메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 2, Issue 3, 2006, Pages 479-531

Price discrimination under EC Compitation Law: Another antitrust doctrine in search of limiting principles?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 33846781113     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhl013     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (47)

References (216)
  • 1
    • 0043190696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Exclusionary pricing and price discrimination. Abuses under Article 82 - An economic analysis"
    • There is, however, a relatively abundant legal and economic literature on the subject. On the enonomics of price discrimination, see
    • There is, however, a relatively abundant legal and economic literature on the subject. On the enonomics of price discrimination, see Derek Ridyard, "Exclusionary pricing and price discrimination. abuses under Article 82 - an economic analysis," 6 European Competition Law Review 286 (2002)
    • (2002) European Competition Law Review , vol.6 , pp. 286
    • Ridyard, D.1
  • 4
    • 85022000243 scopus 로고
    • "Price discrimination and social welfare"
    • Hal R. Varian, "Price discrimination and social welfare," 75 American Economic Review 870 (1985);
    • (1985) American Economic Review , vol.75 , pp. 870
    • Varian, H.R.1
  • 5
    • 0001104079 scopus 로고
    • "Output and welfare implications of third degree price discrimination"
    • Richard Schmalensee, "Output and welfare implications of third degree price discrimination," 71 American Economic Review 242 (1981)
    • (1981) American Economic Review , vol.71 , pp. 242
    • Schmalensee, R.1
  • 6
    • 33846848370 scopus 로고
    • "Price discrimination and rebate policies under EU competition law"
    • for a legal analysis of price discrimination under Article 82 of the EC Treaty, see
    • for a legal analysis of price discrimination under Article 82 of the EC Treaty, see Michel Waelbroeck, "Price discrimination and rebate policies under EU competition law," Fordham Corporate Law Institute 148 (1995).
    • (1995) Fordham Corporate Law Institute , pp. 148
    • Waelbroeck, M.1
  • 7
    • 33846783568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses, December
    • See DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses, December 2005, at 3§.
    • (2005)
  • 8
    • 33846808138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses, December at §§53
    • Id. at §§53, 140-141
    • (2005) , pp. 140-141
  • 9
    • 33846834476 scopus 로고
    • Italian Republic v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 17 July ECR-165 in the context of the ECSC Treaty
    • See ECJ, 17 July 1963, Italian Republic v. Commission, 13-63, ECR-165 in the context of the ECSC Treaty.
    • (1963) , pp. 13-63
  • 10
    • 0007101958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2nd edn (University of Chicago Press)
    • Richard Posner, Antitrust Law, 2nd edn (University of Chicago Press, 2001) at 79-80.
    • (2001) Antitrust Law , pp. 79-80
    • Posner, R.1
  • 17
    • 0043190696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Exclusionary pricing and price discrimination. Abuses under Article 82 - An economic analysis"
    • For a good discussion of this, see
    • For a good discussion of this, see D. Ridyard, supra n 1 at 286.
    • (2002) European Competition Law Review , vol.6 , pp. 286
    • Ridyard, D.1
  • 18
  • 19
    • 0043190696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Exclusionary pricing and price discrimination. Abuses under Article 82 - An economic analysis"
    • For a good discussion of this, see Marginal cost pricing ... retains some desirable efficiency properties in [industries facing problems of cost recovery], but simple short-run marginal cost pricing fails to remunerate the firm's fixed costs. In a dynamic context, it will also fail to provide incentives for firms to make such investments in the future. As a consequence, firms in fixed cost recovery industries charge prices in excess, often well in excess, of short-run marginal costs. The likelihood that such pricing will entail some loss of static efficiency (i.e.: certain consumers will be dissuaded from consuming the product even though they value it higher than the marginal cost of supply) must be traded-off against the risk that the product would not exist at all if investors were not offered the prospect of fixed cost recovery - and even some profit on top - at the time when the necessary investments were made." "Marginal cost pricing ...
    • Id. at 287: "Marginal cost pricing ... retains some desirable efficiency properties in [industries facing problems of cost recovery], but simple short-run marginal cost pricing fails to remunerate the firm's fixed costs. In a dynamic context, it will also fail to provide incentives for firms to make such investments in the future. As a consequence, firms in fixed cost recovery industries charge prices in excess, often well in excess, of short-run marginal costs. The likelihood that such pricing will entail some loss of static efficiency (i.e.: Certain consumers will be dissuaded from consuming the product even though they value it higher than the marginal cost of supply) must be traded-off against the risk that the product would not exist at all if investors were not offered the prospect of fixed cost recovery - and even some profit on top - at the time when the necessary investments were made." "Marginal cost pricing ... retains some desirable efficiency properties in [industries facing problems of cost recovery], but simple short-run marginal cost pricing fails to remunerate the firm's fixed costs. In a dynamic context, it will also fail to provide incentives for firms to make such investments in the future. As a consequence, firms in fixed cost recovery industries charge prices in excess, often well in excess, of short-run marginal costs. The likelihood that such pricing will entail some loss of static efficiency (i.e.: Certain consumers will be dissuaded from consuming the product
    • (2002) European Competition Law Review , vol.6 , pp. 287
    • Ridyard, D.1
  • 21
    • 33846809751 scopus 로고
    • United Brands Company v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 14 February ECR [1978]-207
    • See ECJ, United Brands Company v. Commission, 27/76, 14 February 1978, ECR [1978]-207.
    • (1978) , vol.27 , Issue.76
  • 24
    • 33846809751 scopus 로고
    • United Brands Company v. Commission
    • See, however, in ECJ, 14 February ECR [1978]-207 where the ECJ indicated at 2§28 that: "Differences in transport costs, taxation, customs duties, the wages of the labour force, the conditions of marketing, the differences in the parity of currencies, the density of competition may eventually culminate in different retail selling price"
    • See, however, in United Brands, supra n 14 where the ECJ indicated at 2§28 that: "Differences in transport costs, taxation, customs duties, the wages of the labour force, the conditions of marketing, the differences in the parity of currencies, the density of competition may eventually culminate in different retail selling price."
    • (1978) , vol.27 , Issue.76
  • 26
    • 22244454956 scopus 로고
    • See (Collection scientifique de la Faculté de droit de l'Université de Liège)
    • See René Joliet, Monopolization and Abuse of a Dominant Position (Collection scientifique de la Faculté de droit de l'Université de Liège, 1970) at 247
    • (1970) Monopolization and Abuse of a Dominant Position , pp. 247
    • Joliet, R.1
  • 27
    • 29144489405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 2nd edn (Oxford University Press)
    • See, e.g., Alison Jones & Brenda Sufrin, EC Competition Law, 2nd edn (Oxford University Press, 2004) at 411;
    • (2004) EC Competition Law , pp. 411
    • Jones, A.1    Sufrin, B.2
  • 31
    • 0004109573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5th edn (LexisNexis Butterworths) at 716 and
    • Richard Whish, Competition Law, 5th edn (LexisNexis Butterworths, 2003) at 716 and 710.
    • (2003) Competition Law , pp. 710
    • Whish, R.1
  • 32
    • 27744484856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Defining legitimate competition: How to clarify pricing abuses under Article 82 EC"
    • at 115
    • See John Temple Lang and Robert O'Donoghue, "Defining legitimate competition: How to clarify pricing abuses under Article 82 EC," 26 Fordham International Law Journal 83 (2002) at 115.
    • (2002) Fordham International Law Journal , vol.26 , pp. 83
    • Lang, J.T.1    O'Donoghue, R.2
  • 33
    • 34748892854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See (American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC)
    • See Paul A. London, The Competition Solution (American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC, 2005) at p. 136;
    • (2005) The Competition Solution , pp. 136
    • London, P.A.1
  • 34
    • 85024118006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Trade Commission v. Morton Salt
    • See also ("The legislative history of the Robinson-Patman Act makes it abundantly clear that Congress considered it to be an evil that a large buyer could secure a competitive advantage over a small buyer solely because of the larger buyer's quantity purchasing ability")
    • See also Federal Trade Commission v. Morton Salt, 334 U.S. 37 ("The legislative history of the Robinson-Patman Act makes it abundantly clear that Congress considered it to be an evil that a large buyer could secure a competitive advantage over a small buyer solely because of the larger buyer's quantity purchasing ability").
    • U.S. , vol.334 , pp. 37
  • 35
    • 0004309256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also 2nd edn (The Independent Institute) (" [I]t is readily admitted that Section 2 of the Clayton Act and its important Robinson-Patman amendments, were passed in order to protect small, independent business firms from the buying and selling practices of larger corporations, particularly large chain stores")
    • See also Dominick T. Armentano, Antitrust and Monopoly - Anatomy of a Policy Failure, 2nd edn (The Independent Institute, 1999) at 167 (" [I]t is readily admitted that Section 2 of the Clayton Act and its important Robinson-Patman amendments, were passed in order to protect small, independent business firms from the buying and selling practices of larger corporations, particularly large chain stores.")
    • (1999) Antitrust and Monopoly - Anatomy of a Policy Failure , pp. 167
    • Armentano, D.T.1
  • 36
    • 33846808137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Volvo Trucks North America, Inc. v. Reeder-Simco GMC, Inc
    • See, for a recent illustration
    • See, for a recent illustration, Volvo Trucks North America, Inc. v. Reeder-Simco GMC, Inc., 126 S. Ct. 860 (2006).
    • (2006) S. Ct. , vol.126 , pp. 860
  • 38
    • 33846848371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra at Section V.A
    • See infra at Section V.A.
  • 39
    • 33846795173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra at Section V.C
    • See infra at Section V.C.
  • 40
    • 33846837912 scopus 로고
    • Europemballage Corporation and Continental Can Company Inc. v. Commission
    • ECJ, 6-72, 21 February ECR [1973]-215
    • ECJ, 6-72, Europemballage Corporation and Continental Can Company Inc. v. Commission, 21 February 1973, ECR [1973]-215, at 2§6.
    • (1973) , pp. 26
  • 41
    • 84890622928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The concept of an exclusionary abuse"
    • See GCLC Research Papers on Article 82, June, The ECJ's statement in Continental Can regarding "the nonexhaustive nature of the abuses listed in Article 82 EC were made in the context of a teleological interpretation of the EC Treaty intended to fill an important lacuna in the law - the absence at the time of rules governing mergers and acquisitions"
    • See John Temple Lang & Robert O'Donoghue, "The concept of an exclusionary abuse," GCLC Research Papers on Article 82, June 2005, at 52-3 The ECJ's statement in Continental Can regarding "the nonexhaustive nature of the abuses listed in Article 82 EC were made in the context of a teleological interpretation of the EC Treaty intended to fill an important lacuna in the law - the absence at the time of rules governing mergers and acquisitions."
    • (2005) , pp. 52-53
    • Lang, J.T.1    O'Donoghue, R.2
  • 42
    • 27744484856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Defining legitimate competition: How to clarify pricing abuses under Article 82 EC"
    • See at 115, who consider it is a strict test which is, however, not applied in practice
    • See J. Temple Lang & R. O'Donoghue, supra n 22, who consider it is a strict test which is, however, not applied in practice.
    • (2002) Fordham International Law Journal , vol.26 , pp. 83
    • Lang, J.T.1    O'Donoghue, R.2
  • 44
    • 0011416716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • European Competition Law: A Practictioner's Guide
    • This definition is taken from Kluwer Law International
    • This definition is taken from Lennart Ritter and David Braun, European Competition Law: A Practictioner's Guide, Kluwer Law International, 2004, at 465.
    • (2004) , pp. 465
    • Ritter, L.1    Braun, D.2
  • 45
    • 33846806382 scopus 로고
    • Suiker Unie and others v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 16 December 40/73, ECR [1975]-1663 "As the commission has emphasized the effect of the system complained of was that different net prices were charged to two economic operators who bought the same amount of sugar from SZV if one of them purchased from another producer as well. By acting in this way SZV applied dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties' within the meaning of article 86 (c) of the Treaty"
    • See ECJ, Suiker Unie and others v. Commission, 16 December 1975, 40/73, ECR [1975]-1663 at 1§22: "As the commission has emphasized the effect of the system complained of was that different net prices were charged to two economic operators who bought the same amount of sugar from SZV if one of them purchased from another producer as well. By acting in this way SZV applied dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties' within the meaning of article 86 (c) of the Treaty."
    • (1975) , pp. 122
  • 46
    • 33846817781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Irish Sugar plc
    • To the contrary, uniform pricing of different volumes can be seen as discriminatory. This is why the Commission considers that quantity rebates are normally unobjectionable. See Commission Decision 97/624 of 14 May 1997, OJ L 258 of 22 September at 1§53
    • To the contrary, uniform pricing of different volumes can be seen as discriminatory. This is why the Commission considers that quantity rebates are normally unobjectionable. See Commission Decision 97/624 of 14 May 1997, Irish Sugar plc., OJ L 258 of 22 September 1997, pp. 1-34 at 1§53.
    • (1997) , pp. 1-34
  • 47
    • 84964426146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Manufacture française des pneumatiques Michelin v. Commission (Michelin II)
    • See CFI, 30 September T-203/01
    • See CFI, Manufacture française des pneumatiques Michelin v. Commission (Michelin II), 30 September 2003, T-203/01 at §§98 and 100.
    • (2003) , pp. 98-100
  • 48
    • 27844510507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Michelin II: A per se rule against rebates by dominant companies?"
    • See also at 151
    • See also, Denis Waelbroeck, "Michelin II: A per se rule against rebates by dominant companies?" 1(1) Journal of Competition Law and Economics 149 (2005) at 151.
    • (2005) Journal of Competition Law and Economics , vol.1 , Issue.1 , pp. 149
    • Waelbroeck, D.1
  • 49
    • 33846841442 scopus 로고
    • Hoffmann-La Roche v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 13 February, 85/76, ECR[1979]-461
    • See ECJ, Hoffmann-La Roche v. Commission, 13 February 1979, 85/76, ECR[1979]-461.
    • (1979)
  • 50
    • 33846841442 scopus 로고
    • Hoffmann-La Roche v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 13 February, 85/76, ECR[1979]-461. The trading parties were 22 large firms of different industries
    • Id. at 3§5. The trading parties were 22 large firms of different industries.
    • (1979) , pp. 35
  • 51
    • 33846841442 scopus 로고
    • Hoffmann-La Roche v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 13 February, 85/76, ECR[1979]-461. and following
    • Id. at 1§22 and following.
    • (1979) , pp. 122
  • 52
    • 33846806382 scopus 로고
    • Suiker Unie and others v. Commission
    • A similar approach can be observed in ECJ, 16 December 40/73, ECR [1975]-1663 In that case, the Commission had considered that the fidelity rebates granted by SZV, a dominant sugar producer in Southern Germany, to its customers, amounted to an "unjustifiable discrimination against buyers who also buy sugar from other sources than SZV." The Commission, in particular, seemed concerned by the fact that the rebate policy had been adopted so as to "limit possibilities for imports" and "to strengthen the dominant position of the producer." The Commission thus examined the horizontal effects of the rebates scheme. The Court followed the Commission's reasoning as it essentially disregarded the "competitive disadvantage" requirement contained in Article 82(c) and preferred linking the discrimination to foreclosure effects generated by the rebates
    • similar approach can be observed in Suiker Unie, ECJ, supra n 29. In that case, the Commission had considered that the fidelity rebates granted by SZV, a dominant sugar producer in Southern Germany, to its customers, amounted to an "unjustifiable discrimination against buyers who also buy sugar from other sources than SZV." The Commission, in particular, seemed concerned by the fact that the rebate policy had been adopted so as to "limit possibilities for imports" and "to strengthen the dominant position of the producer." The Commission thus examined the horizontal effects of the rebates scheme. The Court followed the Commission's reasoning as it essentially disregarded the "competitive disadvantage" requirement contained in Article 82(c) and preferred linking the discrimination to foreclosure effects generated by the rebates.
    • (1975) , pp. 122
  • 53
    • 33846846930 scopus 로고
    • BPB Industries plc
    • See Commission Decision 89/22 of 5 December 1988, IV/31.900, OJ L 10 of 13 January
    • See Commission Decision 89/22 of 5 December 1988, IV/31.900, BPB Industries plc., OJ L 10 of 13 January 1989, pp. 50-72.
    • (1989) , pp. 50-72
  • 54
    • 33846846930 scopus 로고
    • BPB Industries plc
    • See Commission Decision 89/22 of 5 December 1988, IV/31.900, OJ L 10 of 13 January
    • Id. at 1§48.
    • (1989) , pp. 148
  • 55
    • 33846797168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BPB Industries plc and British Gypsum Ltd. v. Commission
    • See CFI, T-65/89, ECR 1993 II-389
    • See CFI, BPB Industries plc and British Gypsum Ltd. v. Commission, T-65/ 89, ECR 1993 II-389 at 1§19.
  • 56
    • 33846797169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission decision
    • See Commission decision at 4§9.
  • 57
    • 33846809717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Virgin/British Airways
    • See Commission Decision 2000/74 of 14 July 1999, JOCE L 30 of 4 February
    • See Commission Decision 2000/74 of 14 July 1999, Virgin/British Airways, JOCE L 30 of 4 February 2000, pp. 1-24.
    • (2000) , pp. 1-24
  • 58
    • 33846809717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Virgin/British Airways
    • See Commission Decision 2000/74 of 14 July 1999, JOCE L 30 of 4 February The travel agents were thus given incentives to remain loyal to British Airways through increasing their sales of BA's tickets
    • Id. at §§108 111. The travel agents were thus given incentives to remain loyal to British Airways through increasing their sales of BA's tickets.
    • (2000) , pp. 108-111
  • 59
    • 33846809717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Virgin/British Airways
    • See Commission Decision 2000/74 of 14 July 1999, JOCE L 30 of 4 February The travel agents were thus given incentives to remain loyal to British Airways through increasing their sales of BA's tickets
    • Id. at 1§11.
    • (2000) , pp. 108-111
  • 60
    • 33846811992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 40
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 40 at 1§11
  • 61
    • 84927084540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • British Airways plc v. Commission
    • and CFI, 17 December Case T-219/99, not yet published
    • and CFI, British Airways plc v. Commission, 17 December 2003, Case T-219/ 99, not yet published, at 2§38.
    • (2003) , pp. 238
  • 62
    • 33846810439 scopus 로고
    • Bandengroothandel Frieschebrug BV/NV Nederlandsche Banden-Industrie Michelin
    • See Commission Decision 81/969 of 7 October 1981, OJ L 353 of 9 December at 3§8
    • See Commission Decision 81/969 of 7 October 1981, Bandengroothandel Frieschebrug BV/NV Nederlandsche Banden-Industrie Michelin, OJ L 353 of 9 December 1981, pp. 33-47 at 3§8.
    • (1981) , pp. 33-47
  • 63
    • 33846810439 scopus 로고
    • Bandengroothandel Frieschebrug BV/NV Nederlandsche Banden-Industrie Michelin
    • See Commission Decision 81/969 of 7 October 1981, OJ L 353 of 9 December
    • Id. at 4§9.
    • (1981) , pp. 49
  • 64
    • 27844462655 scopus 로고
    • NV Nederlandsche Banden Industrie Michelin v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 9 November 322/81, ECR [1983]-3461
    • See ECJ, NV Nederlandsche Banden Industrie Michelin v. Commission, 9 November 1983, 322/81, ECR [1983]-3461 at 9§0.
    • (1983) , pp. 90
  • 65
    • 33846799756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30 at 1§54.
  • 66
    • 33846785872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30
    • Id. at 1§52 and 1§54.
  • 67
    • 33846783562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses, December
    • See DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82, supra n 2 at 1§04.
    • (2005) , pp. 104
  • 68
    • 2442561172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Why above-cost price cuts to drive out entrants are not predatory - And the implications for defining costs and market power"
    • See, on this
    • See, on this, Einer Elhauge, "Why above-cost price cuts to drive out entrants are not predatory - and the implications for defining costs and market power," 112 Yale Law Journal 681 (2003);
    • (2003) Yale Law Journal , vol.112 , pp. 681
    • Elhauge, E.1
  • 69
    • 0346386076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Stopping above-cost predatory pricing"
    • Aaron S. Edlin, "Stopping above-cost predatory pricing," 111 Yale Law Journal 941 (2002);
    • (2002) Yale Law Journal , vol.111 , pp. 941
    • Edlin, A.S.1
  • 70
    • 33846841435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra n 21
    • R. Whish, supra n 21 at 653.
    • Whish, R.1
  • 71
    • 33846810476 scopus 로고
    • ECS/AKZO
    • See Commission Decision 85/609 of 14 December 1985, OJ L 374 of 31 December
    • See Commission Decision 85/609 of 14 December 1985, ECS/AKZO, OJ L 374 of 31 December 1985, pp. 1-27.
    • (1985) , pp. 1-27
  • 72
    • 33846810476 scopus 로고
    • ECS/AKZO
    • See Commission Decision 85/609 of 14 December 1985, OJ L 374 of 31 December
    • Id. at 8§3.
    • (1985) , pp. 83
  • 73
    • 33846810476 scopus 로고
    • ECS/AKZO
    • See Commission Decision 85/609 of 14 December 1985, OJ L 374 of 31 December. at Article 3(3). Article (5) was however annulled by the Court of Justice
    • Id. at Article 3(3). Article 3(5) was however annulled by the Court of Justice.
    • (1985) , pp. 83
  • 74
    • 33846799759 scopus 로고
    • AKZO Chemie BV v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 3 July C-62/86, ECR[1991], I-3359
    • See ECJ, AKZO Chemie BV v. Commission, 3 July 1991, C-62/86, ECR[1991], I-3359.
    • (1991)
  • 75
    • 33846822352 scopus 로고
    • Eurofix-Bauco v. Hilti
    • See Commission Decision 88/138 of 22 December 1987, OJ L 65 of 11 March
    • See Commission Decision 88/138 of 22 December 1987, Eurofix-Bauco v. Hilti OJ L 65 of 11 March 1988, pp. 19-44.
    • (1988) , pp. 19-44
  • 76
    • 33749998328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition Law of the European Community
    • At §§80-81 of the Decision the Commission considered that the practice was deemed to be "designed to damage the business of, or deter market entry by, its competitors." Some have seen in the Commission's qualification of the practice a reference to both primary and secondary line injuries, see (Kluwer Law International)
    • At §§80-81 of the Decision the Commission considered that the practice was deemed to be "designed to damage the business of, or deter market entry by, its competitors." Some have seen in the Commission's qualification of the practice a reference to both primary and secondary line injuries, see Van Bael & Bellis, supra n 18 at 915.
    • (2005) , pp. 915
    • Bael, V.1    Bellis2
  • 77
    • 33846845474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30 at 1§54.
  • 78
    • 33846848362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Irish Sugar plc v. Commission
    • This was upheld by the CFI, 7 October, T-228/97, ECR [1999] II-2969
    • This was upheld by the CFI, Irish Sugar plc v. Commission, 7 October 1999, T-228/97, ECR [1999] II-2969 at §§215-225.
    • (1999) , pp. 215-225
  • 79
    • 33846839917 scopus 로고
    • Cewal
    • See Commission Decision 93/82 of 23 December 1992, OJ L 34 of 10 February at 8§3
    • See Commission Decision 93/82 of 23 December 1992, Cewal, OJ L 34 of 10 February 1993 pp. 20-43 at 8§3.
    • (1993) , pp. 20-43
  • 80
    • 33846815802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compagnie Maritime Belge Transports SA and Others v. Commission
    • See CFI, 8 October 1996, 9 November T-24/93, T-25/93, T-26/93 and T-28/93, ECR[1996] II-1211
    • See CFI, Compagnie Maritime Belge Transports SA and Others v. Commission, 8 October 1996, Official Journal C 336, 9 November 1996, T-24/93, T-25/93, T-26/93 and T-28/93, ECR[1996] II-1211 at 1§24.
    • (1996) Official Journal C 336 , pp. 124
  • 81
    • 33846820857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is of note, however, that AG Fennelly stated: "normally, non-discriminatory price cuts by a dominant undertaking which do not entail below-cost sales should not be regarded as being anticompetitive." A contrario, this seems to imply that discrimatory selective price cuts above costs could be held abusive under Article 82 EC. See Opinion of AG Fennelly of 29 October ECR [2000] I-1365
    • It is of note, however, that AG Fennelly stated: "normally, non-discriminatory price cuts by a dominant undertaking which do not entail below-cost sales should not be regarded as being anticompetitive." A contrario, this seems to imply that discrimatory selective price cuts above costs could be held abusive under Article 82 EC. See Opinion of AG Fennelly of 29 October 1998, ECR [2000] I-1365, at 1§32.
    • (1998) , pp. 132
  • 82
    • 33846841441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 53 at and 75
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 53 at §§34(5) and 75.
  • 83
    • 33846795170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See XXVIIth Report on Competition Policy - 1997
    • See XXVIIth Report on Competition Policy - 1997, at 6§9.
  • 84
    • 33846827658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also, supra n 28
    • See also, L. Ritter and D. Braun, supra n 28 at p. 452.
    • Ritter, L.1    Braun, D.2
  • 85
    • 33846806377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van den Bergh Foods Limited
    • See Commission Decision 98/531 of 11 March 1998, OJ L 246 of 4 September
    • See Commission Decision 98/531 of 11 March 1998, Van den Bergh Foods Limited, OJ L 246 of 4 September 1998, p. 1.
    • (1998) , pp. 1
  • 86
    • 33846806377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van den Bergh Foods Limited
    • See Commission Decision 98/531 of 11 March 1998, OJ L 246 of 4 September
    • Id. at 7§6.
    • (1998) , pp. 76
  • 87
    • 33846806377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van den Bergh Foods Limited
    • See Commission Decision 98/531 of 11 March 1998, OJ L 246 of 4 September
    • Id. at 7§7.
    • (1998) , pp. 77
  • 88
    • 33846795171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In most of these cases, complainants were not the trading parties, but the competitors, suffering the exclusionary effect of the practice. This probably reveals that the trading parties did not consider themselves as having been put at a competitive disadvantage.
  • 89
    • 33846808136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It merely prohibited "discriminatory practices involving, within the common market, the application by a seller of dissimilar conditions to comparable transactions..." See Article 60(1) of the ECSC Treaty
    • It merely prohibited "discriminatory practices involving, within the common market, the application by a seller of dissimilar conditions to comparable transactions..." See Article 60(1) of the ECSC Treaty.
  • 90
    • 33846782056 scopus 로고
    • See EEC Commission, Memorandum sur le Probleme de la Concentration dans le Marché Commun, 1 December reprinted in Revue Trimestrielle de Droit Européen (1966) 651-677
    • See EEC Commission, Memorandum sur le Probleme de la Concentration dans le Marché Commun, 1 December 1965 at p. 25 reprinted in Revue Trimestrielle de Droit Européen (1966) 651-677.
    • (1965) , pp. 25
  • 91
    • 22244454956 scopus 로고
    • Monopolization and Abuse of a Dominant Position
    • In the early 1960s, the Commission sought to establish a theoretical framework for interpreting the abuse concept enclosed in Article 82 EC through the appointment of a group of professors changed with the duty to work out the basic enforcement principles of this provision. The group of Professors released a Memorandum on Concentration on the Common Market in 1966 which seemed to suggest that the concept of price discrimination enclosed in Article 86 (c) could encompass the eviction of competing companies. See, contra, Professor Joliet argued that Article 82 (c) merely applied to secondary line discriminations and did not apply to "discriminatory price cutting having adverse effects upon primary-line competition" (Collection scientifique de la Faculté de droit l'Université de Liège)
    • In the early 1960s, the Commission sought to establish a theoretical framework for interpreting the abuse concept enclosed in Article 82 EC through the appointment of a group of professors changed with the duty to work out the basic enforcement principles of this provision. The group of Professors released a Memorandum on Concentration on the Common Market in 1966 which seemed to suggest that the concept of price discrimination enclosed in Article 86 (c) could encompass the eviction of competing companies. See, contra, René Joliet, supra n 21 at 247. Professor Joliet argued that Article 82 (c) merely applied to secondary line discriminations and did not apply to "discriminatory price cutting having adverse effects upon primary-line competition."
    • (1970) , pp. 247
    • Joliet, R.1
  • 92
    • 33846837912 scopus 로고
    • Europemballage Corporation and Continental Can Company Inc. v. Commission
    • ECJ, 21 February, 6-72, ECR [1973]-215
    • ECJ, Europemballage Corporation and Continental Can Company Inc. v. Commission, 21 February 1973, 6-72, ECR [1973]-215.
    • (1973)
  • 93
    • 33749998328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition Law of the European Community
    • In its ruling on the case, the Court of justice did not even mention the condition of competitive disadvantage in its judgment. See (Kluwer Law International)
    • In its ruling on the case, the Court of justice did not even mention the condition of competitive disadvantage in its judgment. See Van Bael & Bellis, supra n 18 at 917.
    • (2005) , pp. 917
    • Bael, V.1    Bellis2
  • 94
    • 33846808134 scopus 로고
    • Industrieverband Solnhofener Natursteinplatten eV
    • As it seems it has been read out from Article 81 (1) (d) EC. The extensive reliance on Article 82(c) for sanctioning primary line injuries price discrimination merely mirrors the evolution of case-law and decisional practice of the Commission under Article 81 (d), which forbids collusive discriminatory action in the same terms as Article 82 EC. In its decision Industrieverband, the Commission implicitly envisaged the application of the concept of discrimination in a primary line injury setting by holding that a collective aggregated sales bonus (i.e. a concerted bonus granted to all customers purchasing from the members of the association of undertakings) was placing "other suppliers at a competitive disadvantage, since they [had] to surmount an artificial, collectively erected barrier when supplying members' customers and this generates business for the members."
    • As it seems it has been read out from Article 81 (1) (d) EC. The extensive reliance on Article 82(c) for sanctioning primary line injuries price discrimination merely mirrors the evolution of case-law and decisional practice of the Commission under Article 81 (d), which forbids collusive discriminatory action in the same terms as Article 82 EC. In its decision Industrieverband, the Commission implicitly envisaged the application of the concept of discrimination in a primary line injury setting by holding that a collective aggregated sales bonus (i.e. a concerted bonus granted to all customers purchasing from the members of the association of undertakings) was placing "other suppliers at a competitive disadvantage, since they [had] to surmount an artificial, collectively erected barrier when supplying members' customers and this generates business for the members." On appeal before the Court, the Commission confirmed that it interpreted the discount at stake as a discriminatory practice. See Commission Decision 80/1074 of 16 October 1980, Industrieverband Solnhofener Natursteinplatten eV, OJ L 318 of 26 November 1980, pp. 32-9.
    • (1980) , pp. 32-39
  • 95
    • 33846819317 scopus 로고
    • Roofing felt
    • In a number of other decisions, the Commission applied similar principles. In Roofing Felt, for instance, the Commission sanctioned a concerted campaign against another manufacturer, IKO, to induce it to abandon a price-cutting policy, through application of discriminatory rebates. See Commission Decision 86/399 of 10 July 1986, OJ L 232 of 19 August
    • In a number of other decisions, the Commission applied similar principles. In Roofing Felt, for instance, the Commission sanctioned a concerted campaign against another manufacturer, IKO, to induce it to abandon a price-cutting policy, through application of discriminatory rebates. See Commission Decision 86/399 of 10 July 1986, Roofing felt, OJ L 232 of 19 August 1986, pp. 15-33.
    • (1986) , pp. 15-33
  • 96
    • 33846846961 scopus 로고
    • Meldoc
    • In Meldoc, the Commission sanctioned the concerted implementation of dumping prices to prevent imports from Belgium suppliers on the Dutch market for fresh milk. See Commission Decision 86/596 of 26 November 1986, OJ L 348 of 10 December
    • In Meldoc, the Commission sanctioned the concerted implementation of dumping prices to prevent imports from Belgium suppliers on the Dutch market for fresh milk. See Commission Decision 86/596 of 26 November 1986, Meldoc OJ L 348 of 10 December 1986, pp.50-65.
    • (1986) , pp. 50-65
  • 97
    • 33846783534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For instance, in the recent Deutsche Post AG case, the Commission justified its superficial assessment of the discriminatory conduct at stake by recalling the Tetra Pak II ruling pursuant to which "Article 82 may be applied even in the absence of a direct effect on competition." See Commission Decision, infra n 112
    • For instance, in the recent Deutsche Post AG case, the Commission justified its superficial assessment of the discriminatory conduct at stake by recalling the Tetra Pak II ruling pursuant to which "Article 82 may be applied even in the absence of a direct effect on competition." See Commission Decision, infra n 112 at 1§33.
  • 98
    • 33846796700 scopus 로고
    • Tetra Pak International SA v. Commission (Tetra Pak II)
    • See CFI, 6 October T-83/91, ECR [1994] II-755
    • See CFI, Tetra Pak International SA v. Commission (Tetra Pak II), 6 October 1994, T-83/91, ECR [1994] II-755.
    • (1994)
  • 99
    • 33846810440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compagnie Maritime Belge Transports SA (C-395/96 P), Compagnie Maritime Belge SA (C-395/96 P) and Dafra-Lines A/S (C-396/96 P) v. Commission
    • See ECJ, 16 March ECR [2000] I-1365
    • See ECJ, Compagnie Maritime Belge Transports SA (C-395/96 P), Compagnie Maritime Belge SA (C-395/96 P) and Dafra-Lines A/S (C-396/96 P) v. Commission, 16 March 2000, ECR [2000] I-1365 at 1§19.
    • (2000) , pp. 119
  • 100
    • 33846820858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30 and following
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30 at §§145 and following.
  • 101
    • 33846815803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra at Section V.B.2
    • See infra at Section V.B.2.
  • 102
    • 33846849875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Interestingly, the U.S. Robinson-Patman Act, which was historically adopted with the main aim of preventing price discrimination from damaging competition between downstream customers (secondary line effects), has also been applied from the start to primary line effects. The main difference between EC law and U.S. law, however, is that price discrimination in the U.S. has hardly been subject to enforcement since the 1980s.
  • 105
    • 33846811993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra n 31 who specifies as: "(i) defining a proper methodology for measuring costs in each industry ...; (ii) deciding how the costs savings can be attributed to each customer ...; and (iii) laying down what the appropriate time period for recovery of fixed costs shall be"
    • See D. Waelbroeck, supra n 31 at 158 who specifies as: "(i) defining a proper methodology for measuring costs in each industry ...; (ii) deciding how the costs savings can be attributed to each customer ...; and (iii) laying down what the appropriate time period for recovery of fixed costs shall be."
    • Waelbroeck, D.1
  • 107
    • 33846837907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • By contrast, if a firm with market power is forced to charge uniform prices, any price reduction it makes to get a marginal customer will make it lose some profits from the inframarginal customers who are prepared to pay a higher price. Thus, a firm with market power which can only impose a uniform price will select a price that many marginal customers will not be willing to pay even though they value the product more that the marginal cost of producing it. This clearly leads to allocative inefficiency.
  • 108
    • 33846848363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra n 3 A Most Favored Nation clause is a clause pursuant to which a contracting party commits itself to treating all its customers the same way, that is, to extend the benefit of any advantage offered to a customer to its other customers
    • See R. Posner, supra n 3 at 81. A Most Favored Nation clause is a clause pursuant to which a contracting party commits itself to treating all its customers the same way, that is, to extend the benefit of any advantage offered to a customer to its other customers.
    • Posner, R.1
  • 109
    • 33846804800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The frequently forgotten benefits of price discrimination"
    • See in Lawrence Wu, ed. (NERA Economic Consulting)
    • See Alan J. Cox, "The frequently forgotten benefits of price discrimination" in The Economics of Antitrust - New Issues, Questions and Insights, Lawrence Wu, ed. (NERA Economic Consulting, 2004) at 106.
    • (2004) The Economics of Antitrust - New Issues, Questions and Insights , pp. 106
    • Cox, A.J.1
  • 110
    • 33846798784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Airtours plc v. Commission
    • The CFI has held that a detection mechanism is a necessary condition for coordinated effects to occur in an oligopolistic market. See CFI, 6 June T-342/99, [2002] E.C.R. II-2585
    • The CFI has held that a detection mechanism is a necessary condition for coordinated effects to occur in an oligopolistic market. See CFI, Airtours plc v. Commission, 6 June 2002, T-342/99, [2002] E.C.R. II-2585 at 6§2
    • (2002) , pp. 62
  • 111
    • 33846834432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Laurent Piau v. Commission
    • and CFI, 18 March T-193/02, not yet published
    • and CFI, Laurent Piau v. Commission, 18 March 2005, T-193/02, not yet published at 1§11.
    • (2005) , pp. 111
  • 112
    • 33846848368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra n 79
    • See A. Cox, supra n 79 at 103-104.
    • Cox, A.1
  • 113
    • 33846830318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CFI, supra n 31 "The granting of a discount by an undertaking in a dominant position to a dealer must be based on an objective economic justification... It cannot depend on a subjective assessment by the undertaking in a dominant position of the extent to which the dealer has met his commitments and is thus entitled to a discount"
    • See CFI, supra n 31 at 1§40: "The granting of a discount by an undertaking in a dominant position to a dealer must be based on an objective economic justification... It cannot depend on a subjective assessment by the undertaking in a dominant position of the extent to which the dealer has met his commitments and is thus entitled to a discount."
  • 114
    • 33846785873 scopus 로고
    • Michelin I
    • See Commission Decision in 81/969 of 7 October supra n 44
    • See Commission Decision in Michelin I, 81/969 of 7 October 1981 supra n 44.
    • (1981)
  • 115
    • 33846845472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michelin I
    • The strictness of this position can be clearly observed from the following passage of the Commission Decision in "with the exception of short-term measures, no discount should be granted unless directly linked to a genuine reduction in the manufacturer's costs"
    • The strictness of this position can be clearly observed from the following passage of the Commission Decision in Michelin I at 5§4: "with the exception of short-term measures, no discount should be granted unless directly linked to a genuine reduction in the manufacturer's costs."
  • 116
    • 33846799758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OECD report on loyalty and fidelity discounts and rebates, DAFFE/COMP(2002)21 at ("Standard volume rebates tend to be a comparatively blunt instrument for encouraging customers to increase their purchases. Their existence is as much a reflection of large buyer power rather than any seller objective or initiative. Large buyers expect to obtain better terms than smaller buyers and they can often recognise that the seller's fixed cost recovery problem translates to a negotiating weakness when it comes to large buyers. For suppliers, even those who enjoy significant market power, who have low marginal costs of supply and high fixed costs, any threat of withdrawal of purchases or goodwill by a large buyer carries a significant business risk. Volume discounts are often a reaction to this risk")
    • See OECD report on loyalty and fidelity discounts and rebates, DAFFE/ COMP(2002)21 at p. 7 ("Standard volume rebates tend to be a comparatively blunt instrument for encouraging customers to increase their purchases. Their existence is as much a reflection of large buyer power rather than any seller objective or initiative. Large buyers expect to obtain better terms than smaller buyers and they can often recognise that the seller's fixed cost recovery problem translates to a negotiating weakness when it comes to large buyers. For suppliers, even those who enjoy significant market power, who have low marginal costs of supply and high fixed costs, any threat of withdrawal of purchases or goodwill by a large buyer carries a significant business risk. Volume discounts are often a reaction to this risk.")
  • 117
    • 33846834469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OECD report on loyalty and fidelity discounts and rebates, DAFFE/COMP(2002)21 at ("Standard volume rebates tend to be a comparatively blunt instrument for encouraging customers to increase their purchases. Their existence is as much a reflection of large buyer power rather than any seller objective or initiative. Large buyers expect to obtain better terms than smaller buyers and they can often recognise that the seller's fixed cost recovery problem translates to a negotiating weakness when it comes to large buyers. For suppliers, even those who enjoy significant market power, who have low marginal costs of supply and high fixed costs, any threat of withdrawal of purchases or goodwill by a large buyer carries a significant business risk. Volume discounts are often a reaction to this risk")
    • Id.
  • 119
    • 33846785874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Chapter II Prohibition
    • See OFT Guideline 402, The Chapter II Prohibition at 4§.15.
    • OFT Guideline 402
  • 120
    • 33846837908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Unlike ex ante control such in merger cases, ex post control under Article 82 EC involves matters where the effects of the allegedly anticompetitive conduct can generally be observed.
  • 121
    • 84856687100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • British Airways plc v Commission
    • See CFI, supra n 43
    • See CFI, British Airways plc v Commission, supra n 43.
  • 122
    • 33846841436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michelin II
    • See also CFI, supra n 31
    • See also CFI, Michelin II, supra n 31.
  • 123
    • 33846841436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michelin II
    • See CFI
    • See CFI, Michelin II, supra n 31 at 2§36
  • 124
    • 33846782057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and supra n 31
    • and D. Waelbroeck, supra n 31 at 159.
    • Waelbroeck, D.1
  • 125
    • 33846834475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses, December
    • See DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82, supra n 2 at §55.
    • (2005) , pp. 55
  • 126
    • 50349093037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "DG Comp's discussion paper on Article 82: Implications of the proposed framework and antitrust rules for dynamically competitive industries"
    • For a detailed account of this new framework, see et seq., available at
    • For a detailed account of this new framework, see Christian Ahlborn, Vincenzo Denicolò, Damien Geradin, & A. Jorge Padilla, "DG Comp's discussion paper on Article 82: Implications of the proposed framework and antitrust rules for dynamically competitive industries," at p. 35 et seq., available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=894466
    • Ahlborn, C.1    Denicolò, V.2    Geradin, D.3    Padilla, A.J.4
  • 127
    • 50349093037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "DG Comp's discussion paper on Article 82: Implications of the proposed framework and antitrust rules for dynamically competitive industries"
    • For a detailed account of this new framework, see et seq., available at
    • Id. at p. 37.
    • Ahlborn, C.1    Denicolò, V.2    Geradin, D.3    Padilla, A.J.4
  • 128
    • 33846834470 scopus 로고
    • Corsica Ferries Italia Srl v. Corpo dei Piloti del Porto di Genova
    • See ECJ, 17 May C-18/93, ECR [1994] I-1783
    • See ECJ, 17 May 1994, Corsica Ferries Italia Srl v. Corpo dei Piloti del Porto di Genova, C-18/93, ECR [1994] I-1783.
    • (1994)
  • 129
    • 33846834470 scopus 로고
    • Corsica Ferries Italia Srl v. Corpo dei Piloti del Porto di Genova
    • See ECJ, 17 May C-18/93, ECR [1994] I-1783
    • Id. at §45.
    • (1994) , pp. 45
  • 130
    • 33846827623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This ruling was subsequently confirmed by the Commission in a decision which condemned the Italian Republic for not complying with the ruling. See Commission Decision 97/745 of 21 October 1997, OJ L 301 of 5 November
    • This ruling was subsequently confirmed by the Commission in a decision which condemned the Italian Republic for not complying with the ruling. See Commission Decision 97/745 of 21 October 1997, OJ L 301 of 5 November 1997, pp. 27-35.
    • (1997) , pp. 27-35
  • 131
    • 33846834474 scopus 로고
    • Opinion of Advocate General Van Gerven delivered on 9 February under C-18/93 ECR [1994] I-1783
    • See Opinion of Advocate General Van Gerven delivered on 9 February 1994 under C-18/93, ECR [1994] I-1783 at 1§9.
    • (1994) , pp. 19
  • 132
    • 33846817779 scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision 95/364 of 28 June 1995 OJ, L 216 of 12 September
    • See Commission Decision 95/364 of 28 June 1995 OJ, L 216 of 12 September 1995, pp. 8-14.
    • (1995) , pp. 8-14
  • 133
    • 33846797203 scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision 95/364 of 28 June 1995 OJ, L 216 of 12 September
    • Id. at 1§7.
    • (1995) , pp. 17
  • 134
    • 33846817778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Portuguese Airports
    • See Commission Decision 1999/199 of 10 February 1999, OJ L 69 of 16 March at 2§6
    • See Commission Decision 1999/199 of 10 February 1999, Portuguese Airports, OJ L 69 of 16 March 1999, pp. 31-39 at 2§6.
    • (1999) , pp. 31-39
  • 135
    • 33846815804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A similar line of reasoning was followed in a decision concerning the landing charges applied by the Spanish Airport Authorities, see Commission Decision 2000/521 of 26 July 2000, OJ L 208 of 18 August at §§48-53
    • similar line of reasoning was followed in a decision concerning the landing charges applied by the Spanish Airport Authorities, see Commission Decision 2000/521 of 26 July 2000, OJ L 208 of 18 August 2000, pp. 36-46 at §§48-53.
    • (2000) , pp. 36-46
  • 136
    • 33846785876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ilmailulaitos/Luftfarsverket
    • See Commission Decision 1999/98 of 10 February 1999, OJ L 69 of 16 March
    • See Commission Decision 1999/98 of 10 February 1999, Ilmailulaitos/ Luftfarsverket, OJ L 69 of 16 March 1999, pp. 24-30
    • (1999) , pp. 24-30
  • 137
    • 33846849878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Portuguese Airports
    • and Commission Decision 1999/199, supra n 98
    • and Commission Decision 1999/199, Portuguese Airports, supra n 98.
  • 138
    • 33846817775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alpha Flight Services/Aéroports de Paris
    • See Commission Decision, 98/153 of 11 June 1998, OJ L 230 of 18 August
    • See Commission Decision, 98/153 of 11 June 1998, Alpha Flight Services/ Aéroports de Paris, OJ L 230 of 18 August 1998, pp. 10-27.
    • (1998) , pp. 10-27
  • 139
    • 33846827659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OAT global fee's structure was, however, slightly different
    • OAT global fee's structure was, however, slightly different.
  • 140
    • 33846784339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OAT global fee's structure was, however, slightly different. at §§119
    • Id at §§119 and 121.
  • 141
    • 33846783563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OAT global fee's structure was, however, slightly different. of Commission Decision
    • Id. at 1§26 of Commission Decision.
  • 142
    • 33846782054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aéroports de Paris v. Commission
    • Confirmed by CFI, 12 December T-128/98 [2000] ECR II-3929
    • Confirmed by CFI, Aéroports de Paris v. Commission, 12 December 2000, T-128/98 [2000] ECR II-3929
    • (2000)
  • 143
    • 33846798785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aéroports de Paris v. Commission
    • and ECJ, 24 October C-82/01, ECR [2002] I-9297
    • and ECJ, Aéroports de Paris v. Commission, 24 October 2002, C-82/01, ECR [2002] I-9297.
    • (2002)
  • 144
    • 33846814226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Case COMP/A.36.568/D3 - Scandlines Sverige AB v. Port of Helsingborg
    • See Commission Decision, 23 July
    • See Commission Decision, 23 July 2004, Case COMP/A.36.568/D3 - Scandlines Sverige AB v. Port of Helsingborg.
    • (2004)
  • 145
    • 33846814226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Case COMP/A.36.568/D3 - Scandlines Sverige AB v. Port of Helsingborg
    • See Commission Decision, 23 July, The port of Helsinborg was operated by Helsinborg Hamn AB, a subdidiary of the City of Helsinborg
    • Id. at 1§1. The port of Helsinborg was operated by Helsinborg Hamn AB, a subdidiary of the City of Helsinborg.
    • (2004) , pp. 11
  • 146
    • 33846814226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Case COMP/A.36.568/D3 - Scandlines Sverige AB v. Port of Helsingborg
    • See Commission Decision, 23 July, The port of Helsinborg was operated by Helsinborg Hamn AB, a subdidiary of the City of Helsinborg
    • Id. at 1§9.
    • (2004) , pp. 19
  • 147
    • 33846814226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Case COMP/A.36.568/D3 - Scandlines Sverige AB v. Port of Helsingborg
    • §§252 Commission Decision, 23 July, Note that the prices of the sea services (similar for both kinds of operators) were equivalent
    • Id. at §§252 and 278. Note that the prices of the sea services (similar for both kinds of operators) were equivalent.
    • (2004) , pp. 278
  • 148
    • 33846814226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Case COMP/A.36.568/D3 - Scandlines Sverige AB v. Port of Helsingborg
    • Commission Decision, 23 July, Without any equivalence in the services provided, the assessment of the pricing policies was therefore pointless
    • Id. at 2§79. Without any equivalence in the services provided, the assessment of the pricing policies was therefore pointless.
    • (2004) , pp. 279
  • 149
    • 33846806378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§257
    • §§257 and 284.
  • 150
    • 33846827660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 2§86.
  • 151
    • 33846848365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deutsche Bahn AG v. Commission
    • See CFI, T-229/94, ECR [1997] II-1689
    • See CFI, Deutsche Bahn AG v. Commission, T-229/94, ECR [1997] II-1689 at 9§3.
  • 152
    • 33846782055 scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision 94/210 of 29 March 1994, HOV-SVZ/MCN, OJ L 104 of 23 April at 2§54
    • See Commission Decision 94/210 of 29 March 1994, HOV-SVZ/MCN, OJ L 104 of 23 April 1994, pp. 34-57 at 2§54.
    • (1994) , pp. 34-57
  • 153
    • 33846798786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CFI, supra n 104
    • See CFI, supra n 104 at 9§0.
  • 154
    • 33846819318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CFI
    • Id. at 9§1.
  • 155
    • 33846804801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See XXVIIth report on Competition Policy, and Commission press release, IP/97/292 of 11 April 1997, "Settlement reached with Belgacom on the publication of telephone directories - ITT withdraws complaint"
    • See XXVIIth report on Competition Policy, 1997 at 6§7 and Commission press release, IP/97/292 of 11 April 1997, "Settlement reached with Belgacom on the publication of telephone directories - ITT withdraws complaint."
    • (1997) , pp. 67
  • 156
    • 33846806383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deutsche Post AG - Interception of cross-border mail
    • See Commission Decision 2001/892 of 25 July 2001, 331 of 15 December
    • See Commission Decision 2001/892 of 25 July 2001, Deutsche Post AG - Interception of cross-border mail, OJ L 331 of 15 December 2001, pp. 40-78.
    • (2001) OJ L , pp. 40-78
  • 157
    • 33846817776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clearstream
    • See Commission Decision of 2 June COMP/38.096, not yet published
    • See Commission Decision of 2 June 2004, Clearstream, COMP/38.096, not yet published.
    • (2004)
  • 158
    • 33846811994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ICSDs are organizations whose core business are clearing and settling securities (traditionally Eurobonds) in an international (nondomestic) environment.
  • 159
    • 33846849876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • As well as Article 86(1). See Commission Decision of 20 October COMP/38.745, not yet published
    • As well as Article 86(1). See Commission Decision of 20 October 2004, COMP/38.745, BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland, not yet published.
    • (2004)
  • 160
    • 33846837911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • As well as Article 86(1). See Commission Decision of 20 October COMP/38.745, not yet published
    • Id. at 6§0.
    • (2004) , pp. 60
  • 161
    • 33846841439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • As well as Article 86(1). See Commission Decision of 20 October COMP/38.745, not yet published
    • Id. at 9§4.
    • (2004) , pp. 94
  • 162
    • 33846846959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Portuguese Republic v. Commission
    • In fact, in many of the cases, the reference to the national discrimination was not mentioned in the review of Article 82(c). This is particularly manifest in the appeal of the Commission's decision in Portuguese Airports before the ECJ. The appellant observed that the various measures at stake did not discriminate on the grounds of nationality because they were not dependent on the nationality of the airlines. The Court conceded that Article 82(c) applied to the application of dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions irrespective of the existence of discrimination on the ground of nationality. See ECJ, C-163/99, 29 March ECR [2001] I-2613
    • In fact, in many of the cases, the reference to the national discrimination was not mentioned in the review of Article 82(c). This is particularly manifest in the appeal of the Commission's decision in Portuguese Airports before the ECJ. The appellant observed that the various measures at stake did not discriminate on the grounds of nationality because they were not dependent on the nationality of the airlines. The Court conceded that Article 82(c) applied to the application of dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions irrespective of the existence of discrimination on the ground of nationality. See ECJ, Portuguese Republic v. Commission, C-163/99, 29 March 2001, ECR [2001] I-2613 at 4§6.
    • (2001) , pp. 46
  • 163
    • 33846834470 scopus 로고
    • Corsica Ferries Italia Srl v. Corpo dei Piloti del Porto di Genova
    • The Court preferred to rely on an objective economic assessment of the forbidden measures. The Court only mentioned in passing that the discount system favored the national airlines (see 5§6). As far as the discounts were concerned, it referred to Michelin and observed that the mere fact that the system was correlated to the volume of purchases could not lead to the conclusion that there was discrimination. The Court, however, observed that the nonlinear progression of the discount only allowed two large companies to obtain it and that there was no objective justification for it (the Court did not make any explicit pronouncement as to the value of economics of scale in terms of justification). As far as the differentiation between domestic and international fees were concerned, the Court held that it led to applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions because different tariffs were charged for the same number of landings of similar aircraft (see 6§6).
    • The Court preferred to rely on an objective economic assessment of the forbidden measures. The Court only mentioned in passing that the discount system favored the national airlines (see 5§6). As far as the discounts were concerned, it referred to Michelin and observed that the mere fact that the system was correlated to the volume of purchases could not lead to the conclusion that there was discrimination. The Court, however, observed that the nonlinear progression of the discount only allowed two large companies to obtain it and that there was no objective justification for it (the Court did not make any explicit pronouncement as to the value of economics of scale in terms of justification). As far as the differentiation between domestic and international fees were concerned, the Court held that it led to applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions because different tariffs were charged for the same number of landings of similar aircraft (see 6§6). A similar approach had been followed by the Court in Corsica Ferries II, where the question of the discrimination on the ground of nationality had not been evoked under Article 82c, but with respect to the issue of the freedom to provide services, where the Court had held that: "The system gives preferential treatment to vessels permitted to engage in maritime cabotage, in other words, those flying the Italian flag... Such a system indirectly discriminates between economic operators according to their nationality, since vessels flying the national flag are generally operated by national economic operators, whereas transport undertakings from other Member States as a rule do not operate ships registered in the State applying that system." ECJ, Corsica Ferries Italia Srl v. Corpo dei Piloti del Porto di Genova, 17 May 1994, C-18/93ECR [1994] I-1783 at §§32-33.
    • (1994) , pp. 32-33
  • 164
    • 33846814227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Article 12 EC condemns discrimination on grounds of nationality: "Within the scope of application of this Treaty, and without prejudice to any special provisions contained therein, any discrimination on grounds of nationality shall be prohibited."
  • 165
    • 33846837909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra at Section V.B.2
    • See A. Cox, supra n 79 at p. 105.
    • Cox, A.1
  • 166
    • 33846827661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • condition for this would be that the buyer enjoys market power downstream. A buyer with market power that wants to gain a competitive advantage downstream may be able to insist on a large discount compared with what the sellers charge other buyers who compete with the powerful buyer downstream.
  • 167
    • 33846849877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a case of this kind, it can be safely assumed that the seller has no market power and takes the price of the big purchaser.
  • 168
    • 18444397275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is assumed here that the downstream rivals of the vertically integrated firm are active in the same product market. As M. Motta observes, in the case of a vertically integrated operator, if the downstream rivals are active in slightly different product markets from the downstream integrated business, supplying them at higher prices would entail foregoing profits because (i) the downstream firm's share remains unchanged and (ii) demand for the output diminishes with a consequent loss of profits. Thus, there would be no incentive to price discriminate in such a setting. See (Cambridge University Press)
    • It is assumed here that the downstream rivals of the vertically integrated firm are active in the same product market. As M. Motta observes, in the case of a vertically integrated operator, if the downstream rivals are active in slightly different product markets from the downstream integrated business, supplying them at higher prices would entail foregoing profits because (i) the downstream firm's share remains unchanged and (ii) demand for the output diminishes with a consequent loss of profits. Thus, there would be no incentive to price discriminate in such a setting. See M. Motta, supra n 6 at 373.
    • (2004) Competition Policy - Theory and Practice , pp. 373
    • Motta, M.1
  • 169
    • 0032368948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The incentive for non-price discrimination by an input monopolist"
    • See at 283 A similar view has been expressed by Thomas Krattenmaker ans Steven Salop, who explained that a downstream firm may often try to raise its rivals' costs in order to foreclose rivals in asking a bottleneck monopolist to only deal with rivals on discriminatory terms (i.e. a practice referred to as the bottleneck method). This was the situation at stake in the famous Terminal Railroad case in the United States
    • See Nicholas Economides, "The incentive for non-price discrimination by an input monopolist," 16 International Journal of Industrial Organization 271 (1998) at 283. A similar view has been expressed by Thomas Krattenmaker ans Steven Salop, who explained that a downstream firm may often try to raise its rivals' costs in order to foreclose rivals in asking a bottleneck monopolist to only deal with rivals on discriminatory terms (i.e. a practice referred to as the bottleneck method). This was the situation at stake in the famous Terminal Railroad case in the United States.
    • (1998) International Journal of Industrial Organization , vol.16 , pp. 271
    • Economides, N.1
  • 170
    • 84934452640 scopus 로고
    • "Anticompetitive exclusion: Raising rivals' costs to achieve power over price"
    • at 235
    • See Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop, "Anticompetitive exclusion: Raising rivals' costs to achieve power over price," 2 Yale Law Journal 209 (1986) at 235.
    • (1986) Yale Law Journal , vol.2 , pp. 209
    • Krattenmaker, T.G.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 173
    • 33846822353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DG Commission Decision Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses, December
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 100 at 1§09.
    • (2005) , pp. 109
  • 174
    • 33846801792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Guidelines on the Assessment of Horizontal Mergers under the Council Regulation on the Control of Concentrations between Undertakings, OJ C 31 of 5 February at 4§8
    • See Commission Guidelines on the Assessment of Horizontal Mergers under the Council Regulation on the Control of Concentrations between Undertakings, OJ C 31 of 5 February 2004, pp. 5-18 at 4§8.
    • (2004) , pp. 5-18
  • 175
    • 33846820859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is likely to be a minimal concern where access costs are a limited share of the average total costs.
  • 176
    • 33846808132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis Trinko
    • In stark contrast with the U.S. Supreme Court, this again recently mentioned these collusive risks in Trinko. See LLP, 13 January
    • In stark contrast with the U.S. Supreme Court, this again recently mentioned these collusive risks in Trinko. See Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis Trinko, LLP, 13 January 2004, 540 U.S.
    • (2004) U.S. , vol.540
  • 179
    • 33846796700 scopus 로고
    • Tetra Pak International SA v. Commission
    • See CFI, 6 October T-83/91 ECR [1994] II-755
    • See CFI, Tetra Pak International SA v. Commission, 6 October 1994, T-83/ 91 ECR [1994] II-755
    • (1994)
  • 180
    • 33846806381 scopus 로고
    • Tetra Pak II
    • and Commission Decision 92/163 of 24 July 1991 OJ L 72 of 18 March There were also a number of discrimination elements in the case which were not concerned with geographic price discrimination, but which related to price discrimination, within the Italian market, between users. See 1§58, 160, 161, 62-8 of the Decision
    • and Commission Decision 92/163 of 24 July 1991 Tetra Pak II, OJ L 72 of 18 March 1992, pp. 1-68. There were also a number of discrimination elements in the case which were not concerned with geographic price discrimination, but which related to price discrimination, within the Italian market, between users. See 1§58, 160, 161, 62-8 of the Decision.
    • (1992) , pp. 1-68
  • 181
    • 33846849876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • See Commission Decision of 20 October, COMP/38.745, Tetra Pak was indeed facing fierce competition from Elopak in Italy
    • See Commission Decision supra n 129 at 5§2. Tetra Pak was indeed facing fierce competition from Elopak in Italy.
    • (2004) , pp. 52
  • 182
    • 33846848366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CFI, supra n 129
    • See CFI, supra n 129 at 1§70
  • 183
    • 33846849876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • and Commission Decision of 20 October, COMP/38.745
    • and Commission Decision, supra n 129 at 1§60.
    • (2004) , pp. 160
  • 184
    • 33846804805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CFI supra n 129
    • See CFI supra n 129 at 1§71
  • 185
    • 33846849876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • and Commission Decision of 20 October, COMP/38.745
    • and Commission supra n 129 at 1§60.
    • (2004)
  • 186
    • 33846841440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CFI supra n 129
    • See CFI supra n 129 at 1§73.
  • 187
    • 33846839916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BdKEP/Deutsche Post AG and Bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • Two clauses in the contract limited the purchaser's right to resell or transfer the equipment to third parties: A first claus (referred to as clause xv) provided "the purchaser is required to obtain Tetra Park's agreement before selling or transferring the use of the equipment (Italy), resale is subject to conditions (Spain), and Tetra Park reserves the right to repurchase the equipment at a pre-arranged fixed price (all countries); failure to comply with this clause may give rise to a specific penelty (Greece, Ireland, United Kingdom)." A second clause (referred to as clause xvi) provided: "the purchaser must ensure that any third party to whom he resells the aquipment assumes all his obligations (Italy, Spain)." In its decision the Commission held that "The requirement that the purchaser obtain Tetra Pak's agreement before he can exercise his right to dispose of an asset in his property or even to transfer its use [...]
    • Two clauses in the contract limited the purchaser's right to resell or transfer the equipment to third parties: A first claus (referred to as clause xv) provided "the purchaser is required to obtain Tetra Park's agreement before selling or transferring the use of the equipment (Italy), resale is subject to conditions (Spain), and Tetra Park reserves the right to repurchase the equipment at a pre-arranged fixed price (all countries); failure to comply with this clause may give rise to a specific penelty (Greece, Ireland, United Kingdom)." A second clause (referred to as clause xvi) provided: "the purchaser must ensure that any third party to whom he resells the aquipment assumes all his obligations (Italy, Spain)." In its decision the Commission held that "The requirement that the purchaser obtain Tetra Pak's agreement before he can exercise his right to dispose of an asset in his property or even to transfer its use (Italy) not only has no connection with the purpose of the previously signed sales contract but also, in view of the effect it has on the very essence of the right of ownership, constitutes an unfair condition of the transaction... The conditions prohibit export of the machine and forbid third parties which are potential purchasers from being offered conditions of resale which more favorable than those which apply to Tetra Pak. Such conditions directly affect trade between the Member States and again limit the purchaser's outlets... Tetra Pak's automatic right of pre-emption must in itself be considered to constitute an abuse in so far as it again unduly limits the ability of the user, who does after all own the machine, to dispose of his asset as he wishes, and constitutes one of the instruments by which Tetra Pak is able to compartmentalize national markets... Requirement to ensure that any third party purchasing equipment assume the obligations of the third party accepts a series of obligations which themselves constitute abuse." See Commission Decision, supra n 129 at §§123-8.
    • (2004) , pp. 123-128
  • 188
    • 33846839915 scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision 84/379 of 2 July 1984, BL, OJ L 207 of 2 August
    • See Commission Decision 84/379 of 2 July 1984, BL, OJ L 207 of 2 August 1984, pp. 11-16.
    • (1984) , pp. 11-16
  • 189
    • 33846804802 scopus 로고
    • British Leyland plc v. Commission
    • Confirmed implicitly by the ECJ on appeal, 226/84, 11 November ECR [1986]-3263
    • Confirmed implicitly by the ECJ on appeal, 226/84, British Leyland plc v. Commission, 11 November 1986, ECR [1986]-3263.
    • (1986)
  • 190
    • 33846845473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 135
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 135 at 2§6.
  • 191
    • 33846783566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Decision, supra, n 135
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 135 at 2§9.
  • 192
    • 33846837912 scopus 로고
    • Europemballage Corporation and Continental Can Company Inc. v. Commission
    • See Commission Decision, 21 February ECR [1973]-215
    • See Commission Decision, supra n 30 at 1§29.
    • (1973) , pp. 129
  • 193
    • 33846837912 scopus 로고
    • Europemballage Corporation and Continental Can Company Inc. v. Commission
    • See CFI, 21 February ECR [1973]-215 In addition, the export rebates (granted to Irish Sugar's customers exporting sugar in processed form to other Member states) seemed designed to make sure that its customers contemplating sourcing to foreign suppliers would not switch to the latter in order to obtain supplies
    • See CFI, supra n 54 at 1§83. In addition, the export rebates (granted to Irish Sugar's customers exporting sugar in processed form to other Member states) seemed designed to make sure that its customers contemplating sourcing to foreign suppliers would not switch to the latter in order to obtain supplies.
    • (1973) , pp. 183
  • 194
    • 33846806380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CFI
    • See CFI at 1§39.
  • 195
    • 33846799757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Notice - Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, OJ C 291 of 13 October at 1§14 that concerns market partitioning groups, that is, agreements whose main element is that the buyer is restricted in where he either sources or resells a particular product
    • See Commission Notice - Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, OJ C 291 of 13 October 2000, pp. 1-44 at 1§14 that concerns market partitioning groups, that is, agreements whose main element is that the buyer is restricted in where he either sources or resells a particular product.
    • (2000) , pp. 1-44
  • 196
    • 33846804803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Notice - Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, OJ C 291 of 13 October that concerns market partitioning groups, that is, agreements whose main element is that the buyer is restricted in where he either sources or resells a particular product "In an exclusive distribution agreement the supplier agrees to sell his products only to one distributor for resale in a particular territory. At the same time the distributor is usually limited in his active selling into other exclusively allocated territories. The possible competition risks are mainly reduced intra-brand competition and market partitioning, which may in particular facilitate price discrimination"
    • Id. at 1§61: "In an exclusive distribution agreement the supplier agrees to sell his products only to one distributor for resale in a particular territory. At the same time the distributor is usually limited in his active selling into other exclusively allocated territories. The possible competition risks are mainly reduced intra-brand competition and market partitioning, which may in particular facilitate price discrimination."
    • (2000) , pp. 161
  • 197
    • 33846795172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commission Notice - Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, OJ C 291 of October, "In an exclusive distribution agreement the supplier agrees to sell his products only to one distributor for resale in a particular territory. At the same time the distributor is usually limited in his active selling into other exclusively allocated territories. The possible competition risks are mainly reduced intra-brand competition and market partitioning, which may in particular facilitate price discrimination" "The combination of exclusive distribution with exclusive purchasing increases the possible competition risks of reduced intra-brand competition and market partitioning which may in particular facilitate price discrimination"
    • Id. at 1§72: "The combination of exclusive distribution with exclusive purchasing increases the possible competition risks of reduced intra-brand competition and market partitioning which may in particular facilitate price discrimination."
    • (2000) , pp. 172
  • 198
    • 33846819315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Notice - Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, OJ C 291 of 13 October "In an exclusive customer allocation agreement, the supplier agrees to sell his products only to one distributor for resale to a particular class of customers. At the same time, the distributor is usually limited in his active selling to other exclusively allocated classes of customers. The possible competition risks are mainly reduced intra-brand competition and market partitioning, which may in particular facilitate price discrimination"
    • See 1§78: "In an exclusive customer allocation agreement, the supplier agrees to sell his products only to one distributor for resale to a particular class of customers. At the same time, the distributor is usually limited in his active selling to other exclusively allocated classes of customers. The possible competition risks are mainly reduced intra-brand competition and market partitioning, which may in particular facilitate price discrimination."
    • (2000) , pp. 178
  • 199
    • 33846806379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Notice - Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer agreements, OJ C 101 of 27 April at 1§88: "there are two main competitive risks stemming from captive use restrictions: (a) a restriction of intra-technology competition on the market for the supply of inputs and (b) an exclusion of arbitrage between licensees enhancing the possibility for the licensor to impose discriminatory royalties on licensees. "See also 1§86 which explains what a captive use restriction is: "In other words, this type of use restriction takes the form of an obligation on the licensee to use the products incorporating the licensed technology only as an input for incorporation into his own production; it does not cover the sale of the licensed product for incorporation into the products of other producers"
    • See Commission Notice - Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer agreements, OJ C 101 of 27 April 2004, pp. 2-42at 1§88: "there are two main competitive risks stemming from captive use restrictions: (a) a restriction of intra-technology competition on the market for the supply of inputs and (b) an exclusion of arbitrage between licensees enhancing the possibility for the licensor to impose discriminatory royalties on licensees. "See also 1§86 which explains what a captive use restriction is: "In other words, this type of use restriction takes the form of an obligation on the licensee to use the products incorporating the licensed technology only as an input for incorporation into his own production; it does not cover the sale of the licensed product for incorporation into the products of other producers."
    • (2004) , pp. 2-42
  • 200
    • 33846809749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commission Notice - Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer agreements, OJ C 101 of April "there are two main competitive risks stemming from captive use restrictions: (a) a restriction of intra-technology competition on the market for the supply of inputs and (b) an exclusion of arbitrage between licensees enhancing the possibility for the licensor to impose discriminatory royalties on licensees" "quantity limitations are used to implement an underlying market partitioning agreement. Indications thereof include the adjustment of quantities over time to cover only local demand, the combination of quantity limitations and an obligation to sell minimum quantities in the territory"
    • Id. at 9§8: "quantity limitations are used to implement an underlying market partitioning agreement. Indications thereof include the adjustment of quantities over time to cover only local demand, the combination of quantity limitations and an obligation to sell minimum quantities in the territory."
    • (2004) , pp. 98
  • 201
    • 33846784342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Opel Nederland BV/General Motors Nederland BV
    • See, e.g., Commission Decision of 20 September 2000, 28 February
    • See, e.g., Commission Decision of 20 September 2000, Opel Nederland BV/ General Motors Nederland BV, OJ L 59, 28 February 2001, pp. 1-42
    • (2001) OJ L 59 , pp. 1-42
  • 202
    • 33846784341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • General Motors Nederland and Opel Nederland v. Commission
    • and CFI, T-368/00, 21 October ECR [2003] II-4491 (partial annulment)
    • and CFI, T-368/00, 21 October 2003, General Motors Nederland and Opel Nederland v. Commission, ECR [2003] II-4491 (partial annulment);
    • (2003)
  • 203
    • 33846810475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Volkswagen v. Commission
    • CFI, T-62/98, 6 July ECR [2000] II-2707
    • CFI, T-62/98, 6 July 2000, Volkswagen v. Commission, ECR [2000] II-2707.
    • (2000)
  • 204
    • 33846811995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bayer AG v. Commission
    • See CFI, 26 October T-41/96ECR 2000 II-3383
    • See CFI, Bayer AG v. Commission, 26 October 2000, T-41/96ECR 2000 II-3383 at 7§1;
    • (2000) , pp. 71
  • 205
    • 33846837910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bundesverband der Arzneimittel-Importeure eV and Commission v. Bayer AG
    • ECJ, 6 January C-2/01 P and C-3/01 P, ECR [2004] I-23 §§101
    • ECJ, Bundesverband der Arzneimittel-Importeure eV and Commission v. Bayer AG, 6 January 2004, C-2/01 P and C-3/01 P, ECR [2004] I-23 at §§101 and 141.
    • (2004) , pp. 141
  • 206
    • 33846819316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Micro Leader Business v. Commission
    • The ruling of the CFI in Micro Leader Business seems also to support this view. See CFI, 16 December T-198/98, ECR [1999] II-3989
    • The ruling of the CFI in Micro Leader Business seems also to support this view. See CFI, Micro Leader Business v. Commission, 16 December 1999, T-198/98, ECR [1999] II-3989 at 5§6.
    • (1999) , pp. 56
  • 207
    • 33846811996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bayer AG v. Commission
    • See CFI, supra n 146
    • See CFI, Bayer AG v. Commission, supra n 146 at 1§76.
  • 208
    • 33846798787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Syfait and Others v. GlaxoSmithKline plc
    • ECJ, 31 May C-53/03, not yet published. Note in addition that a gap in the EC competition system exists where, as the CFI held in Bayer, a supplier restricts parallel trade "without abusing a dominant position, and there is no concurrence of wills between him." This can, for instance, arise if the supplier is vertically integrated and does not enjoy a dominant position on the market. The Court seems to recognize that, in such situation, "a manufacturer may adopt the supply policy which he considers necessary, even if, by the very nature of its aim, for example, to hinder parallel imports, the implementation of that policy may entail restrictions on competition and affect trade between Member States"
    • ECJ, Syfait and Others v. GlaxoSmithKline plc, 31 May 2005, C-53/03, not yet published. Note in addition that a gap in the EC competition system exists where, as the CFI held in Bayer, a supplier restricts parallel trade "without abusing a dominant position, and there is no concurrence of wills between him." This can, for instance, arise if the supplier is vertically integrated and does not enjoy a dominant position on the market. The Court seems to recognize that, in such situation, "a manufacturer may adopt the supply policy which he considers necessary, even if, by the very nature of its aim, for example, to hinder parallel imports, the implementation of that policy may entail restrictions on competition and affect trade between Member States."
    • (2005)
  • 209
    • 33846811996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bayer AG v. Commission
    • See CFI, supra n 146. However, this question falls outside the scope of this article, which is only concerned with the scope of the liability imposed by Article 82 EC on dominant firms
    • See CFI, Bayer AG v. Commission, supra n 146 at 1§76. However, this question falls outside the scope of this article, which is only concerned with the scope of the liability imposed by Article 82 EC on dominant firms.
  • 210
    • 33846848367 scopus 로고
    • Nestlé/Perrier
    • As implicitly confirmed in the Commission Notice on the definition of the relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law, OJ C 372 of 9 December 1997, and more explicitly by the Commission in its market definition practice. See, e.g., Commission Decision 92/ 553 of 22 July 1992, OJ L 356 of 5 December
    • As implicitly confirmed in the Commission Notice on the definition of the relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law, OJ C 372 of 9 December 1997, and more explicitly by the Commission in its market definition practice. See, e.g., Commission Decision 92/ 553 of 22 July 1992, Nestlé/Perrier, OJ L 356 of 5 December 1992, pp. 1-31.
    • (1992) , pp. 1-31
  • 211
    • 33846784340 scopus 로고
    • Corinne Bodson v. SA Pompes funèbres des régions libérées
    • In that respect, the Court held in Bodson that price differences in different locations may provide a basis for assessing whether or not the prices charged are excessive pursuant to Article 82(a). See ECJ, 4 May 30/87, ECR [1988]-2479
    • In that respect, the Court held in Bodson that price differences in different locations may provide a basis for assessing whether or not the prices charged are excessive pursuant to Article 82(a). See ECJ, Corinne Bodson v. SA Pompes funèbres des régions libérées, 4 May 1988, 30/87, ECR [1988]-2479.
    • (1988)
  • 212
    • 33846808133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As well as the clauses preventing resale of Tetra Pak's machines in Tetra Pak II
    • As well as the clauses preventing resale of Tetra Pak's machines in Tetra Pak II.
  • 213
    • 33846782053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United Brands Company v. Commission
    • Another passage of the ECJ's judgment was quite problematic. Indeed, while the ECJ acknowledged that "differences in transport costs, taxation, customs duties, the wages of the labor force, the conditions of marketing, the differences in the parity of currencies, the density of competition may eventually culminate in different retail selling price levels according to the Member States," it also stated that those differences were factors which UBC could only take into account to a limited extent since it was selling an identical product at an identical place to ripeners/distributors who alone "bear the risks of the consumers' market" (see ECJ, supra n 14) This part of the decision was not only criticized for the fact that it was not true that only ripeners/distributors bore the risks of the market, but also because it created incentives to operators, such as UBC, to vertically integrate production and retailing functions.
    • Another passage of the ECJ's judgment was quite problematic. Indeed, while the ECJ acknowledged that "differences in transport costs, taxation, customs duties, the wages of the labor force, the conditions of marketing, the differences in the parity of currencies, the density of competition may eventually culminate in different retail selling price levels according to the Member States," it also stated that those differences were factors which UBC could only take into account to a limited extent since it was selling an identical product at an identical place to ripeners/distributors who alone "bear the risks of the consumers' market" (see ECJ, United Brands Company v. Commission, supra n 14 at 2§28). This part of the decision was not only criticized for the fact that it was not true that only ripeners/distributors bore the risks of the market, but also because it created incentives to operators, such as UBC, to vertically integrate production and retailing functions. Indeed, the Court judgment led to the odd situation that, while operators which combined production and retailing functions could take demand considerations to differentiate prices, a nonvertically integrated operator, such as UBC, could not do so.
  • 214
    • 84979110465 scopus 로고
    • "Price discrimination under Article 86: Political economy in the European Court"
    • 282
    • See William Bishop, "Price discrimination under Article 86: Political economy in the European Court," 44 Modern Law Review 282 (1981) at 288-9.
    • (1981) Modern Law Review , vol.44 , pp. 288-289
    • Bishop, W.1
  • 215
    • 33846834472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra n 6
    • See M. Motta, supra n 6 at 492.
    • Motta, M.1
  • 216
    • 33846809750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EC Competition law forbids, in that respect, restriction to passive sales. It does not, however, prohibit restrictions to active sales inserted within exclusive distribution agreements. See §§49 and 50 of the Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, supra n 140
    • EC Competition law forbids, in that respect, restriction to passive sales. It does not, however, prohibit restrictions to active sales inserted within exclusive distribution agreements. See §§49 and 50 of the Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, supra n 140.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.