메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 16, Issue 4, 2005, Pages 347-368

Constitutional origins of dictatorship and democracy

Author keywords

Parliamentary; Presidential; Semi presidential; Separation of powers

Indexed keywords


EID: 28144448900     PISSN: 10434062     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1007/s10602-005-4316-x     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (12)

References (131)
  • 2
    • 4243971778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Die dualistische variante des parlamentarismus: Eine französische ansicht zur wissenschaftlichen fata morgana des semi-präsidentiellen systems
    • Also see Armel Le Divellec, Die dualistische Variante des Parlamentarismus: Eine französische Ansicht zur wissenschaftlichen Fata Morgana des semi-präsidentiellen Systems, 27 Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen 145-51 (1996);
    • (1996) Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen , vol.27 , pp. 145-151
    • Divellec, A.L.1
  • 9
    • 0037892925 scopus 로고
    • Semi-präsidentialismus: Ein eigenständiger systemtyp? Zur unterscheidung von legislative und parlament
    • Winfried Steffani, Semi-Präsidentialismus: ein eigenständiger Systemtyp? Zur Unterscheidung von Legislative und Parlament, 26 Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen, 621-41 (1995);
    • (1995) Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen , vol.26 , pp. 621-641
    • Steffani, W.1
  • 12
    • 0348198424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The tyranny of madison
    • id.
    • and the useful conceptual cleaning and empirical contributions in Semi-Presidentialism in Europe (Robert Elgie, ed., 1999). Indeed, some authors have hastily generalized from France's rather exceptional experience with semi-presidentialism. Jonathan Zasloff, for example, remarks that "[s]emi-presidentialism's record, to the extent that it can be determined, is promising, or at least, not unpromising." See id., The Tyranny of Madison, 44 UCLA L. Rev. 795, 820 (1997).
    • (1997) UCLA L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 795
  • 13
    • 0035608994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The contribution of democracy to rebuilding postconflict societies
    • Also see Samuel H. Barnes, The Contribution of Democracy to Rebuilding Postconflict Societies, 95 American Journal of International Law 86, 95 (2001).
    • (2001) 95 American Journal of International Law , vol.86 , pp. 95
    • Barnes, S.H.1
  • 15
    • 28144443276 scopus 로고
    • Governments can be single-party or coalitional, and have majority or minority status. Majority governments seem to be the most viable, whereas the least viable seem to be minority governments. See Michael Laver and Norman Schofield, Multiparty Government 142 (1990);
    • (1990) Multiparty Government , vol.142
    • Laver, M.1    Schofield, N.2
  • 17
    • 0032220681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How does cabinet instability affect political performance? Portfolio volatility and health care cost containment in parliamentary democracies
    • Also see John D. Huber, How Does Cabinet Instability Affect Political Performance? Portfolio Volatility and Health Care Cost Containment in Parliamentary Democracies, 92 American Political Science Review 577-91 (1998), for the argument that minority governments have increased portfolio changes across parties, limiting governmental effectiveness.
    • (1998) American Political Science Review , vol.92 , pp. 577-591
    • Huber, J.D.1
  • 18
    • 0040807106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government formation and public policy
    • And although Michael Laver, in Government Formation and Public Policy, 33 PS: Political Science and Politics 21-23 (2000), argues that neither coalition governments, nor minority governments, need be weak and unstable, the literature on coalition and minority governments has almost exclusively concerned itself with consolidated democratic systems, and has ignored their impact in transitional democracies.
    • (2000) PS: Political Science and Politics , vol.33 , pp. 21-23
    • Laver, M.1
  • 19
    • 0004263556 scopus 로고
    • These tensions are maximized under divided government, when the president does not enjoy a majority in the legislature, and minimized under unified government. See The Politics of Divided Government (Gary W. Cox and Samuel Kernell, eds., 1991);
    • (1991) The Politics of Divided Government
    • Cox, G.W.1    Kernell, S.2
  • 23
    • 0033234869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unified government, divided government, and party responsiveness
    • and John. J. Coleman, Unified Government, Divided Government, and Party Responsiveness, 93 American Political Science Review 821-35 (1999).
    • (1999) American Political Science Review , vol.93 , pp. 821-835
    • Coleman, J.J.1
  • 24
    • 28144445930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See elgie (1999)
    • See elgie (1999).
  • 26
    • 28144464713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Yves Mény, Le système politique français 98 (1996), who notes that in the French constitution, "[t]he powers of Head of State are indefinable, literally indefinite, without end...[w]ho could in fact resist such a temptation?"
    • (1996) Le Système Politique Français , vol.98
    • Mény, Y.1
  • 28
    • 23744457801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the relationship between semi-presidentialism and constitutional dictatorship, see Skach, Borrowing Constitutional Designs, pp. 12-30, and 49-70.
    • Borrowing Constitutional Designs , pp. 12-30
    • Skach1
  • 30
    • 84945767012 scopus 로고
    • Democratic socialism and the tests of power
    • That is why François Mitterrand altered the structure of his Socialist Party in an attempt to eliminate various factions within it. See Philip Cerny, Democratic Socialism and the Tests of Power, 6 West European Politics 188-202 (1983).
    • (1983) West European Politics , vol.6 , pp. 188-202
    • Cerny, P.1
  • 31
    • 28144436954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This was the case with Georges Pompidou and his prime ministers. This was also the case in Poland during the first two periods of consolidated majority government.
  • 32
    • 28144435181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comment at round table discussion of the 40th anniversary colloquim
    • Paris, October 7
    • e République (Paris, October 7, 1998).
    • (1998) e République
    • Maus, D.1
  • 33
    • 28144440708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shugart and Carey, supra note 1, miss this point. Their emphasis on de jure presidential power as a contributing factor to democratic breakdown obscures the fact that political conflict within semipresidentialism varies over time, although the de jure presidential powers remain constant.
    • Supra Note , vol.1
    • Shugart1    Carey2
  • 34
    • 28144443873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A majority is stable when it lasts for the entire duration of the legislature, and coherent when "the parties, groups and individuals which compose [the majority] are in agreement concerning essential political trends," Duverger, supra note. 1, p. 91. Theoretically, either the prime minister or the president can enjoy the legislative majority during cohabitation. Empirically, it is usually the prime minister, due to constitutional stipulations or convention, which ensure that the president chooses a prime minister from the largest party or coalition in the legislature.
    • Supra Note , vol.1 , pp. 91
    • Duverger1
  • 35
    • 28144451940 scopus 로고
    • Marie-Anne Cohendet, La Cohabitation: Leçons d'une Expérience
    • Duverger, supra note 1; Marie-Anne Cohendet, La Cohabitation: Leçons d'une Expérience (1993).
    • (1993) Supra Note , vol.1
    • Duverger1
  • 37
    • 28144437621 scopus 로고
    • argue that, "...when the executive does not control a legislative majority in a parliamentary democracy, minority government is, in effect, divided government." Similarly, Alberto Alesina and Howard Rosenthal, Partisan Politics, Divided Government, and the Economy 257 (1995) state, "...the similarities between the French and the American cases of divided government are more striking than the differences." However, there are crucial conceptual and analytical distinctions between the divided government, minority government, and what I call divided majority government. For example, presidentialism's divided government is for a fixed term, whereas parliamentarism's minority government can be for a variable term. This crucial difference creates different incentives, and one of the complications with semi-presidentialism's divided minority government is that these different incentives are combined. These distinctions become acute in democratizing countries where political institutions tend to be weaker, and party systems more polarized, than in consolidated settings.
    • (1995) Partisan Politics, Divided Government, and the Economy , vol.257
    • Alesina, A.1    Rosenthal, H.2
  • 40
    • 0003705411 scopus 로고
    • Kaare Strom, Minority Government and Majority Rule (1990), suggests a useful conceptual differentiation between formal minority governments, which receive external legislative support and approach majority status, and substantive minority governments, which remain minority governments even when external support is counted. I follow Strom's distinction, counting formal minority governments as the functional equivalent of majority governments.
    • (1990) Minority Government and Majority Rule
    • Strom, K.1
  • 41
    • 28144446862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The arguments in id.
    • The arguments in id., and Laver, supra note 3, that minority government "need not be feared" with respect to democracy are not applicable here. First, their analyses concern parliamentary, and not semi-presidential, systems. Second, they assume (among other things) stable political institutions, and well-organized and resourceful political parties, whereas I am interested in how minority governments fare in situations of uncertainty when political institutions are neither stable nor well developed (i.e., in democratic transition and re-equilibration).
    • Supra Note , vol.3
    • Laver1
  • 42
    • 23744495097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Russian predicament
    • The longer treatment of the Russian case is found in Timothy J. Colton and Cindy Skach, The Russian Predicament, 16 Journal of Democracy 113-126 (2005).
    • (2005) Journal of Democracy , vol.16 , pp. 113-126
    • Colton, T.J.1    Skach, C.2
  • 43
    • 0003053005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential decree authority in Russia, 1991-95
    • John M. Carcy and Matthew Soberg Shugart, eds.
    • Also see Scott Parrish, Presidential Decree Authority in Russia, 1991-95, in Executive Decree Authority 62-103 (John M. Carcy and Matthew Soberg Shugart, eds.1998).
    • (1998) Executive Decree Authority , pp. 62-103
    • Parrish, S.1
  • 44
    • 0003353530 scopus 로고
    • Juan J. Linz and Alfred Stepan, eds., See id. p. 27
    • Juan J. Linz, Crisis, Breakdown, & Recquilibration, part of The Breakdown of Democratic Regimes 27-38 (Juan J. Linz and Alfred Stepan, eds., 1978). See id. p. 27, who states, "[c]hanges in regime occur with the transfer of legitimacy from one set of political institutions to another. They are brought on by the action of one or more disloyal oppositions that question the existence of the regime and aim at changing it."
    • (1978) Crisis, Breakdown, & Recquilibration, Part of the Breakdown of Democratic Regimes , pp. 27-38
    • Linz, J.J.1
  • 45
    • 28144441580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are also two conditions that do not explain or predict a country's placement or movement among the different subtypes of semi-presidentialism, but rather, influence whether - once in a subtype - conflict will be exacerbated or mitigated. One condition concerns powers constitutionally granted to a president, on the one hand, and the extent to which a president uses these powers, on the other hand. A second condition concerns the set of specific legislative and agenda rules which affect the power of governments vis-à-vis the legislature, and those determining the role of a country's constitutional court as a moderating power.
  • 46
    • 0002429903 scopus 로고
    • Political development and political engineering
    • Giovanni Sartori, Political Development and Political Engineering, 17 Public Policy 261-98, 293 (1966);
    • (1966) Public Policy , vol.17 , pp. 261-298
    • Sartori, G.1
  • 48
    • 28144436126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, 22
    • Id, 22.
  • 49
    • 0003987768 scopus 로고
    • especially his discussion of bargaining through side-payments
    • See William Riker, The Theory of Political Coalitions (1962), especially his discussion of bargaining through side-payments, 105-123.
    • (1962) The Theory of Political Coalitions , pp. 105-123
    • Riker, W.1
  • 54
    • 33845731165 scopus 로고
    • Majority formation is only one possible goal of electoral system design. Accurate reflection of minority parties in the legislature is another - often opposite - goal. See Dieter Nohlen, Wahlsysteme der Welt: Daten und Analysen, Ein Handbuch 13-18, 48-56 (1978);
    • (1978) Wahlsysteme der Welt: Daten und Analysen, Ein Handbuch , pp. 13-18
    • Nohlen, D.1
  • 56
    • 28144451223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes
    • Another factor within electoral system design is the relative timing of presidential and legislative elections. Evidence to date indicates that presidential and legislative elections held simultaneously are more likely to give a president a majority in the legislature, other things being equal. In semi-presidentialism, constitutional prerogatives often allow presidents to call early legislative elections shortly after taking office (or during the term) to try to re-equilibrate the presidential and legislative majorities, as Mitterrand did after his election in 1981. But as Sartori, supra note 1, p. 179 notes, "[c]oneurrent elections cannot fabricate undivided majorities that are not potentially in the works; but staggered elections do facilitate divided majority outcomes". This said, it does seem to be the case that the electorate is encouraged to vote for the same party in concurrent elections.
    • Supra Note , vol.1 , pp. 179
    • Sartori1
  • 57
    • 28144457423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Also see Shugart and Carey, supra note 1, pp. 229-258 and Appendix B.
    • Supra Note , vol.1 , pp. 229-258
    • Shugart1    Carey2
  • 59
  • 63
    • 28144461164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In other words, "...a bipolar [party] system assumes a normal, bell-curve distribution (a Gauss-Laplace curve) of where the electors place themselves along a left-right (or other) continuum, whereas bipolarization assumes a double-peaked distribution of political opinion with an almost empty center." See Sartori, supra note 1, p. 14.
    • Supra Note , vol.1 , pp. 14
    • Sartori1
  • 64
    • 28144455567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is the actual percentage the French presidential candidate Jacques Chirac won in the first round presidential elections on April 23, 1995. The second round, limited to the two front-runners, which included Chirac and Socialist Party candidate Lionel Jospin, gave him 52.63%.
  • 65
    • 28144444243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Only parliamentarism has such incentives, via executive responsibility to the legislature. At the legislative level, closed party lists give parties more control over candidates, reducing the personalization of campaigns, enhancing the value of the party label in local elections, and enabling the party to reward the most loyal rank-and-file members by placing them on the list. See Shugart and Carey, supra note 1, p. 171.
    • Supra Note , vol.1 , pp. 171
    • Shugart1    Carey2
  • 66
    • 28144442688 scopus 로고
    • Actual "outsiders" have included the aforementioned Perot in the United States, Fujimori in Peru, and Tyminski in Poland's 1990 presidential race. Tyminski, described as an "unknown Polish expatriate businessman," running on an anti-party campaign, was able to pass up the previous Solidarity prime minister Tadeusz Mazowiecki in the first round election by a 3.1% margin, and advance to the second round against Lech Walesa. See Frances Millard, The Anatomy of the New Poland: Postcommunist Politics in its First Phase 128 (1994).
    • (1994) The Anatomy of the New Poland: Postcommunist Politics in Its First Phase , pp. 128
    • Millard, F.1
  • 68
    • 84976104285 scopus 로고
    • Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicamerialism and multipartyism
    • nor George Tsebelis, Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicamerialism and Multipartyism, 25 British Journal of Political Science 289-325 (1995), are adequately able to explain the causal mechanism of regime instability in semi-presidentialism. Tsebelis is interested in presidents' constitutional veto power over legislation, ignoring other important presidential powers such as emergency and decree powers. Moreover, legitimacy erosion and democratic breakdown can emanate from a president's reaction to his position of impotence vis-à-vis the legislature, which itself emanates from the president's poor relationship to, or ideological distance from, parties in the legislature.
    • (1995) British Journal of Political Science , vol.25 , pp. 289-325
    • Tsebelis, G.1
  • 69
    • 21144471988 scopus 로고
    • Constitutions as governance structures: The political foundations of secure markets
    • In this sense, the semi-presidential constitution may not be an effective coordination device which constitutions must be if they are to contribute to democratic consolidation. On coordination devices see Barry R. Weingast, Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secure Markets, 149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 286-311 (1993);
    • (1993) Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics , vol.149 , pp. 286-311
    • Weingast, B.R.1
  • 70
    • 0031507203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law
    • id
    • and id, The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law, 91 American Political Science Review 245-63 (1997). On constitutions and commitment,
    • (1997) American Political Science Review , vol.91 , pp. 245-263
  • 72
  • 73
    • 0003574938 scopus 로고
    • Democratization is, at a procedural minimum, the "...process whereby the rules and procedures of citizenship are either applied to political institutions previously governed by other principles..., or expanded to include persons not previously enjoying such rights and obligations..., or extended to cover issues and institutions not previously subject to citizen participation." Sec Guillermo O'Donnell and Philippe C. Schmitter, Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies 8 (1986). Here I am concerned not only with democratization so defined, but also, with the consolidation and stability of democracy, which has attitudinal and behavioral dimensions in addition to procedural ones.
    • (1986) Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies , pp. 8
    • O'Donnell, G.1    Schmitter, P.C.2
  • 75
    • 0003591736 scopus 로고
    • This is a contribution, given the almost complete lack of existing knowledge concerning semi-presidentialism's relationship to democracy. Once more evidence becomes available from the new and existing semi-presidential democracies, further testing of this relationship through large-n statistical analysis could be undertaken. See Gary King, Robert O. Keohane, and Sidney Verba, Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research 214-15 (1994). For the merits of crucial cases,
    • (1994) Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research , pp. 214-215
    • King, G.1    Keohane, R.O.2    Verba, S.3
  • 80
  • 84
    • 27744490760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Executive decree authority in France
    • John M. Carey and Matthew Soberg Shugart, eds.
    • and John D. Huber, Executive Decree Authority in France, in Executive Decree Authority 233-53 (John M. Carey and Matthew Soberg Shugart, eds., 1998).
    • (1998) Executive Decree Authority , pp. 233-253
    • Huber, J.D.1
  • 85
    • 28144448161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The presidential mandate was changed, by referendum, to five years in September 2000.
  • 89
    • 28144444488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From 1958 to 1986, and then from 1988 to the present, a majority-plurality formula has been used for the National Assembly. This system requires an absolute majority for victory in the first round, or a plurality for victory in the second round. The second round is limited to parties having passed a threshold, which has increased from 5% of the registered electorate in 1958, to 10% in 1966, and 12.5% in 1976. See Duverger, supra note 6, pp. 495-500;
    • Supra Note , vol.6 , pp. 495-500
    • Duverger1
  • 91
    • 28144448318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Over de Gaulle's tenure, the percentage of ministers and secretaries of state from the UNR increased steadily: 31% under Debré, 34% under Pompidou I, 54% under Pompidou II, 55% under Pompidou III, and 84% under Couve de Murville in 1968. Data from Keesings Contemporary Archives (1959-1969). After 1967, the UNR was transformed into the Union des démocrates pour la République (UDR).
  • 92
    • 84933490757 scopus 로고
    • Accounting for the survival of minority governments: An examination of the French case, 1988-1991
    • Formally, there was a minority government from 1988 to 1993; but as the Socialists governed alternatively with support from the Communists and the Gaullists, they substantively enjoyed majority status. On these years see Robert Elgie and Moshe Maor, Accounting for the Survival of Minority Governments: An Examination of the French Case, 1988-1991 15 west European Politics 57-74 (1992);
    • (1992) West European Politics , vol.15 , pp. 57-74
    • Elgie, R.1    Maor, M.2
  • 97
    • 84935446711 scopus 로고
    • On economic planning in this period, see Peter Hall, Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France 146-49 (1986). In 1963, the Pompidou government created the Délegation à l'Aménagement du Territoire et à l'Action Régionale (DATAR), which was meant as a center of knowledge for regional planning.
    • (1986) Governing the Economy: the Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France , pp. 146-149
    • Hall, P.1
  • 102
    • 84930557711 scopus 로고
    • The French double executive and the experience of cohabitation
    • 105
    • and Jean V. Poulard, The French Double Executive and the Experience of Cohabitation 105 Political Science Quarterly Vol. 105 243-67 (1990).
    • (1990) Political Science Quarterly , vol.105 , pp. 243-267
    • Poulard, J.V.1
  • 106
    • 28144443872 scopus 로고
    • Parteiensystem und sozialstruktur
    • Gerhard A. Ritter, ed.
    • Rainer M. Lepsius, Parteiensystem und Sozialstruktur, in Die Deutschen Parteien vor 1918, 40-63 (Gerhard A. Ritter, ed., 1973);
    • (1973) Die Deutschen Parteien vor , vol.1918 , pp. 40-63
    • Lepsius, R.M.1
  • 107
    • 0001829787 scopus 로고
    • From fragmented party democracy to government by emergency decree and national socialist takeover: Germany
    • id., (Juan J. Linz and Alfred Stepan, eds.)
    • and id., From Fragmented Party Democracy to Government by Emergency Decree and National Socialist Takeover: Germany, in The Breakdown of Democratic Regimes: Europe, 34-79 (Juan J. Linz and Alfred Stepan, eds., 1978).
    • (1978) The Breakdown of Democratic Regimes: Europe , pp. 34-79
  • 110
    • 28144452365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Nohlen, supra note 26, pp. 209-213.
    • Supra Note , vol.26 , pp. 209-213
    • Nohlen1
  • 112
    • 28144440354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • also see the discussion of Lakeman and Lambert, and omitted variable bias in analyses of PR's role in Weimar's breakdown, in King, Keohane, and Verba, supra note 38, p. 190.
    • Supra Note , vol.38 , pp. 190
    • King, K.1    Verba2
  • 116
    • 12144271995 scopus 로고
    • See the data collected in 109/110 Informationen zur politischen Bildung: Die Weimarer Republik, (1988).
    • (1988) Die Weimarer Republik
  • 119
    • 28144449458 scopus 로고
    • Die sozialdemokratie in der defensive: Der immobilismus der SPD und der aufstief des nationalsozialismus
    • id., ed.
    • Hans Mommsen, Die Sozialdemokratie in der Defensive: Der Immobilismus der SPD und der Aufstief des Nationalsozialismus, in Sozialdemokratie zwischen Klassenbewegung und Volkspartei, 106-33 (id., ed., 1974).
    • (1974) Sozialdemokratie Zwischen Klassenbewegung und Volkspartei , pp. 106-133
    • Mommsen, H.1
  • 123
    • 28144437449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Brünings dismissal, see Patch, supra
    • On Brünings dismissal, see Patch, supra;
  • 125
    • 4243550705 scopus 로고
    • Die verfassungsmässigkeit der bestellung eines reichskommissars für das land preussen
    • Carl Schmitt defended the Reich government before the court. His defense is found in Schmitt, Die Verfassungsmässigkeit der Bestellung eines Reichskommissars für das Land Preussen, 15 Deutsche Juristenzeitung, 954-58 (1932). The court's decision is found in Preussen contra Reich vor dem Staatsgerichtshof: Stenogrammbericht der Verhandlungen vor dem Staatsgerichtshof in Leipzig vom 10. Bis 14. und vom 17. Oktober 1932 (1932).
    • (1932) Deutsche Juristenzeitung , vol.15 , pp. 954-958
    • Schmitt1
  • 126
    • 0031286128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal theory in the collapse of weimar: Contemporary lessons?
    • Also see David Dyzenhaus, Legal Theory in the Collapse of Weimar: Contemporary Lessons? 91 American Political Science Review 121-34 (1997);
    • (1997) American Political Science Review , vol.91 , pp. 121-134
    • Dyzenhaus, D.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.