메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 23, Issue 1, 2006, Pages 231-254

The uneven results of institutional changes in central and Eastern Europe: The role of culture

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 33644917691     PISSN: 02650525     EISSN: 14716437     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0265052506060109     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (15)

References (58)
  • 1
    • 33644920008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The end of socialism in Central and Eastern Europe in the late 1980s opened the region to an influx of new ideas and opportunities. Indeed, everybody wanted a piece of the action. Overnight, former dissidents became political leaders and social innovators. The old ruling elite quickly forgot "the laws of history" and has been trying to find ways to retain power and influence. Western politicians saw an opportunity to extend the political and economic influence of their countries. Western businesses eyed new markets. Western scholars realized that social changes in C&EE were likely to create enormous opportunities for research grants, promotions, and publications in academic journals. In an about-face, many academics from the West who used to preach socialism, economic planning, and all sorts of industrial democracy schemes joined their free-market colleagues in supporting the process of transition to capitalism. In order to "strengthen" their grant proposals and submissions to academic journals, Western scholars needed cooperation from their colleagues in C&EE, and they had no problem getting that support. In exchange for funding, travel, and possible visiting appointments in the West, many scholars from C&EE were eager to join their Western colleagues on projects they privately considered irrelevant.
  • 2
    • 33644889445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The twentieth century experienced two major applications of socialism: National Socialism, and Marxism-Leninism or communism. Those two brands of socialism were equally unrelenting in their oppression of inferior races and the bourgeoisie, respectively. It is perfectly legitimate to refer to C&EE countries as either former socialist or former communist countries.
  • 3
    • 0000432745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the relationship between economic freedom and economic growth
    • See, for example, Jacob de Haan and Jan Sturm, "On the Relationship between Economic Freedom and Economic Growth," European Journal of Political Economy 16 (2000): 215-41;
    • (2000) European Journal of Political Economy , vol.16 , pp. 215-241
    • De Haan, J.1    Sturm, J.2
  • 4
    • 0028561171 scopus 로고
    • Property rights and economic growth
    • Johan Torstensson, "Property Rights and Economic Growth," Kyklos 47, (1994): 231-47;
    • (1994) Kyklos , vol.47 , pp. 231-247
    • Torstensson, J.1
  • 5
    • 84974486152 scopus 로고
    • Constitution and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England
    • Douglass North, and Barry Weingast, "Constitution and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England," Journal of Economic History 49 (1989): 803-32;
    • (1989) Journal of Economic History , vol.49 , pp. 803-832
    • North, D.1    Weingast, B.2
  • 6
    • 33644892265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Svetozar Pejovich, ed., (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar)
    • and Svetozar Pejovich, ed., The Economics of Property Rights (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2001), vol. 2, part IV.
    • (2001) The Economics of Property Rights , vol.2 , Issue.4 PART
  • 8
    • 33644900807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Heritage Foundation Lecture no. 813 (Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation)
    • Ana Isabel Eiras, Ethics, Corruption, and Economic Freedom, The Heritage Foundation Lecture no. 813 (Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation, 2003), 1.
    • (2003) Ethics, Corruption, and Economic Freedom , pp. 1
    • Eiras, A.I.1
  • 9
    • 33644890532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, neoclassical economics was mainstream economics in the 1990s (and still is); it is supported by the majority of economists as well as major organizations such as the World Bank. Perhaps the most prominent figure was Jeffrey Sachs.
  • 10
  • 11
    • 84968775560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • After socialism: Where hope for individual liberty lies
    • Svetozar Pejovich, "After Socialism: Where Hope for Individual Liberty Lies," Journal des Economistes et des Eludes Humaines 11 (2001): 23-27.
    • (2001) Journal des Economistes et des Eludes Humaines , vol.11 , pp. 23-27
    • Pejovich, S.1
  • 12
    • 33644894552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Federation of Serbia and Montenegro was ranked as repressive in the 2003 Heritage Index of Economic Freedom and was dropped from the index in 2004 for lack of information.
  • 13
    • 0004431815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • General implications of subjectivism in economics
    • paper presented University of Dallas
    • James Buchanan, "General Implications of Subjectivism in Economics," paper presented at a conference titled "Subjectivism in Economics," University of Dallas, 1976, p. 2.
    • (1976) A Conference Titled "Subjectivism in Economics," , pp. 2
    • Buchanan, J.1
  • 15
    • 84906941142 scopus 로고
    • Cultural endowments and economic development: What can we learn from anthropology?
    • For different definitions of culture, see Vernon Ruttan, "Cultural Endowments and Economic Development: What Can We Learn from Anthropology?" Economic Development and Cultured Change 36 (1988): 247-71.
    • (1988) Economic Development and Cultured Change , vol.36 , pp. 247-271
    • Ruttan, V.1
  • 16
    • 0003540038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 37. Ernest Gellner defined culture as "a distinct way of doing things which characterizes a given community."
    • (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance , pp. 37
    • North, D.1
  • 17
  • 18
    • 33644897917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I refer to a constitution that is credible (i.e., protects individual rights de facto) and stable (i.e., difficult to change). Many constitutions (e.g., Soviet constitutions) are not worth the paper on which they are written.
  • 19
    • 33644885523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Two major requirements for an independent judiciary are that judges expect their decisions to be carried out and that their jobs do not depend on legislators and/or bureaucrats. An independent judiciary should not be confused with a good judiciary. It all depends on the people who become judges.
  • 20
    • 0003243573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rule of law, democracy, and economic performance
    • Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation and the Wall Street Journal
    • Robert Barro, "Rule of Law, Democracy, and Economic Performance," in 2000 Index of Economic Freedom (Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation and the Wall Street Journal, 2000), 47. In the West, the rule of law and democracy go together. However, Fareed Zakaria argues that a number of countries that have multiparty elections are, in effect, illiberal democracies; they do better on political liberties than on civil and economic ones.
    • (2000) 2000 Index of Economic Freedom , pp. 47
    • Barro, R.1
  • 21
    • 0004616144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rise of illiberal democracy
    • See Fareed Zakaria, "The Rise of Illiberal Democracy," Foreign Affairs 76 (1997): 22-43.
    • (1997) Foreign Affairs , vol.76 , pp. 22-43
    • Zakaria, F.1
  • 24
    • 0010810017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
    • See Deepak Lal, Unintended Consequences (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1998), 83.
    • (1998) Unintended Consequences , pp. 83
    • Lal, D.1
  • 25
    • 33644885054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I thank James Buchanan for his comments on the extended family.
  • 26
    • 33644903567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a letter to the author of this essay, Professor Avner Greif wrote: " 'Maghrib' means 'West' in Arabic. During the medieval period and long after, the term was used to refer to the Muslim World's west: North Africa, Spain, and Sicily. The Maghribi traders migrated from Iraq in the tenth century to the Maghrib and hence they were called 'the Maghribi traders.' The documents that I have used reflect the correspondence of the Maghribi community in Fustat (known today as Old Cairo)."
  • 27
    • 0028570634 scopus 로고
    • Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies
    • Avner Greif, "Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies," Journal of Political Economy 102 (1994): 942.
    • (1994) Journal of Political Economy , vol.102 , pp. 942
    • Greif, A.1
  • 28
    • 33644888090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sofia: International Center for Minority Studies
    • Antonina Zhelyazkova, Albanian Prospects (Sofia: International Center for Minority Studies, 2003), 140-41. Young Albanians who go abroad work hard and save their money. Most of them continue to live in their own cultural ghettos. Those who return to their homeland bring along the money they have saved but not necessarily Western values.
    • (2003) Albanian Prospects , pp. 140-141
    • Zhelyazkova, A.1
  • 30
    • 33644929083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transition problems in the Russian agriculture sector: A historical-institutional perspective
    • Pejovich, ed.
    • Silke Stahl, "Transition Problems in the Russian Agriculture Sector: A Historical-Institutional Perspective," in Pejovich, ed., The Economics of Property Rights, 157.
    • The Economics of Property Rights , pp. 157
    • Stahl, S.1
  • 32
    • 0010810017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law of limited liability was known in Europe as early as the eleventh century. See Lal, Unintended Consequences, 81-82.
    • Unintended Consequences , pp. 81-82
    • Lal1
  • 33
    • 0004424704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On property and constitutionalism
    • Cass Sunstein, "On Property and Constitutionalism," Cardozo law Review 14 (1993): 935.
    • (1993) Cardozo Law Review , vol.14 , pp. 935
    • Sunstein, C.1
  • 34
    • 33644931193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I thank Professor Andreas Freytag from Friedrich-Schiller University in Jena, Germany, for this point.
  • 35
    • 33644892844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic Books
    • Andre Gerolymatos, The Balkan Wars (New York: Basic Books, 2002), 73-77.
    • (2002) The Balkan Wars , pp. 73-77
    • Gerolymatos, A.1
  • 36
    • 33644912388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1996 and 2004 Index of Economic Freedom published jointly by the Heritage Foundation and the Wall Street Journal.
    • Wall Street Journal
  • 37
    • 33644881168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is important to repeat that the ranking of countries in the Heritage Index is in terms of economic freedoms only.
  • 39
    • 1842658592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic variables and the development of the law: The case of western mineral rights
    • L. Alston, T. Eggertsson, and D. North, eds., (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), (emphasis added)
    • Gary Libecap, "Economic Variables and the Development of the Law: The Case of Western Mineral Rights," in L. Alston, T. Eggertsson, and D. North, eds., Empirical Studies in Institutional Change (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), 57 (emphasis added).
    • (1996) Empirical Studies in Institutional Change , pp. 57
    • Libecap, G.1
  • 40
    • 33644881455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In contrast, positive rights, such as a right to free public education, call for interference by the state.
  • 42
    • 85055302713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property rights and the wealth of nations: A cross-country study
    • Bernhard Heitger, "Property Rights and the Wealth of Nations: A Cross-Country Study," Cato Journal 23 (2004): 400.
    • (2004) Cato Journal , vol.23 , pp. 400
    • Heitger, B.1
  • 43
  • 44
    • 33644913457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In this essay, I use the terms "lowering" and "changing" the margin of acceptable behavior interchangeably.
  • 45
    • 33644895203 scopus 로고
    • The ethos problem in the present pluralistic society
    • As far as I know, an article by Goetz Briefs is the earliest attempt to interpret the consequences of the relationship between formal and informal rules via changes at the margin. See Goetz Briefs, "The Ethos Problem in the Present Pluralistic Society," Review of Social Economy 15 (1957): 47-75.
    • (1957) Review of Social Economy , vol.15 , pp. 47-75
    • Briefs, G.1
  • 46
    • 33644906976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In addition to financial losses, those costs could range from losing friends to losing jobs and alienation from the community.
  • 47
    • 3042792707 scopus 로고
    • Politics, property, and the law
    • James Buchanan, "Politics, Property, and the Law," Journal of Law and Economics 15 (1972): 451-52.
    • (1972) Journal of Law and Economics , vol.15 , pp. 451-452
    • Buchanan, J.1
  • 48
    • 33644925916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an example of this, see the appendix.
    • For an example of this, see the appendix.
  • 50
    • 0004285879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 7892
    • See Simeon Djankov et al., The Regulation of Entry (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 7892, 2000).
    • (2000) The Regulation of Entry
    • Djankov, S.1
  • 51
    • 33644891982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Subsequent investors (shareholders) are buying into those initial contracts made by original investors. In transparent financial markets, share prices incorporate the expected effects of initial contractual terms.
  • 52
    • 0003846902 scopus 로고
    • New York: Macmillan
    • Research and evidence have totally undermined Adolf Berle and Gardiner Means's analysis of the costs of the dispersion of shareholding (Berle and Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property [New York: Macmillan, 1935]). To paraphrase Armen Alchian, the "separation of ownership from control" hypothesis is an empty piece of poetry. Of course, if corporate managers could and did transfer shareholders' wealth to themselves, how do we explain that literally millions of large and small savers are purchasing shares? There is no law that says that they have to do so. And in the United States, people have many other alternatives for investing their funds.
    • (1935) The Modern Corporation and Private Property
    • Berle1    Means2
  • 53
    • 33644901363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Turin: International Centre for Economic Research, Working Paper no. 2
    • See Jonathan Macey, Gli Stati Uniti: Un Paese Senze Legge (Turin: International Centre for Economic Research, Working Paper no. 2, 1998).
    • (1998) Gli Stati Uniti: un Paese Senze Legge
    • Macey, J.1
  • 55
    • 0006761611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate ownership around the world
    • and Rafael La Porta et al., "Corporate Ownership Around the World," Journal of finance 54 (1999): 471-513.
    • (1999) Journal of Finance , vol.54 , pp. 471-513
    • La Porta, R.1
  • 58
    • 2542636990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding the transaction costs of transition: It's the culture, stupid
    • The material in this appendix is adapted from Svetozar Pejovich, "Understanding the Transaction Costs of Transition: It's the Culture, Stupid," Review of Austrian Economics 16 (2003): 355-56.
    • (2003) Review of Austrian Economics , vol.16 , pp. 355-356
    • Pejovich, S.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.