serious and Unstable Condition
, pp. 38-53
-
-
Aaron, H.J.1
-
2
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) in American Health Care
-
7, (Autumn)
-
Clark C. Havighurst & Barak D. Richman, Distributive Injustice(s) in American Health Care, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 7, 24 (Autumn 2006).
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 24
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
4
-
-
0347972449
-
FTC v. Tenet Healthcare Corp
-
See 1045, (8th Cir.)
-
See FTC v. Tenet Healthcare Corp., 186 F.3d 1045, 1047 (8th Cir. 1999);
-
(1999)
F.3d
, vol.186
, pp. 1047
-
-
-
5
-
-
33947389785
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp
-
260, (8th Cir.)
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d 260, 273 (8th Cir. 1995);
-
(1995)
F.3d
, vol.69
, pp. 273
-
-
-
6
-
-
33947398551
-
California v. Sutter Health Sys
-
1057, (N.D. Cal.) aff'd, 130 F. Supp. 2d 1109 (N.D. Cal. 2001)
-
California v. Sutter Health Sys., 84 F. Supp. 2d 1057, 1085 (N.D. Cal. 2000), aff'd, 130 F. Supp. 2d 1109 (N.D. Cal. 2001);
-
(2000)
F. Supp. 2d
, vol.84
, pp. 1085
-
-
-
7
-
-
33947377619
-
United States v. Long Island Jewish Med. Ctr
-
121, (E.D.N.Y.)
-
United States v. Long Island Jewish Med. Ctr., 983 F. Supp. 121, 149 (E.D.N.Y. 1997);
-
(1997)
F. Supp.
, vol.983
, pp. 149
-
-
-
8
-
-
33947412468
-
FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp
-
1285, (W.D. Mich.) aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997) (unpublished table decision)
-
FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1302-03 (W.D. Mich. 1996), aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997) (unpublished table decision);
-
(1996)
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1302-1303
-
-
-
9
-
-
33947376631
-
United States v. Mercy Health Servs
-
968, (N.D. Iowa) vacated as moot, 107 F.3d 632 (8th Cir. 1997)
-
United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995), vacated as moot, 107 F.3d 632 (8th Cir. 1997);
-
(1995)
F. Supp.
, vol.902
, pp. 989
-
-
-
10
-
-
33947421392
-
In re Adventist Health Sys
-
224
-
In re Adventist Health Sys., 117 F.T.C. 224, 224 (1994).
-
(1994)
F.T.C.
, vol.117
, pp. 224
-
-
-
11
-
-
0036518043
-
Whither Antitrust? The Uncertain Future of Competition Law in Health Care
-
Mar.-Apr
-
Thomas L. Greaney, Whither Antitrust? The Uncertain Future of Competition Law in Health Care, Health Aff., Mar.-Apr. 2002, at 185.
-
(2002)
Health Aff.
, pp. 185
-
-
Greaney, T.L.1
-
12
-
-
33947414576
-
-
See infra
-
See infra Part II.
-
, Issue.PART II
-
-
-
13
-
-
33947403297
-
Butterworth Health Corp
-
Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. at 1302.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1302
-
-
-
14
-
-
33947356373
-
-
E.g., Judge Posner, also reiterated that nonprofits are likely to pose greater danger to competition than for-profits, adding "[t]he ideology of nonprofit enterprise is cooperative rather than competitive. If the managers of nonprofit enterprises are less likely to strain after that last penny of profit, they may be less prone to engage in profit-maximizing collusion but by the same token less prone to engage in profit-maximizing competition" (7th Cir.)
-
E.g., Judge Posner, infra note 16;
-
-
-
-
15
-
-
33947368772
-
National Collegiate Athletic Ass'nv. Board of Regents
-
Judge Tjoflat
-
Judge Tjoflat, infra note 17;
-
(1984)
U.S.
, vol.468
, Issue.2
, pp. 100
-
-
-
16
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
Professors
-
Professors Dranove & Ludwick, infra note 63.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 87
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
19
-
-
33947371013
-
-
See infra
-
See infra Part II.
-
, Issue.PART II
-
-
-
20
-
-
33947388098
-
-
See infra
-
See infra Part III.
-
, Issue.PART III
-
-
-
21
-
-
33947361719
-
-
See infra
-
See infra Part IV.
-
, Issue.PART IV
-
-
-
22
-
-
33947383166
-
Hosp. Corp. of Am. v. FTC
-
1381, (7th Cir.) (citations omitted)
-
Hosp. Corp. of Am. v. FTC, 807 F.2d 1381, 1390 (7th Cir. 1986) (citations omitted).
-
(1986)
F.2d
, vol.807
, pp. 1390
-
-
-
23
-
-
33947383166
-
Hosp. Corp. of Am. v. FTC
-
1381, (7th Cir.) (citations omitted)
-
Id. at 1391.
-
(1986)
F.2d
, vol.807
, pp. 1391
-
-
-
24
-
-
33947393753
-
United States v. Rockford Mem'l Corp
-
1278, (7th Cir.)
-
United States v. Rockford Mem'l Corp., 898 F.2d 1278,1285 (7th Cir. 1990).
-
(1990)
F.2d
, vol.898
, pp. 1285
-
-
-
25
-
-
33947393753
-
United States v. Rockford Mem'l Corp
-
Judge Posner also reiterated that nonprofits are likely to pose greater danger to competition than for-profits, adding "[t]he ideology of nonprofit enterprise is cooperative rather than competitive. If the managers of nonprofit enterprises are less likely to strain after that last penny of profit, they may be less prone to engage in profit-maximizing collusion but by the same token less prone to engage in profit-maximizing competition" (7th Cir.)
-
Judge Posner also reiterated that nonprofits are likely to pose greater danger to competition than for-profits, adding "[t]he ideology of nonprofit enterprise is cooperative rather than competitive. If the managers of nonprofit enterprises are less likely to strain after that last penny of profit, they may be less prone to engage in profit-maximizing collusion but by the same token less prone to engage in profit-maximizing competition." Id.
-
(1990)
F.2d
, vol.898
, pp. 1285
-
-
-
26
-
-
33947404945
-
FTC v. Univ. Health, Inc
-
1206, (11th Cir.)
-
FTC v. Univ. Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1224 (11th Cir. 1991).
-
(1991)
F.2d
, vol.938
, pp. 1224
-
-
-
27
-
-
33947368772
-
National Collegiate Athletic Ass'nv. Board of Regents
-
In addition, Judge Tjoflat invoked 85, to conclude that "the Supreme Court has rejected the notion that nonprofit corporations act under such a different set of incentives than for-profit corporations that they are entitled to an implicit exemption from the antitrust laws"
-
In addition, Judge Tjoflat invoked National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 100 n.2 (1984), to conclude that "the Supreme Court has rejected the notion that nonprofit corporations act under such a different set of incentives than for-profit corporations that they are entitled to an implicit exemption from the antitrust laws."
-
(1984)
U.S.
, vol.468
, Issue.2
, pp. 100
-
-
-
28
-
-
33947404945
-
Univ. Health
-
Univ. Health, 938 F.2d at 1224.
-
F.2d
, vol.938
, pp. 1224
-
-
-
29
-
-
33947365205
-
The Impact of Tax-Exempt Status: The Supply-Side Subsidies
-
Richard Schmalbeck observes in this volume that nonprofit hospitals enjoy a similar generosity from tax courts and IRS rulings. 121, (Autumn)
-
Richard Schmalbeck observes in this volume that nonprofit hospitals enjoy a similar generosity from tax courts and IRS rulings. Richard L. Schmalbeck, The Impact of Tax-Exempt Status: The Supply-Side Subsidies, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 121, 124-27 (Autumn 2006).
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 124-127
-
-
Schmalbeck, R.L.1
-
30
-
-
33947414165
-
-
(W.D. Va.) aff'd, 892 F.2d 1042 (4th Cir. 1989) (unpublished table decision)
-
707 F. Supp. 840 (W.D. Va. 1989), aff'd, 892 F.2d 1042 (4th Cir. 1989) (unpublished table decision).
-
(1989)
F. Supp.
, vol.707
, pp. 840
-
-
-
31
-
-
33947418213
-
-
(W.D. Va.) aff'd, 892 F.2d 1042 (4th Cir. 1989) (unpublished table decision)
-
Id at 849.
-
(1989)
F. Supp.
, vol.707
, pp. 849
-
-
-
32
-
-
33947418213
-
-
(W.D. Va.) aff'd, 892 F.2d 1042 (4th Cir. 1989) (unpublished table decision)
-
Id.
-
(1989)
F. Supp.
, vol.707
, pp. 849
-
-
-
33
-
-
33947373563
-
-
(W.D. Va.) aff'd, 892 F.2d 1042 (4th Cir. 1989) (unpublished table decision)
-
See id. at 847-48.
-
(1989)
F. Supp.
, vol.707
, pp. 847-848
-
-
-
34
-
-
33947375315
-
United States v. Carilion Health Sys., No. 89-2625
-
See 1989 WL 157282 (4th Cir. Nov. 29)
-
See United States v. Carilion Health Sys., No. 89-2625, 1989 WL 157282 (4th Cir. Nov. 29, 1989).
-
(1989)
-
-
-
35
-
-
33947388945
-
-
(W.D. Mo.) aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995)
-
911 F. Supp. 1213 (W.D. Mo. 1995), aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995).
-
(1995)
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1213
-
-
-
36
-
-
33947378468
-
-
Under the FTC's alternative market definitions, the proposed merger would create a market with a Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) of between 2288 and 4356. (W.D. Mo.) aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995)
-
Under the FTC's alternative market definitions, the proposed merger would create a market with a Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) of between 2288 and 4356. Id at 1222.
-
(1995)
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1222
-
-
-
37
-
-
33947378468
-
-
The hospitals argued that the merger would result in an HHI between 1322 and 1624. (W.D. Mo.) aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995)
-
The hospitals argued that the merger would result in an HHI between 1322 and 1624. Id.
-
(1995)
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1222
-
-
-
38
-
-
85069366780
-
-
Under the Department of Justice's merger guidelines, a market is not "highly concentrated" until the HHI reaches 1800. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 41,552 (Sept. 10). available at
-
Under the Department of Justice's merger guidelines, a market is not "highly concentrated" until the HHI reaches 1800. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552 41,558 (Sept. 10, 1992), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/ atr/public/guidelines/horiz_book/hmg1.html.
-
(1992)
Fed. Reg.
, vol.57
-
-
-
39
-
-
33947363474
-
Freeman Hosp
-
(citations omitted)
-
Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. at 1222 (citations omitted).
-
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1222
-
-
-
40
-
-
33947363474
-
Freeman Hosp
-
(citations omitted)
-
Id. at 1227.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1227
-
-
-
41
-
-
33947389785
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp
-
See (8th Cir.)
-
See FTC v. Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995).
-
(1995)
F. 3d
, vol.69
, pp. 260
-
-
-
42
-
-
33947389785
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp
-
The court briefly confirmed that the hospitals' nonprofit status did not defeat the FTC's jurisdiction in the case See. (8th Cir.)
-
The court briefly confirmed that the hospitals' nonprofit status did not defeat the FTC's jurisdiction in the case. Id at 266-67.
-
(1995)
F. 3d
, vol.69
, pp. 266-267
-
-
-
43
-
-
20644460331
-
Korematsu v. United States
-
214, (Jackson, J., dissenting)
-
Korematsu v. United States, 323 U.S. 214, 246 (1944) (Jackson, J., dissenting).
-
(1944)
U.S.
, vol.323
, pp. 246
-
-
-
44
-
-
33947376631
-
-
It appears that the Freeman opinion did not capture widespread attention. In United States v. Mercy Health Services, another challenge to a proposed merger of two nonprofit hospitals, the court wrote, "The hospitals have also asserted as a defense their non-profit status and procompetitive intent. The hospitals cite United States v. Carilion Health for the proposition that the non-profit status of the hospitals can be considered in determining whether the hospitals would act in an anticompetitive manner. The government points out, this is a questionable legal proposition. No other courts have explicitly adopted this theory of defense." 968, (N.D. Iowa) (citation abridged), vacating as moot 107 F.3d 632 (8th Cir. 1997)
-
It appears that the Freeman opinion did not capture widespread attention. In United States v. Mercy Health Services, another challenge to a proposed merger of two nonprofit hospitals, the court wrote, "The hospitals have also asserted as a defense their non-profit status and procompetitive intent. The hospitals cite United States v. Carilion Health for the proposition that the non-profit status of the hospitals can be considered in determining whether the hospitals would act in an anticompetitive manner. The government points out, this is a questionable legal proposition. No other courts have explicitly adopted this theory of defense." 902 F. Supp 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995) (citation abridged), vacating as moot 107 F.3d 632 (8th Cir. 1997).
-
(1995)
F. Supp
, vol.902
, pp. 989
-
-
-
45
-
-
33947434189
-
-
(W.D. Mich.) aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997) (unpublished table decision)
-
946 F. Supp. 1285 (W.D. Mich. 1996), aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997) (unpublished table decision).
-
(1996)
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1285
-
-
-
46
-
-
33947422221
-
-
(W.D. Mich.) aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997) (unpublished table decision)
-
Id. at 1294.
-
(1996)
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1294
-
-
-
47
-
-
33947382775
-
-
For general acute inpatient care, the post-merger HHI would be between 2767 and 4521, reflecting a gain of 1064 to 1889 points as a result of the merger. For primary inpatient care, the post-merger HHI would range from 4506 to 5079, reflecting a gain of 1675 to 2001 points. The court concluded that "the proposed merger would result in a significant increase in the concentration of power in two relevant markets, and produce an entity controlling an undue percentage share of each of those markets." (W.D. Mich.) aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997) (unpublished table decision)
-
For general acute inpatient care, the post-merger HHI would be between 2767 and 4521, reflecting a gain of 1064 to 1889 points as a result of the merger. For primary inpatient care, the post-merger HHI would range from 4506 to 5079, reflecting a gain of 1675 to 2001 points. The court concluded that "the proposed merger would result in a significant increase in the concentration of power in two relevant markets, and produce an entity controlling an undue percentage share of each of those markets." Id.
-
(1996)
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1249
-
-
-
48
-
-
85069366780
-
-
For concentration standards under the Department of Justice's merger guidelines (Sept. 10) available at
-
For concentration standards under the Department of Justice's merger guidelines, see supra note 25.
-
(1992)
Fed. Reg.
, vol.57
-
-
-
49
-
-
33947389786
-
Butterworth
-
Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1296.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1296
-
-
-
50
-
-
33947389786
-
Butterworth
-
Id.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1296
-
-
-
51
-
-
33947378468
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp
-
(citing 1213, (W.D. Mo.) aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995))
-
(citing FTC v. Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. 1213, 1222 (W.D. Mo. 1995), aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995)).
-
(1995)
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1222
-
-
-
52
-
-
33947389786
-
Butterworth
-
Id.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1296
-
-
-
53
-
-
33947403297
-
Butterworth
-
1297
-
Id. at 1297, 1302.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1302
-
-
-
54
-
-
33947432153
-
Butterworth
-
In addition, the court gave significant weight to a "Community Commitment" that the hospitals signed, which pledged to freeze certain prices, limit profit margins, and maintain a commitment to serve the medically needy
-
In addition, the court gave significant weight to a "Community Commitment" that the hospitals signed, which pledged to freeze certain prices, limit profit margins, and maintain a commitment to serve the medically needy. Id. at 1298.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1298
-
-
-
55
-
-
33947432153
-
Butterworth
-
The document, which the FTC regarded as "unenforceable, illusory, or inadequate," was designed "to assuage any purchaser concerns and to reiterate [the hospitals'] strong conviction that the purpose and intent of the transaction is to reduce costs." (alteration in original)
-
The document, which the FTC regarded as "unenforceable, illusory, or inadequate," was designed "to assuage any purchaser concerns and to reiterate [the hospitals'] strong conviction that the purpose and intent of the transaction is to reduce costs." Id. (alteration in original).
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1298
-
-
-
56
-
-
33947376198
-
FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp
-
No. 96-2440, 1997 WL 420543, at *3 (6th Cir. July 8)
-
FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp., No. 96-2440, 1997 WL 420543, at *3 (6th Cir. July 8, 1997).
-
(1997)
-
-
-
57
-
-
0036518043
-
Whither Antitrust? The Uncertain Future of Competition Law in Health Care
-
Mar.-Apr
-
Greaney, supra note 5, at 188.
-
(2002)
Health Aff.
, pp. 188
-
-
Greaney, T.L.1
-
58
-
-
33745695972
-
The Application of Antitrust Doctrine to the Healthcare Industry: The Interweaving of Empirical and Normative Issues
-
91, Though academic defenders of Butterworth were fewer in number, some did weigh in, including one who praised the court for using expert testimony and empirical evidence to "reconsider[] old presumptions in the light of new evidence"
-
James F. Blumstein, The Application of Antitrust Doctrine to the Healthcare Industry: The Interweaving of Empirical and Normative Issues, 31 Ind. L. Rev. 91, 117 (1998). Though academic defenders of Butterworth were fewer in number, some did weigh in, including one who praised the court for using expert testimony and empirical evidence to "reconsider[] old presumptions in the light of new evidence."
-
(1998)
Ind. L. Rev.
, vol.31
, pp. 117
-
-
Blumstein, G.F.1
-
59
-
-
33745695965
-
Presumptions, Damn Presumptions and Economic Theory: The Role of Empirical Evidence in Hospital Merger Analysis
-
125
-
Michael S. Jacobs, Presumptions, Damn Presumptions and Economic Theory: The Role of Empirical Evidence in Hospital Merger Analysis, 31 Ind. L. Rev. 125, 142 (1998).
-
(1998)
Ind. L. Rev.
, vol.31
, pp. 142
-
-
Jacobs, M.S.1
-
60
-
-
33947403297
-
-
946 F. Supp. at 1302.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1302
-
-
-
61
-
-
33947389785
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp
-
260, (8th Cir.) (alteration and omissions in original) (quoting from the district court's oral denial of the temporary restraining order)
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d 260, 263 (8th Cir. 1995) (alteration and omissions in original) (quoting from the district court's oral denial of the temporary restraining order).
-
(1995)
F.3d
, vol.69
, pp. 263
-
-
-
62
-
-
33947416290
-
-
Federal Trade Comm'n & U.S. Dep't of Justice, ch. 4, at 1 available at
-
Federal Trade Comm'n & U.S. Dep't of Justice, Improving Health Care: A Dose of Competition, ch. 4, at 1 (2004), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/health_care/204694.pdf, at 165.
-
(2004)
Improving Health Care: A Dose of Competition
, pp. 165
-
-
-
63
-
-
59449083919
-
Protecting Competition and Consumers: A Conversation with Timothy J. Muris
-
See, e.g., Nov.-Dec. at 101, (quoting the former Chairman of the Federal Trade Commission as saying, "In hospital merger cases, the government is zero for the last seven. I don't know the specifics of every case, but what's striking is the zero. I can certainly accept the idea that the government should not have won them all. But it seems very unlikely the government should have lost them all")
-
See, e.g., William M. Sage, Protecting Competition and Consumers: A Conversation with Timothy J. Muris, Health Aff., Nov.-Dec. 2003, at 101, 103 (quoting the former Chairman of the Federal Trade Commission as saying, "In hospital merger cases, the government is zero for the last seven. I don't know the specifics of every case, but what's striking is the zero. I can certainly accept the idea that the government should not have won them all. But it seems very unlikely the government should have lost them all").
-
(2003)
Health Aff.
, pp. 103
-
-
Sage, W.M.1
-
64
-
-
0036518043
-
Whither Antitrust? The Uncertain Future of Competition Law in Health Care
-
Mar.-Apr
-
See Greaney, supra note 5, at 193.
-
(2002)
Health Aff.
, pp. 193
-
-
Greaney, T.L.1
-
65
-
-
33947432533
-
-
See Complaint, In re Evanston Northwest Healthcare Corp., No. 9315 (Fed. Trade Comm'n Feb. 10), available at
-
See Complaint, In re Evanston Northwest Healthcare Corp., No. 9315 (Fed. Trade Comm'n Feb. 10, 2004), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/ 0110234/040210emhcomplaint.pdf;
-
(2004)
-
-
-
66
-
-
33947394548
-
-
Federal Trade Comm'n, Evanston Northwestern Healthcare Corp. and ENH Medical Group, Inc., (last visited May 9) (showing all actions taken in the case)
-
Federal Trade Comm'n, Evanston Northwestern Healthcare Corp. and ENH Medical Group, Inc., http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9315/index.htm (last visited May 9, 2006) (showing all actions taken in the case).
-
(2006)
-
-
-
67
-
-
33947360423
-
-
In re Evanston Northwestern Healthcare Corp., No. 9315, (Fed. Trade Comm'n Oct. 20), (ALJ initial decision)
-
In re Evanston Northwestern Healthcare Corp., No. 9315, at 120-22 (Fed. Trade Comm'n Oct. 20, 2005) (ALJ initial decision), http://www.ftc.gov/ os/adjpro/d9315/051020initialdecision.pdf.
-
(2005)
, pp. 120-122
-
-
-
68
-
-
33947418629
-
FTC ALJ Finds That Evanston Hospital Merger Violated Antitrust Law and Orders Divestiture
-
(Oct. 28)
-
Michael R. Bissegger, FTC ALJ Finds That Evanston Hospital Merger Violated Antitrust Law and Orders Divestiture (Oct. 28, 2005), http://www.ebglaw.com/article_1198.html.
-
(2005)
-
-
Bissegger, M.R.1
-
69
-
-
33947418629
-
FTC ALJ Finds That Evanston Hospital Merger Violated Antitrust Law and Orders Divestiture
-
(Oct. 28)
-
Id.
-
(2005)
-
-
Bissegger, M.R.1
-
70
-
-
33947390571
-
-
The court in Carilion relied on expert testimony to arrive at two key factual findings that favored the defendants. First, the court concluded, "as a general rule hospital rates are lower, the fewer the number of hospitals in an area" - in other words, nonprofit market concentration is correlated with lower prices
-
The court in Carilion relied on expert testimony to arrive at two key factual findings that favored the defendants. First, the court concluded, "as a general rule hospital rates are lower, the fewer the number of hospitals in an area" - in other words, nonprofit market concentration is correlated with lower prices. 707 F. Supp. at 846.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.707
, pp. 846
-
-
-
71
-
-
33947368771
-
-
And second, "charitable, nonprofit hospitals tend to charge lower rates than for-profit hospitals," suggesting that nonprofits do not utilize market power like for-profits
-
And second, "charitable, nonprofit hospitals tend to charge lower rates than for-profit hospitals," suggesting that nonprofits do not utilize market power like for-profits. Id.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.707
, pp. 846
-
-
-
72
-
-
33947368771
-
-
The court offered little analysis explaining how it arrived at these conclusions but mentioned in a footnote that the FTC's expert witness, who predicted that the merger would increase prices, "did not explain the basis of his findings to the court's satisfaction," and that the defendant's witness "raised serious questions about [the FTC's] method of analysis."
-
The court offered little analysis explaining how it arrived at these conclusions but mentioned in a footnote that the FTC's expert witness, who predicted that the merger would increase prices, "did not explain the basis of his findings to the court's satisfaction," and that the defendant's witness "raised serious questions about [the FTC's] method of analysis." Id. at 846 n.6.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.707
, Issue.6
, pp. 846
-
-
-
73
-
-
33947359185
-
FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp
-
The defendants' expert witness, David Eisenstadt, was also employed by the Butterworth defendants. See 1285, (W.D. Mich.) aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997)
-
The defendants' expert witness, David Eisenstadt, was also employed by the Butterworth defendants. See FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285,1290 (W.D. Mich. 1996), aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997).
-
(1996)
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1290
-
-
-
74
-
-
33947378468
-
FTC v. Freeman Hosp
-
In Freeman, the court dedicated slightly more of its opinion to exploring the nature and economic effects of nonprofits and rested its analysis chiefly on a published article by William Lynk, who also served as the defendants' chief expert witness. See 1213, (W.D. Mo.) aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995)
-
In Freeman, the court dedicated slightly more of its opinion to exploring the nature and economic effects of nonprofits and rested its analysis chiefly on a published article by William Lynk, who also served as the defendants' chief expert witness. See FTC v. Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. 1213, 1222 (W.D. Mo. 1995), aff'd, 69 F.3d 260 (8th Cir. 1995)
-
(1995)
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1222
-
-
-
75
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
(citing 363, [hereinafter Lynk, Property Rights]). The court drew upon the article to support the proposition, "if a nonprofit organization is controlled by the very people who depend on it for service, there is no rational economic incentive for such an organization to raise its prices to the monopoly level even if it has the power to do so"
-
(citing William J. Lynk, Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis, 39 Antitrust Bull. 363, 377 (1994) [hereinafter Lynk, Property Rights]). The court drew upon the article to support the proposition, "if a nonprofit organization is controlled by the very people who depend on it for service, there is no rational economic incentive for such an organization to raise its prices to the monopoly level even if it has the power to do so."
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 377
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
76
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
(citing 363, [hereinafter Lynk, Property Rights]) Id
-
Id.;
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 377
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
77
-
-
33947363474
-
Freeman Hosp
-
see also (citations omitted). and accompanying text. It then examined "who controls the hospitals" and, after revealing that twelve of the Board's eighteen members were owners, employees, or retirees of local businesses, concluded, "the vast majority of the combined Board of Trustees is comprised of persons who indirectly represent the interests of hospital consumers."
-
see also supra note 26 and accompanying text. It then examined "who controls the hospitals" and, after revealing that twelve of the Board's eighteen members were owners, employees, or retirees of local businesses, concluded, "the vast majority of the combined Board of Trustees is comprised of persons who indirectly represent the interests of hospital consumers."
-
F. Supp.
, vol.911
, pp. 1222
-
-
-
78
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
Id at 1222-23.
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 1222-1223
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
79
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
Consequently, the court reasoned, "it would not be in these individual Board member[s'] best economic interest to permit prices to be raised beyond a normal competitive level"
-
Consequently, the court reasoned, "it would not be in these individual Board member[s'] best economic interest to permit prices to be raised beyond a normal competitive level." Id at 1223;
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 1223
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
80
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
see also (reiterating the same conclusion)
-
see also id. at 1227 (reiterating the same conclusion).
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 1227
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
81
-
-
33947419454
-
-
The Butterworth opinion engaged in a more empirical analysis to determine how nonprofits set prices. Similar to the court in Freeman, it began by citing another Lynk article, which concluded from an empirical study of California hospital markets that "on balance increased nonprofit market share is associated with lower, not higher, prices"
-
The Butterworth opinion engaged in a more empirical analysis to determine how nonprofits set prices. Similar to the court in Freeman, it began by citing another Lynk article, which concluded from an empirical study of California hospital markets that "on balance increased nonprofit market share is associated with lower, not higher, prices." 946 F. Supp. at 1295
-
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1295
-
-
-
82
-
-
84937297642
-
Nonprofit Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
(quoting 437, [hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]). The court then accepted expert testimony from Lynk, who was also an expert witness for the Butterworth defendants, that analyzed the Grand Rapids hospital market that included the merging parties. Lynk "concluded that in Michigan, too, higher hospital concentration is associated with lower nonprofit hospital prices"
-
(quoting William J. Lynk, Nonprofit Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power, 38 J.L. & Econ. 437, 459 (1995) [hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]). The court then accepted expert testimony from Lynk, who was also an expert witness for the Butterworth defendants, that analyzed the Grand Rapids hospital market that included the merging parties. Lynk "concluded that in Michigan, too, higher hospital concentration is associated with lower nonprofit hospital prices."
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 459
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
83
-
-
84937297642
-
Nonprofit Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
Finding this evidence consistent with pledges from the hospitals' chairmen (who "have community interests at heart") that the merger was intended to lower health care costs and to improve quality, and not to increase prices, the court concluded that the merger would enhance consumer welfare
-
Id. Finding this evidence consistent with pledges from the hospitals' chairmen (who "have community interests at heart") that the merger was intended to lower health care costs and to improve quality, and not to increase prices, the court concluded that the merger would enhance consumer welfare.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 459
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
84
-
-
84937297642
-
Nonprofit Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
Finding this evidence consistent with pledges from the hospitals' chairmen (who "have community interests at heart") that the merger was intended to lower health care costs and to improve quality, and not to increase prices, the court concluded that the merger would enhance consumer welfare. 1296-97
-
See id at 1296-97, 1301-03.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 1301-1303
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
85
-
-
84937297642
-
Nonprofit Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
(These findings were also consistent with observations the judge himself made during tours of the hospitals, in which he noted that the hospitals were "well-maintained" and during which he became convinced that the Board of Directors will adhere to their "fiduciary reponsibilities" to renovate and upgrade their facilities
-
(These findings were also consistent with observations the judge himself made during tours of the hospitals, in which he noted that the hospitals were "well-maintained" and during which he became convinced that the Board of Directors will adhere to their "fiduciary reponsibilities" to renovate and upgrade their facilities. Id. at 1301.)
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 1301
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
86
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
[hereinafter Lynk, Property Rights]
-
Lynk, Property Rights, supra note 49, at 372.
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 372
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
87
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
[hereinafter Lynk, Property Rights]
-
See id. at 366.
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 366
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
88
-
-
0002658430
-
Property Rights and the Presumption of Merger Analysis
-
[hereinafter Lynk, Property Rights]
-
See id. at 368-70.
-
(1994)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.39
, pp. 368-370
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
89
-
-
84937297642
-
Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
at 442-43, [hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]
-
Lynk, Hospital Mergers, supra note 49, at 442-43, 445-46.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 445-446
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
90
-
-
84937297642
-
Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
The sample excludes hospitals in Los Angeles County and federal hospitals because, Lynk reasoned, those institutions catered to outlier populations. [hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]
-
The sample excludes hospitals in Los Angeles County and federal hospitals because, Lynk reasoned, those institutions catered to outlier populations. Id. at 442.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 442
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
91
-
-
84937297642
-
Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
Kaiser hospitals and some others were also excluded because they do not release pricing data. Price data was time-lagged from individual hospital data to allow for prices to adjust to market conditions. [hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]
-
Kaiser hospitals and some others were also excluded because they do not release pricing data. Price data was time-lagged from individual hospital data to allow for prices to adjust to market conditions. Id. at 442.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 442
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
92
-
-
84937297642
-
Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
449, [hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]
-
Id. at 449, 452.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 452
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
93
-
-
84937297642
-
Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
[hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]
-
Id. at 453.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 453
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
94
-
-
84937297642
-
Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power
-
[hereinafter Lynk, Hospital Mergers]
-
Id. at 459.
-
(1995)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 459
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
-
95
-
-
0008561436
-
Market Power and Hospital Pricing. Are Nonprofits Different?
-
May-June at 167
-
Glenn Melnick et al., Market Power and Hospital Pricing. Are Nonprofits Different?, Health Aff., May-June 1999, at 167, 168.
-
(1999)
Health Aff.
, pp. 168
-
-
Melnick, G.1
-
96
-
-
33947406526
-
Ownership and Pricing
-
Oct. 6, at 2, (quoting David Dranove of Northwestern University's Kellogg Graduate School of Management)
-
Mary Chris Jaklevic, Ownership and Pricing, Modern Healthcare, Oct. 6, 1997, at 2, 16 (quoting David Dranove of Northwestern University's Kellogg Graduate School of Management).
-
(1997)
Modern Healthcare
, pp. 16
-
-
Jaklevic, M.C.1
-
97
-
-
33947406526
-
Ownership and Pricing
-
Additional controversy arose out of Lynk's employment in the consulting group Lexecon because Dennis Carlton, one of the Journal of Law and Economics editors, was also one of Lexecon's principals. Oct. 6, at 2
-
Additional controversy arose out of Lynk's employment in the consulting group Lexecon because Dennis Carlton, one of the Journal of Law and Economics editors, was also one of Lexecon's principals. Id.
-
(1997)
Modern Healthcare
, pp. 16
-
-
Jaklevic, M.C.1
-
98
-
-
6244268270
-
Professor: Article Was Misleading
-
The journal's editors, however, said Professor Carlton had recused himself when the editors selected Lynk's article for publication. See Letter to the Editor, Dec. 1
-
The journal's editors, however, said Professor Carlton had recused himself when the editors selected Lynk's article for publication. See Dennis W. Carlton, Letter to the Editor, Professor: Article Was Misleading, Modern Healthcare, Dec. 1, 1997, at 52;
-
(1997)
Modern Healthcare
, pp. 52
-
-
Carlton, D.W.1
-
99
-
-
85064775818
-
Journal Story Gave Incomplete Account
-
Letter to the Editor, Oct. 20
-
Sam Peltzman, Letter to the Editor, Journal Story Gave Incomplete Account, Modern Healthcare, Oct. 20, 1997, at 28.
-
(1997)
Modern Healthcare
, pp. 28
-
-
Peltzman, S.1
-
100
-
-
0345542525
-
Do Nonprofit Hospitals Exercise Market Power?
-
Fed. Trade Comm'n U.S. Dep't of Justice, (Nov.)
-
John Simpson, Fed. Trade Comm'n & Richard Shin, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Do Nonprofit Hospitals Exercise Market Power? 16 (Nov. 1996), http://www.ftc.gov/be/workpapers/wp214.pdf.
-
(1996)
, pp. 16
-
-
Simpson, J.1
Shin, R.2
-
101
-
-
0032945049
-
The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior
-
69
-
Emmett B. Keeler et al., The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior, 18 J. Health Econ. 69, 72-76 (1999).
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 72-76
-
-
Keeler, E.B.1
-
102
-
-
0032945049
-
The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior
-
Id at 72-73.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 72-73
-
-
Keeler, E.B.1
-
103
-
-
0032945049
-
The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior
-
Id. at 83.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 83
-
-
Keeler, E.B.1
-
104
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
87
-
David Dranove & Richard Ludwick, Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis, 18 J. Health Econ. 87, 87 (1999).
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 87
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
105
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
The two sources of bias are Lynk's simultaneous use of correlated coefficients and potential correlations due to omitted variables
-
The two sources of bias are Lynk's simultaneous use of correlated coefficients and potential correlations due to omitted variables. Id at 88.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 88
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
106
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
The first problem arises because both hospital market share and market concentration are used as explanatory variables, so a merger affects two - Not one - Coefficients, thus creating a simultaneity bias (where it is hard to measure the movement in one coefficient while holding the other constant)
-
The first problem arises because both hospital market share and market concentration are used as explanatory variables, so a merger affects two - not one - coefficients, thus creating a simultaneity bias (where it is hard to measure the movement in one coefficient while holding the other constant). Id at 88-89.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 88-89
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
107
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
Dranove and Ludwick correct this bias by examining only post-merger prices set by merged hospitals
-
Dranove and Ludwick correct this bias by examining only post-merger prices set by merged hospitals. Id. at 89.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 89
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
108
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
The second problem is caused by Lynk's failure to measure the severity of patients' claims properly
-
The second problem is caused by Lynk's failure to measure the severity of patients' claims properly. Id at 90-91.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 90-91
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
109
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
This might invite an omitted variable bias, such as if hospitals in highly concentrated markets specialized in delivering expensive care for severely ill patients
-
This might invite an omitted variable bias, such as if hospitals in highly concentrated markets specialized in delivering expensive care for severely ill patients. Id.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 90-91
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
110
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
Dranove & Ludwick correct for this source of bias by controlling illness severity by measuring the number of secondary diagnoses accompanying a hospital claim
-
Dranove & Ludwick correct for this source of bias by controlling illness severity by measuring the number of secondary diagnoses accompanying a hospital claim. Id.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 90-91
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
111
-
-
0032928726
-
Competition and Pricing by Nonprofit Hospitals: A Reassessment of Lynk's Analysis
-
Dranove & Ludwick note that ideally, service quality should be controlled as well. See
-
Dranove & Ludwick note that ideally, service quality should be controlled as well. See id. at 90-91.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 90-91
-
-
Dranove, D.1
Ludwick, R.2
-
112
-
-
0032945049
-
The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior
-
Like 69, Dranove and Ludwick also exclude Medicare and Medicaid patient claims from the data but found the different sample still produced Lynk's same results when Lynk's empirical specification was used
-
Like Keeler et al., supra note 60, Dranove and Ludwick also exclude Medicare and Medicaid patient claims from the data but found the different sample still produced Lynk's same results when Lynk's empirical specification was used.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 72-76
-
-
Keeler, E.B.1
-
113
-
-
0032945049
-
The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior
-
Dranove and Ludwick also restrict the sample to hospitals in markets with an HHI greater than 0.10, thus eliminating hospitals in highly diffuse markets
-
Id at 92. Dranove and Ludwick also restrict the sample to hospitals in markets with an HHI greater than 0.10, thus eliminating hospitals in highly diffuse markets.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 92
-
-
Keeler, E.B.1
-
114
-
-
0032945049
-
The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior
-
They otherwise make every effort to execute analyses identical to Lynk's
-
Id. They otherwise make every effort to execute analyses identical to Lynk's.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 92
-
-
Keeler, E.B.1
-
115
-
-
0032945049
-
The Changing Effects of Competition on Non-Profit and For-Profit Hospital Pricing Behavior
-
Id at 97.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 97
-
-
Keeler, E.B.1
-
118
-
-
0032904331
-
Price and Profit
-
Lynk & Neumann then reexamine pricing data from the Butterworth hospitals to reveal that updated analyses confirm Lynk's testimony in that case that the nonprofit hospitals would price lower than comparable for-profits
-
Lynk & Neumann then reexamine pricing data from the Butterworth hospitals to reveal that updated analyses confirm Lynk's testimony in that case that the nonprofit hospitals would price lower than comparable for-profits. Id at 108-10.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 108-110
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
Neumann, L.R.2
-
120
-
-
0032904331
-
Price and Profit
-
On the question of the nature of ownership, however, Lynk & Neumann are far less conciliatory, maintaining there are institutional differences between for-profits and nonprofits that demand attention. See
-
On the question of the nature of ownership, however, Lynk & Neumann are far less conciliatory, maintaining there are institutional differences between for-profits and nonprofits that demand attention. See id. at 110-11.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 110-111
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
Neumann, L.R.2
-
121
-
-
0032904331
-
Price and Profit
-
They assert in closing: [I]f a hospital were effectively controlled by those with interests parallel to the interests of hospital consumers, it is hard to see why those who control such a hospital would consciously choose to exercise any monopoly power that the hospital might possess. To assume that they would willfully do so is to deny the principle of self-interest
-
They assert in closing: [I]f a hospital were effectively controlled by those with interests parallel to the interests of hospital consumers, it is hard to see why those who control such a hospital would consciously choose to exercise any monopoly power that the hospital might possess. To assume that they would willfully do so is to deny the principle of self-interest. Id.
-
(1999)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.18
, pp. 110-111
-
-
Lynk, W.J.1
Neumann, L.R.2
-
125
-
-
85066180786
-
The Effects of Market Concentration and Horizontal Mergers on Hospital Costs and Prices
-
The studies listed, in addition to those cited above, include
-
The studies listed, in addition to those cited above, include: Robert Connor et al., The Effects of Market Concentration and Horizontal Mergers on Hospital Costs and Prices, 5 Int'l J. Econ. Bus. 159 (1998);
-
(1998)
Int'l J. Econ. Bus.
, vol.5
, pp. 159
-
-
Connor, R.1
-
126
-
-
0035583466
-
The Competitive Effects of Not-For-Profit Hospital Mergers: A Case Study
-
Michael G. Vita & Seth Sacher, The Competitive Effects of Not-For-Profit Hospital Mergers: A Case Study, 49 J. Indus. Econ. 63 (2001);
-
(2001)
J. Indus. Econ.
, vol.49
, pp. 63
-
-
Vita, M.G.1
Sacher, S.2
-
127
-
-
1542618045
-
Medicare Upcoding and Hospital Ownership
-
Elaine Silverman & Jonathan Skinner, Medicare Upcoding and Hospital Ownership, 23 J. Health Econ. 369 (2004).
-
(2004)
J. Health Econ.
, vol.23
, pp. 369
-
-
Silverman, E.1
Skinner, J.2
-
130
-
-
33947398969
-
-
See supra notes 45-46
-
See supra notes 45-46.
-
-
-
-
131
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) in American Health Care
-
Though antitrust law is chiefly concerned with matters of efficiency, the concern over higher prices fits neatly within our emphasis on distributive justice. So, in addition to the traditional objections to a monopolist's supracompetitive prices, we also detail how the health system redistributes wealth in undesirable ways, including the preponderance of inflated prices that channel dollars from middle-income consumers to wealthy providers. (Autumn) (referring to the "regressive redistribution of income from consumers to producers")
-
Though antitrust law is chiefly concerned with matters of efficiency, the concern over higher prices fits neatly within our emphasis on distributive justice. So, in addition to the traditional objections to a monopolist's supracompetitive prices, we also detail how the health system redistributes wealth in undesirable ways, including the preponderance of inflated prices that channel dollars from middle-income consumers to wealthy providers. Havighurst & Richman, supra note 2, at 14 (referring to the "regressive redistribution of income from consumers to producers").
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 14
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
133
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) American Health Care
-
(Autumn) at ("By effectively steepening the demand curve a monopolist faces, health insurance enhances the monopolist's pricing freedom and ability to exploit consumers, enabling it to charge even more than the theoretical 'monopoly price'")
-
Id at 15 ("By effectively steepening the demand curve a monopolist faces, health insurance enhances the monopolist's pricing freedom and ability to exploit consumers, enabling it to charge even more than the theoretical 'monopoly price.'");
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 15
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
134
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) American Health Care
-
(Autumn) at ("By effectively steepening the demand curve a monopolist faces, health insurance enhances the monopolist's pricing freedom and ability to exploit consumers, enabling it to charge even more than the theoretical 'monopoly price'") at (describing "the tendency of insurance to induce consumption that would not otherwise occur")
-
id. at 31 (describing "the tendency of insurance to induce consumption that would not otherwise occur").
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 31
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
135
-
-
33947414164
-
Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd. of Regents
-
See, e.g., 85, ("Restrictions on price and output are the paradigmatic examples of restraints of trade that the Sherman Act was intended to prohibit")
-
See, e.g., Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd. of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 107-08 (1984) ("Restrictions on price and output are the paradigmatic examples of restraints of trade that the Sherman Act was intended to prohibit.");
-
(1984)
U.S.
, vol.468
, pp. 107-108
-
-
-
136
-
-
85090441935
-
Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad, Sys
-
1, ("[O]ur inquiry must focus on... whether the practice facially appears to be one that would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output....")
-
Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad, Sys., 441 U.S. 1, 19-20 (1979) ("[O]ur inquiry must focus on... whether the practice facially appears to be one that would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output....").
-
(1979)
U.S.
, vol.441
, pp. 19-20
-
-
-
138
-
-
33947421391
-
Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC
-
756, (Breyer, J., dissenting) (evaluating a restraint's likely effect on prices to determine whether it is anticompetitive)
-
Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 784-85 (1999) (Breyer, J., dissenting) (evaluating a restraint's likely effect on prices to determine whether it is anticompetitive);
-
(1999)
U.S.
, vol.526
, pp. 784-785
-
-
-
139
-
-
0003851002
-
-
("The whole task of antitrust can be summed up as the effort to improve allocative efficiency without impairing productive efficiency so greatly as to produce either no gain or a net loss in consumer welfare")
-
Robert H. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself 91 (1978) ("The whole task of antitrust can be summed up as the effort to improve allocative efficiency without impairing productive efficiency so greatly as to produce either no gain or a net loss in consumer welfare.").
-
(1978)
The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War With Itself
, pp. 91
-
-
Bork, R.H.1
-
140
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) in American Health Care
-
(Autumn) at (describing "the tendency of insurance to induce consumption that would not otherwise occur")
-
Havighurst & Richman, supra note 2, at 31 (describing "the tendency of insurance to induce consumption that would not otherwise occur").
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 31
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
141
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) in American Health Care
-
This is particularly true when one considers the dynamic consequences of moral hazard, whereby subsidized demand stimulates investments in expensive new technologies in which many consumers would prefer not to invest. See at (Autumn) at (describing "the tendency of insurance to induce consumption that would not otherwise occur")
-
This is particularly true when one considers the dynamic consequences of moral hazard, whereby subsidized demand stimulates investments in expensive new technologies in which many consumers would prefer not to invest. See id. at 29;
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 29
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
142
-
-
33947411918
-
The Tax Subsidy to Employment-Based Health Insurance and the Distribution of Well-Being
-
see also 83, (Autumn)
-
see also Mark Pauly, The Tax Subsidy to Employment-Based Health Insurance and the Distribution of Well-Being, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 83, 99-100 (Autumn 2006).
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 99-100
-
-
Pauly, M.1
-
143
-
-
33947412468
-
FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp
-
1285, 1300, (W.D. Mich.) aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997)
-
FTC v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1300, 1306 (W.D. Mich. 1996), aff'd, 121 F.3d 708 (6th Cir. 1997).
-
(1996)
F. Supp.
, vol.946
, pp. 1306
-
-
-
144
-
-
33947377619
-
United States v. Long Island Jewish Med. Ctr
-
See also 121, (E.D.N.Y.)
-
See also United States v. Long Island Jewish Med. Ctr., 983 F. Supp. 121, 146 (E.D.N.Y. 1997).
-
(1997)
F. Supp.
, vol.983
, pp. 146
-
-
-
145
-
-
33947365205
-
The Impact of Tax-Exempt Status: The Supply-Side Subsidies
-
This, in fact, is a precondition to obtaining nonprofit status. See Richard Schmalbeck observes in this volume that nonprofit hospitals enjoy a similar generosity from tax courts and IRS rulings. (Autumn)
-
This, in fact, is a precondition to obtaining nonprofit status. See Schmalbeck, infra note 95 and accompanying text.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 124
-
-
Schmalbeck, R.L.1
-
146
-
-
33947391434
-
United States v. Brown Univ
-
But see 658, (3d Cir.) (allowing "the undisputed public interest in equality of educational access and opportunity" to be considered as justification for a group of colleges' collusion on financial aid)
-
But see United States v. Brown Univ., 5 F.3d 658, 672 (3d Cir. 1993) (allowing "the undisputed public interest in equality of educational access and opportunity" to be considered as justification for a group of colleges' collusion on financial aid).
-
(1993)
F.3d
, vol.5
, pp. 672
-
-
-
147
-
-
33947366597
-
The Politically Correct Corporation and the Antitrust Laws: The Proper Treatment of Noneconomic or Social Welfare Justifications Under Section 1 of The Sherman Act
-
For criticisms of Brown University, see 137, ("Even assuming that the defendants genuinely intend to benefit the public, they still cannot be trusted to balance properly the asserted public interest benefits against the resulting harms to competition so long as they receive direct financial advantages")
-
For criticisms of Brown University, see Lee Goldman, The Politically Correct Corporation and the Antitrust Laws: The Proper Treatment of Noneconomic or Social Welfare Justifications Under Section 1 of The Sherman Act, 13 Yale L. & Pol'y Rev. 137, 148 (1995) ("Even assuming that the defendants genuinely intend to benefit the public, they still cannot be trusted to balance properly the asserted public interest benefits against the resulting harms to competition so long as they receive direct financial advantages.").
-
(1995)
Yale L. & Pol'y Rev.
, vol.13
, pp. 148
-
-
Goldman, L.1
-
150
-
-
33947383166
-
Hosp. Corp. of Am. v. FTC
-
Judge Posner also holds this view, see 1381, (7th Cir.) (citations omitted). and Judge Easterbrook apparently does as well. Easterbrook remanded a Sherman Act section 2 claim against Blue Cross/Blue Shield to determine whether the nonprofit defendants had sufficient market power to shift costs to rivals
-
Judge Posner also holds this view, see supra, note 14, and Judge Easterbrook apparently does as well. Easterbrook remanded a Sherman Act section 2 claim against Blue Cross/Blue Shield to determine whether the nonprofit defendants had sufficient market power to shift costs to rivals.
-
(1986)
F.2d
, vol.807
, pp. 1390
-
-
-
151
-
-
33947425750
-
Ball Mem'l Hosp. v. Mut. Hosp. Ins
-
See 1325, (7th Cir.)
-
ee Ball Mem'l Hosp. v. Mut. Hosp. Ins., 784 F.2d 1325, 1340-41 (7th Cir. 1986).
-
(1986)
F.2d
, vol.784
, pp. 1340-1341
-
-
-
152
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) in American Health Care
-
It is possible that the surplus from supracompetitive prices is whittled away in inflated salaries, administrative inefficiencies, or undesired quality improvements. See 7, (Autumn) ("[I]n the absence of either market discipline or effective political oversight, there is no assurance that easily gained revenues will not be squandered in low-priority activities, in overpaying for inputs, or simply through managerial slack")
-
It is possible that the surplus from supracompetitive prices is whittled away in inflated salaries, administrative inefficiencies, or undesired quality improvements. See Havighurst & Richman, supra note 2, at 22-23 ("[I]n the absence of either market discipline or effective political oversight, there is no assurance that easily gained revenues will not be squandered in low-priority activities, in overpaying for inputs, or simply through managerial slack.").
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 22-23
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
153
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) in American Health Care
-
But this kind of waste can itself be characterized as a subsidy. See (Autumn)
-
But this kind of waste can itself be characterized as a subsidy. See id.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
154
-
-
33947395801
-
-
See supra Part IV.B.
-
, Issue.PART IV.B
-
-
-
157
-
-
33947389379
-
FTC v. Ind. Fed. of Dentists
-
See, e.g., 447, (holding a group of dentists liable for collectively refusing to submit x-rays to insurance companies and thus maintaining an information imbalance)
-
See, e.g., FTC v. Ind. Fed. of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 459 (1986) (holding a group of dentists liable for collectively refusing to submit x-rays to insurance companies and thus maintaining an information imbalance);
-
(1986)
U.S.
, vol.476
, pp. 459
-
-
-
158
-
-
33947358366
-
Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc'y
-
332, 341, (holding that "maximum" price-fixing by a group of doctors violates the Sherman Act)
-
Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332, 341, 357 (1982) (holding that "maximum" price-fixing by a group of doctors violates the Sherman Act);
-
(1982)
U.S.
, vol.457
, pp. 357
-
-
-
159
-
-
33947407807
-
Am. Med. Ass'n v. FTC
-
443, (reviewing an FTC order forbidding medical associations from interfering with doctors' non-deceptive advertising)
-
Am. Med. Ass'n v. FTC, 638 F.2d 443, 447 (1980) (reviewing an FTC order forbidding medical associations from interfering with doctors' non-deceptive advertising).
-
(1980)
F.2d
, vol.638
, pp. 447
-
-
-
160
-
-
33947415022
-
-
Rev. Rul. 56-185, 1956-1 C.B. 202
-
Rev. Rul. 56-185, 1956-1 C.B. 202 (1956).
-
(1956)
-
-
-
161
-
-
33947365205
-
The Impact of Tax-Exempt Status: The Supply-Side Subsidies
-
Richard Schmalbeck observes in this volume that nonprofit hospitals enjoy a similar generosity from tax courts and IRS rulings. 121, (Autumn) (internal citations omitted)
-
Schmalbeck, supra note 18, at 124 (internal citations omitted).
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 124
-
-
Schmalbeck, R.L.1
-
162
-
-
33947397162
-
IHC Health Plans, Inc. v. Comm'r
-
1188, (10th Cir.)
-
IHC Health Plans, Inc. v. Comm'r, 325 F.3d 1188, 1197 (10th Cir. 2003).
-
(2003)
F.3d
, vol.325
, pp. 1197
-
-
-
163
-
-
33947365205
-
The Impact of Tax-Exempt Status: The Supply-Side Subsidies
-
Richard Schmalbeck observes in this volume that nonprofit hospitals enjoy a similar generosity from tax courts and IRS rulings. 121, (Autumn)
-
Schmalbeck, supra note 18, at 128
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 128
-
-
Schmalbeck, R.L.1
-
164
-
-
33947397162
-
IHC Health Plans
-
(citing IHC Health Plans, 325 F.3d at 1197).
-
F.3d
, vol.325
, pp. 1197
-
-
-
165
-
-
33947377619
-
United States v. Long Island Jewish Med. Ctr
-
121, (E.D.N.Y.)
-
United States v. Long Island Jewish Med. Ctr., 983 F. Supp. 121, 146 (E.D.N.Y. 1997).
-
(1997)
F. Supp.
, vol.983
, pp. 146
-
-
|