메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 95, Issue 1, 2001, Pages 86-100

The contribution of democracy to rebuilding postconflict societies

(1)  Barnes, Samuel H a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0035608994     PISSN: 00029300     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/2642039     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (58)

References (79)
  • 1
    • 0345778633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political culture and democratic institutions: Russia in global perspective
    • In surveys of the 1990s, residents of 50 countries were asked to react to statements about democratic political systems. The statement that "[d]emocracy may have problems but it's better than any other form of government" gained agreement or strong agreement from 73% or more of the population in 49 countries. (In Russia, 57% agreed or strongly agreed.) See Ronald Inglehart, Political Culture and Democratic Institutions: Russia in Global Perspective, Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, table 2, at 23 (Aug. 31-Sept. 3, 2000) [hereinafter Inglehart, Political Culture]. Inglehart concludes that "democracy has become virtually the only model with global appeal." Id. at 3; see also RONALD INGLEHART, MODERNIZATION AND POSTMODERNIZATION: CULTURAL, ECONOMIC, AND POLITICAL CHANGE IN 43 SOCIETIES (1997).
    • Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association
    • Inglehart, R.1
  • 2
    • 0003430361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In surveys of the 1990s, residents of 50 countries were asked to react to statements about democratic political systems. The statement that "[d]emocracy may have problems but it's better than any other form of government" gained agreement or strong agreement from 73% or more of the population in 49 countries. (In Russia, 57% agreed or strongly agreed.) See Ronald Inglehart, Political Culture and Democratic Institutions: Russia in Global Perspective, Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, table 2, at 23 (Aug. 31-Sept. 3, 2000) [hereinafter Inglehart, Political Culture]. Inglehart concludes that "democracy has become virtually the only model with global appeal." Id. at 3; see also RONALD INGLEHART, MODERNIZATION AND POSTMODERNIZATION: CULTURAL, ECONOMIC, AND POLITICAL CHANGE IN 43 SOCIETIES (1997).
    • (1997) Modernization and Postmodernization: Cultural, Economic, and Political Change in 43 Societies
    • Inglehart, R.1
  • 3
    • 0003934897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In his study of East German mass and elite opinions, Robert Rohrschneider points out that this former Communist country's citizens quickly adopted the "easy" aspects of democratic ideology - freedom and rights - though they were slower to develop concern for toleration and restraint in dealing with others. ROBERT ROHRSCHNEIDER, LEARNING DEMOCRACY: DEMOCRATIC AND ECONOMIC VALUES IN UNIFIED GERMANY (1999).
    • (1999) Learning Democracy: Democratic and Economic Values in Unified Germany
    • Rohrschneider, R.1
  • 4
    • 0039574272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Boutros Boutros-Ghali, Supplement to Reports on Democratization (Agenda for Democratization), UN Doc. A/51/761, annex (1996)
    • See, e.g., Boutros Boutros-Ghali, Supplement to Reports on Democratization (Agenda for Democratization), UN Doc. A/51/761, annex (1996).
  • 5
    • 0004343207 scopus 로고
    • 53 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 69
    • The case of India reminds us that national wealth is not always a necessary ingredient for democracy. The relationship between per capita income and the strength of democracy has generated a long scholarly discussion. Seymour Martin Lipset argued in 1959 that democracy is possible only when societies reach a certain level of prosperity. Seymour M. Lipset, Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy, 53 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 69 (1959). Lipset modified his view of this relationship in 1994. Seymour Martin Lipset, The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited: 1993 Presidential Address, 59 AM. SOC. REV. 1 (1994).
    • (1959) Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy
    • Lipset, S.M.1
  • 6
    • 0039574265 scopus 로고
    • 59 AM. SOC. REV. 1
    • The case of India reminds us that national wealth is not always a necessary ingredient for democracy. The relationship between per capita income and the strength of democracy has generated a long scholarly discussion. Seymour Martin Lipset argued in 1959 that democracy is possible only when societies reach a certain level of prosperity. Seymour M. Lipset, Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy, 53 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 69 (1959). Lipset modified his view of this relationship in 1994. Seymour Martin Lipset, The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited: 1993 Presidential Address, 59 AM. SOC. REV. 1 (1994).
    • (1994) The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited: 1993 Presidential Address
    • Lipset, S.M.1
  • 9
    • 0004018017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Snyder argues, perhaps controversially, that the international aid community is oblivious to this "harsh reality." " [D]emocratization," he argues, "is likely to spark nationalist conflict in countries that have an underdeveloped economy; a population with both poor civic skills and underdeveloped representative andjournalistic institutions; and elites who are threatened by democratic change." Id. at 305. At a minimum, in Snyder's view, old elites may need to be "cushioned as they f[a]ll from power." Id. at 308
    • JACK SNYDER, FROM VOTING TO VIOLENCE: DEMOCRATIZATION AND NATIONALIST CONFLICT 310 (2000). Snyder argues, perhaps controversially, that the international aid community is oblivious to this "harsh reality." " [D]emocratization," he argues, "is likely to spark nationalist conflict in countries that have an underdeveloped economy; a population with both poor civic skills and underdeveloped representative andjournalistic institutions; and elites who are threatened by democratic change." Id. at 305. At a minimum, in Snyder's view, old elites may need to be "cushioned as they f[a]ll from power." Id. at 308.
    • (2000) From Voting to Violence: Democratization and Nationalist Conflict , pp. 310
    • Snyder, J.1
  • 10
    • 0040940626 scopus 로고
    • Democratization and the danger of war
    • Summer
    • The same qualification has been offered by social scientists in regard to the "democratic peace" hypothesis. Edward Mansfield and Jack Snyder have noted that the box score of mature democracies in declining to fight wars against each other does not determine what the dangers are in growing a new democracy. See Edward D. Mansfield & Jack Snyder, Democratization and the Danger of War, INT'L SECURITY, Summer 1995, at 5; Edward D. Mansfield & Jack Snyder, Democratization and War, FOREIGN AFF., May/June 1995, at 79.
    • (1995) Int'l Security , pp. 5
    • Mansfield, E.D.1    Snyder, J.2
  • 11
    • 0003177916 scopus 로고
    • Democratization and war
    • May/June
    • The same qualification has been offered by social scientists in regard to the "democratic peace" hypothesis. Edward Mansfield and Jack Snyder have noted that the box score of mature democracies in declining to fight wars against each other does not determine what the dangers are in growing a new democracy. See Edward D. Mansfield & Jack Snyder, Democratization and the Danger of War, INT'L SECURITY, Summer 1995, at 5; Edward D. Mansfield & Jack Snyder, Democratization and War, FOREIGN AFF., May/June 1995, at 79.
    • (1995) Foreign Aff. , pp. 79
    • Mansfield, E.D.1    Snyder, J.2
  • 12
    • 0004018017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More recently, Professor Snyder has extended his work to argue that formal democratic mechanisms may be exploited by transitional elites who seek to use exclusionary nationalism as a means of retaining power, especially where the institutions of civil society and a free press are underdeveloped. See JACK SNYDER, FROM VOTING TO VIOLENCE: DEMOCRATIZATION AND NATIONALIST CONFLICT (2000).
    • (2000) From Voting to Violence: Democratization and Nationalist Conflict
    • Snyder, J.1
  • 15
    • 0039574266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The continued existence of contestation presumes the maintenance of the rights and institutions necessary to protect and implement it
    • The continued existence of contestation presumes the maintenance of the rights and institutions necessary to protect and implement it.
  • 18
    • 85059148772 scopus 로고
    • Political culture, political structure, and democracy: The case of legitimation and opposition structure
    • Frederick D. Weil & Mary Gautier eds.
    • The social science literature on political culture is vast, and the subject of culture is much wider. Much of the general literature on culture is "soft" and humanistic in approach, which makes discussions of, for example, the compatibility of some religious beliefs and democracy hopelessly confusing. For a discussion of political culture as a topic for empirical analysis, see Samuel H. Barnes, Political Culture, Political Structure, and Democracy: The Case of Legitimation and Opposition Structure, in POLITICAL CULTURE AND POLITICAL STRUCTURE: THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL STUDIES 45 (Frederick D. Weil & Mary Gautier eds., 1994). For an empirical exploration of the role of culture in democratization of a single country, see PETER MCDONOUGH, SAMUEL H. BARNES, & ANTONIO LÓPEZ PINA, with DOH C. SHIN & JOSÉ ALVARO MOISÉS, THE CULTURAL DYNAMICS OF DEMOCRATIZATION IN SPAIN (1998).
    • (1994) Political Culture and Political Structure: Theoretical and Empirical Studies , pp. 45
    • Barnes, S.H.1
  • 19
    • 0003614537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The social science literature on political culture is vast, and the subject of culture is much wider. Much of the general literature on culture is "soft" and humanistic in approach, which makes discussions of, for example, the compatibility of some religious beliefs and democracy hopelessly confusing. For a discussion of political culture as a topic for empirical analysis, see Samuel H. Barnes, Political Culture, Political Structure, and Democracy: The Case of Legitimation and Opposition Structure, in POLITICAL CULTURE AND POLITICAL STRUCTURE: THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL STUDIES 45 (Frederick D. Weil & Mary Gautier eds., 1994). For an empirical exploration of the role of culture in democratization of a single country, see PETER MCDONOUGH, SAMUEL H. BARNES, & ANTONIO LÓPEZ PINA, with DOH C. SHIN & JOSÉ ALVARO MOISÉS, THE CULTURAL DYNAMICS OF DEMOCRATIZATION IN SPAIN (1998).
    • (1998) The Cultural Dynamics Of Democratization In Spain
    • Mcdonough, P.1    Barnes, S.H.2    Pina, A.L.3    Shin, D.C.4    Moisés, J.A.5
  • 20
    • 0039574258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 95 AJIL 7, 7
    • As Payam Akhavan accurately observes: Contrary to the simplistic myths of primordial "tribal" hatred, the conflicts in the former Yugoslavia and Rwanda were not expressions of spontaneous blood lust or inevitable historical cataclysms. Both conflicts resulted from the deliberate incitement of ethnic hatred and violence by which ruthless demagogues and warlords elevated themselves to positions of absolute power. Payam Akhavan, Beyond Impunity: Can International Criminal Justice Prevent Future Atrocities? 95 AJIL 7, 7 (2001); see also DONALD L. HOROWITZ, THE ETHNIC RIOT (forthcoming).
    • (2001) Beyond Impunity: Can International Criminal Justice Prevent Future Atrocities?
    • Akhavan, P.1
  • 21
    • 0040165687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • forthcoming
    • As Payam Akhavan accurately observes: Contrary to the simplistic myths of primordial "tribal" hatred, the conflicts in the former Yugoslavia and Rwanda were not expressions of spontaneous blood lust or inevitable historical cataclysms. Both conflicts resulted from the deliberate incitement of ethnic hatred and violence by which ruthless demagogues and warlords elevated themselves to positions of absolute power. Payam Akhavan, Beyond Impunity: Can International Criminal Justice Prevent Future Atrocities? 95 AJIL 7, 7 (2001); see also DONALD L. HOROWITZ, THE ETHNIC RIOT (forthcoming).
    • The Ethnic Riot
    • Horowitz, D.L.1
  • 22
    • 0013339497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Structure and strategy in ethnic conflict: A few steps toward synthesis
    • Boris Pleskovic & Joseph E. Stiglitz eds.
    • See Donald L. Horowitz, Structure and Strategy in Ethnic Conflict: A Few Steps Toward Synthesis, in ANNUAL WORLD BANK CONFERENCE ON DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS 1998, at 345 (Boris Pleskovic & Joseph E. Stiglitz eds., 1999).
    • (1998) Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics , pp. 345
    • Horowitz, D.L.1
  • 23
    • 0040165670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 90 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 715
    • In an important study of interethnic cooperation, James D. Fearon and David D. Laitin have noted the rarity of ethnic violence between the many ethnic groups living in close contact with one another. James D. Fearon & David D. Laitin, Explaining Interethnic Cooperation, 90 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 715 (1996). Steven Fish, a student of post-Communist democratization, finds that ethnic homogeneity is unrelated to democratic achievement in those countries. M. Steven Fish, Democratization's Requisites: The Postcommunist Experience, 14 POST-SOV. AFF. 212 (1998).
    • (1996) Explaining Interethnic Cooperation
    • Fearon, J.D.1    Laitin, D.D.2
  • 24
    • 0038981479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 14 POST-SOV. AFF. 212
    • In an important study of interethnic cooperation, James D. Fearon and David D. Laitin have noted the rarity of ethnic violence between the many ethnic groups living in close contact with one another. James D. Fearon & David D. Laitin, Explaining Interethnic Cooperation, 90 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 715 (1996). Steven Fish, a student of post-Communist democratization, finds that ethnic homogeneity is unrelated to democratic achievement in those countries. M. Steven Fish, Democratization's Requisites: The Postcommunist Experience, 14 POST-SOV. AFF. 212 (1998).
    • (1998) Democratization's Requisites: The Postcommunist Experience
    • Steven Fish, M.1
  • 27
    • 23044522336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Religion, democracy, and the "twin tolerations,"
    • Oct.
    • See Alfred Stepan, Religion, Democracy, and the "Twin Tolerations," J. DEMOCRACY, Oct. 2000, at 37.
    • (2000) J. Democracy , pp. 37
    • Stepan, A.1
  • 28
    • 0039574252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 1, Inglehart labeled these as "survival values" vs. "self-expression values." The level of economic development in each society was measured by 1980 GNP/capita. Its degree of democracy was measured by the sum of Freedom House ratings, 1981-1998. Id.
    • Inglehart, Political Culture, supra note 1, at 3. Inglehart labeled these as "survival values" vs. "self-expression values." The level of economic development in each society was measured by 1980 GNP/capita. Its degree of democracy was measured by the sum of Freedom House ratings, 1981-1998. Id.
    • Political Culture , pp. 3
    • Inglehart1
  • 29
    • 0039574264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-11
    • Id. at 10-11.
  • 31
    • 0003601591 scopus 로고
    • Robert Bates provides a classic illustration of how knowledgeable and democratically elected politicians may pursue policies obviously destructive of their countries' economic well-being, because of their own need to survive politically. ROBERT H. BATES, MARKETS AND STATES IN TROPICAL AFRICA: THE POLITICAL BASIS OF AGRICULTURAL POLICIES (1981). In rational-choice theory as such, a rational actor, strictly defined, will not work for collective benefits because he will receive the benefits regardless of his own efforts and one individual will almost never determine the outcome. See MANCUR OLSON, JR., THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION: PUBLIC GOODS AND THE THEORY OF GROUPS (1965).
    • (1981) Markets and States in Tropical Africa: The Political Basis of Agricultural Policies
    • Bates, R.H.1
  • 32
    • 0004305444 scopus 로고
    • Robert Bates provides a classic illustration of how knowledgeable and democratically elected politicians may pursue policies obviously destructive of their countries' economic well-being, because of their own need to survive politically. ROBERT H. BATES, MARKETS AND STATES IN TROPICAL AFRICA: THE POLITICAL BASIS OF AGRICULTURAL POLICIES (1981). In rational-choice theory as such, a rational actor, strictly defined, will not work for collective benefits because he will receive the benefits regardless of his own efforts and one individual will almost never determine the outcome. See MANCUR OLSON, JR., THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION: PUBLIC GOODS AND THE THEORY OF GROUPS (1965).
    • (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups
    • Olson M., Jr.1
  • 34
    • 0039574246 scopus 로고
    • 5 BELIEFS IN GOVERNMENT
    • There has been wide discussion of a decline in aspects of political participation in advanced democracies, though the evidence is still inconclusive. See MAX KAASE & KENNETH NEWTON, 5 BELIEFS IN GOVERNMENT (1995).
    • (1995)
    • Kaase, M.A.X.1    Newton, K.2
  • 35
    • 0038981493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Today's models of the institutions of democracy evolved slowly and in only a few countries. In the British case, the power of the Crown was gradually shared with the nobility, the gentry, and the rising bourgeoisie. Through the creation of modern parties and other structures of mass mobilization, power was later shared with the adult population and finally vested in a prime minister and cabinet, drawn from the dominant party in the Commons. Although the British Constitution is only partially a written one, and though - historically - the power of Parliament is in principle unlimited, the British system is highly institutionalized. Those in power do not act arbitrarily, the courts operate independently without political interference, and the opposition flourishes.
  • 36
    • 0040759768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The many varieties of proportional representation demonstrate that the number of parties can be reduced or expanded by design. There are also many examples of single-member districts' giving rise to multiparty systems, so the relationship between electoral systems and number of parties is not a strong one. The number of parties reflects the number of dimensions of conflict in the society, as well as the electoral laws.
  • 37
    • 0040759778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are other patterns of executive-legislative relationships. For example, amendments to the Israeli Constitution now provide for the independent and direct election of the prime minister by the electorate.
  • 38
    • 0004011727 scopus 로고
    • For an introduction to the large literature on this debate, see THE FAILURE OF PRESIDENTIAL DEMOCRACY (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994) (Vol. 1: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES; Vol. 2: THE CASE OF LATIN AMERICA); Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, J. DEMOCRACY, Winter 1990, at 51; Juan J. Linz, The Virtues of Parliamentarism, J. DEMOCRACY, Fall 1990, at 84. But see GIOVANNI SARTORI, COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING: AN INQUIRY INTO STRUCTURES, INCENTIVES AND OUTCOMES 97 (1994) (stating: "That presidential systems perform poorly - as Linz maintains. . . - in countries with deep cleavages and with a fragmented party system, is very true. But could they perform better - these conditions remaining equal - under parliamentary forms? Ceteris paribus I think not.").
    • (1994) The Failure of Presidential Democracy
    • Linz, J.J.1    Valenzuela, A.2
  • 39
    • 0040759780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an introduction to the large literature on this debate, see THE FAILURE OF PRESIDENTIAL DEMOCRACY (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994) (Vol. 1: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES; Vol. 2: THE CASE OF LATIN AMERICA); Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, J. DEMOCRACY, Winter 1990, at 51; Juan J. Linz, The Virtues of Parliamentarism, J. DEMOCRACY, Fall 1990, at 84. But see GIOVANNI SARTORI, COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING: AN INQUIRY INTO STRUCTURES, INCENTIVES AND OUTCOMES 97 (1994) (stating: "That presidential systems perform poorly - as Linz maintains. . . - in countries with deep cleavages and with a fragmented party system, is very true. But could they perform better - these conditions remaining equal - under parliamentary forms? Ceteris paribus I think not.").
    • Comparative Perspectives , vol.1
  • 40
    • 0040165681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an introduction to the large literature on this debate, see THE FAILURE OF PRESIDENTIAL DEMOCRACY (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994) (Vol. 1: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES; Vol. 2: THE CASE OF LATIN AMERICA); Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, J. DEMOCRACY, Winter 1990, at 51; Juan J. Linz, The Virtues of Parliamentarism, J. DEMOCRACY, Fall 1990, at 84. But see GIOVANNI SARTORI, COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING: AN INQUIRY INTO STRUCTURES, INCENTIVES AND OUTCOMES 97 (1994) (stating: "That presidential systems perform poorly - as Linz maintains. . . - in countries with deep cleavages and with a fragmented party system, is very true. But could they perform better - these conditions remaining equal - under parliamentary forms? Ceteris paribus I think not.").
    • The Case of Latin America , vol.2
  • 41
    • 69249129841 scopus 로고
    • The perils of presidentialism
    • Winter
    • For an introduction to the large literature on this debate, see THE FAILURE OF PRESIDENTIAL DEMOCRACY (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994) (Vol. 1: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES; Vol. 2: THE CASE OF LATIN AMERICA); Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, J. DEMOCRACY, Winter 1990, at 51; Juan J. Linz, The Virtues of Parliamentarism, J. DEMOCRACY, Fall 1990, at 84. But see GIOVANNI SARTORI, COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING: AN INQUIRY INTO STRUCTURES, INCENTIVES AND OUTCOMES 97 (1994) (stating: "That presidential systems perform poorly - as Linz maintains. . . - in countries with deep cleavages and with a fragmented party system, is very true. But could they perform better - these conditions remaining equal - under parliamentary forms? Ceteris paribus I think not.").
    • (1990) J. Democracy , pp. 51
    • Linz, J.J.1
  • 42
    • 84930558463 scopus 로고
    • The virtues of parliamentarism
    • Fall
    • For an introduction to the large literature on this debate, see THE FAILURE OF PRESIDENTIAL DEMOCRACY (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994) (Vol. 1: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES; Vol. 2: THE CASE OF LATIN AMERICA); Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, J. DEMOCRACY, Winter 1990, at 51; Juan J. Linz, The Virtues of Parliamentarism, J. DEMOCRACY, Fall 1990, at 84. But see GIOVANNI SARTORI, COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING: AN INQUIRY INTO STRUCTURES, INCENTIVES AND OUTCOMES 97 (1994) (stating: "That presidential systems perform poorly - as Linz maintains. . . - in countries with deep cleavages and with a fragmented party system, is very true. But could they perform better - these conditions remaining equal - under parliamentary forms? Ceteris paribus I think not.").
    • (1990) J. Democracy , pp. 84
    • Linz, J.J.1
  • 43
    • 0004084476 scopus 로고
    • stating: "That presidential systems perform poorly - as Linz maintains. . . - in countries with deep cleavages and with a fragmented party system, is very true. But could they perform better - these conditions remaining equal - under parliamentary forms? Ceteris paribus I think not."
    • For an introduction to the large literature on this debate, see THE FAILURE OF PRESIDENTIAL DEMOCRACY (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994) (Vol. 1: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES; Vol. 2: THE CASE OF LATIN AMERICA); Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, J. DEMOCRACY, Winter 1990, at 51; Juan J. Linz, The Virtues of Parliamentarism, J. DEMOCRACY, Fall 1990, at 84. But see GIOVANNI SARTORI, COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING: AN INQUIRY INTO STRUCTURES, INCENTIVES AND OUTCOMES 97 (1994) (stating: "That presidential systems perform poorly - as Linz maintains. . . - in countries with deep cleavages and with a fragmented party system, is very true. But could they perform better - these conditions remaining equal - under parliamentary forms? Ceteris paribus I think not.").
    • (1994) Comparative Constitutional Engineering: An Inquiry into Structures, Incentives and Outcomes , pp. 97
    • Sartori, G.1
  • 48
    • 0039574256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This issue is particularly applicable to consociational regimes, which are discussed below
    • This issue is particularly applicable to consociational regimes, which are discussed below.
  • 49
    • 0040165671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nationalism and the liberal state
    • CONST. Art. 5 (2) (d) (Bosn. & Herz.), translated in 35 ILM 117 (1996), (Ruth Wedgwood ed., 1999) (mutual vetoes are workable only where two conditions are met: where "all relevant parties [are] more or less satisfied with the status quo, so that none is seized by an urgent need to use government as a mechanism of change," and where "the environment is stable so that no external shocks demand the attention of government as a steering mechanism"; id. at 53)
    • CONST. Art. 5 (2) (d) (Bosn. & Herz.), translated in 35 ILM 117 (1996), 〈http://www.ohr.int/gfa/gfa-an4.htm〉; see also Remarks of Douglas Rae, Nationalism and the Liberal State, in AFTER DAYTON: LESSONS OF THE BOSNIAN PEACE 51, 52-53 (Ruth Wedgwood ed., 1999) (mutual vetoes are workable only where two conditions are met: where "all relevant parties [are] more or less satisfied with the status quo, so that none is seized by an urgent need to use government as a mechanism of change," and where "the environment is stable so that no external shocks demand the attention of government as a steering mechanism"; id. at 53), 〈http://www.cfr.org/public/pubs/AfterDay.pdf〉.
    • After Dayton: Lessons of the Bosnian Peace , vol.51 , pp. 52-53
    • Douglas, R.1
  • 50
    • 0040165676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Similar agonies of policymaking and coalition maintenance in France's Third and Fourth Republics led to the transition to the semipresidential Fifth Republic in 1958. Analogous problems of governmental stability in postwar Italy led to repeated calls for strengthening the executive, as well as a partial switch from proportional representation to a system currently consisting of three-quarters single-member districts and one-quarter proportional representation.
  • 51
    • 0038981494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To be sure, no electoral system is unbiased; no matter what choice is made, it will advantage one party and one group over another. It is virtually a rule of politics that those who design electoral systems do so with a clear eye as to what they want to achieve in partisan terms.
  • 52
    • 0038981492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Horowitz, supra note 15
    • Horowitz, supra note 15.
  • 53
    • 0039574247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As Horowitz notes, "There are . . . bottom-up reasons for ethnically based parties once constituencies are homogeneous." Id. at 363. Horowitz records that some countries experimented with electoral laws requiring that "candidates secure secondary support from differently composed constituencies adjacent to theirs." Id. In 1978 Nigeria required that a successful presidential candidate obtain a plurality and, in addition, a minimal level of geographic distribution among states.
  • 55
    • 0038981491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 439
    • Id. at 439.
  • 56
    • 0004338649 scopus 로고
    • 1 COMP. POL. STUD. 32
    • Consociationalism has been explored in the many publications of Arend Lijphart: Typologies of Democratic Systems, 1 COMP. POL. STUD. 32 (1968) ; THE POLITICS OF ACCOMMODATION: PLURALISM AND DEMOCRACY IN THE NETHERLANDS (1968); and DEMOCRACY IN PLURAL SOCIETIES, supra note 31. For a critique of Lijphart's views, see SARTORI, supra note 29, at 69-75.
    • (1968) Typologies of Democratic Systems
    • Lijphart, A.1
  • 57
    • 0003795465 scopus 로고
    • Consociationalism has been explored in the many publications of Arend Lijphart: Typologies of Democratic Systems, 1 COMP. POL. STUD. 32 (1968) ; THE POLITICS OF ACCOMMODATION: PLURALISM AND DEMOCRACY IN THE NETHERLANDS (1968); and DEMOCRACY IN PLURAL SOCIETIES, supra note 31. For a critique of Lijphart's views, see SARTORI, supra note 29, at 69-75.
    • (1968) The Politics of Accommodation: Pluralism And Democracy in The Netherlands
  • 58
    • 84976164527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 31. For a critique of Lijphart's views, see SARTORI, supra note 29
    • Consociationalism has been explored in the many publications of Arend Lijphart: Typologies of Democratic Systems, 1 COMP. POL. STUD. 32 (1968) ; THE POLITICS OF ACCOMMODATION: PLURALISM AND DEMOCRACY IN THE NETHERLANDS (1968); and DEMOCRACY IN PLURAL SOCIETIES, supra note 31. For a critique of Lijphart's views, see SARTORI, supra note 29, at 69-75.
    • Democracy in Plural Societies , pp. 69-75
  • 59
    • 0040759769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The segments, called verzuiling, were both religious and political in nature, with separate segments for Catholics, Protestants, Socialists, and Liberals
    • The segments, called verzuiling, were both religious and political in nature, with separate segments for Catholics, Protestants, Socialists, and Liberals.
  • 60
    • 0038981500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Protestants were concentrated in the north of the Netherlands, and Catholics in the south. Socialists and Liberals were overrepresented in the most economically advanced provinces, North and South Holland
    • Protestants were concentrated in the north of the Netherlands, and Catholics in the south. Socialists and Liberals were overrepresented in the most economically advanced provinces, North and South Holland.
  • 62
    • 0038981498 scopus 로고
    • 1 COMP. POL. 245
    • See Michael C. Hudson, Democracy and Social Mobilization in Lebanese Politics, 1 COMP. POL. 245 (1969). Lijphart notes that economist Arthur Lewis endorsed essentially consociational political structures as most suitable for the plural societies of West African states. See W. ARTHUR LEWIS, POLITICS IN WEST AFRICA, ch. 3 (1965).
    • (1969) Democracy and Social Mobilization in Lebanese Politics
    • Hudson, M.C.1
  • 63
    • 0004186556 scopus 로고
    • ch. 3
    • See Michael C. Hudson, Democracy and Social Mobilization in Lebanese Politics, 1 COMP. POL. 245 (1969). Lijphart notes that economist Arthur Lewis endorsed essentially consociational political structures as most suitable for the plural societies of West African states. See W. ARTHUR LEWIS, POLITICS IN WEST AFRICA, ch. 3 (1965).
    • (1965) Politics in West Africa
    • Lewis, W.A.1
  • 64
    • 84936526885 scopus 로고
    • DONALD L. HOROWITZ, ETHNIC GROUPS IN CONFLICT (1985); DONALD L. HOROWITZ, A DEMOCRATIC SOUTH AFRICA? CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING IN A DIVIDED SOCIETY (1991). For a more recent summary, see Donald L. Horowitz, Constitutional Design: An Oxymoron? Paper Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association (Sept. 3-6, 1998) (corrected version). See also David Wippman, Practical and Legal Constraints on Internal Power Sharing, in INTERNATIONAL LAW AND ETHNIC CONFLICT 211 (David Wippman ed., 1998). Arguing from a rational-choice perspective, Alvin Rabushka and Kenneth A. Shepsle reach a far more pessimistic conclusion concerning the potential for democratic stability under any institutional arrangement in multiethnic societies. They view ethnic conflict as a Hobbesian zero-sum game, where there are no win-win solutions. ALVIN RABUSHKA & KENNETH SHEPSLE, POLITICS IN PLURAL SOCIETIES: A THEORY OF DEMOCRATIC INSTABILITY (1972).
    • (1985) Ethnic Groups In Conflict
    • Horowitz, D.L.1
  • 65
    • 84936527139 scopus 로고
    • DONALD L. HOROWITZ, ETHNIC GROUPS IN CONFLICT (1985); DONALD L. HOROWITZ, A DEMOCRATIC SOUTH AFRICA? CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING IN A DIVIDED SOCIETY (1991). For a more recent summary, see Donald L. Horowitz, Constitutional Design: An Oxymoron? Paper Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association (Sept. 3-6, 1998) (corrected version). See also David Wippman, Practical and Legal Constraints on Internal Power Sharing, in INTERNATIONAL LAW AND ETHNIC CONFLICT 211 (David Wippman ed., 1998). Arguing from a rational-choice perspective, Alvin Rabushka and Kenneth A. Shepsle reach a far more pessimistic conclusion concerning the potential for democratic stability under any institutional arrangement in multiethnic societies. They view ethnic conflict as a Hobbesian zero-sum game, where there are no win-win solutions. ALVIN RABUSHKA & KENNETH SHEPSLE, POLITICS IN PLURAL SOCIETIES: A THEORY OF DEMOCRATIC INSTABILITY (1972).
    • (1991) A Democratic South Africa? Constitutional Engineering in a Divided Society
    • Horowitz, D.L.1
  • 66
    • 0040759773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional design: An oxymoron?
    • Sept. 3-6, corrected version
    • DONALD L. HOROWITZ, ETHNIC GROUPS IN CONFLICT (1985); DONALD L. HOROWITZ, A DEMOCRATIC SOUTH AFRICA? CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING IN A DIVIDED SOCIETY (1991). For a more recent summary, see Donald L. Horowitz, Constitutional Design: An Oxymoron? Paper Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association (Sept. 3-6, 1998) (corrected version). See also David Wippman, Practical and Legal Constraints on Internal Power Sharing, in INTERNATIONAL LAW AND ETHNIC CONFLICT 211 (David Wippman ed., 1998). Arguing from a rational-choice perspective, Alvin Rabushka and Kenneth A. Shepsle reach a far more pessimistic conclusion concerning the potential for democratic stability under any institutional arrangement in multiethnic societies. They view ethnic conflict as a Hobbesian zero-sum game, where there are no win-win solutions. ALVIN RABUSHKA & KENNETH SHEPSLE, POLITICS IN PLURAL SOCIETIES: A THEORY OF DEMOCRATIC INSTABILITY (1972).
    • (1998) Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association
    • Horowitz, D.L.1
  • 67
    • 0011237730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Practical and legal constraints on internal power sharing
    • David Wippman ed.
    • DONALD L. HOROWITZ, ETHNIC GROUPS IN CONFLICT (1985); DONALD L. HOROWITZ, A DEMOCRATIC SOUTH AFRICA? CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING IN A DIVIDED SOCIETY (1991). For a more recent summary, see Donald L. Horowitz, Constitutional Design: An Oxymoron? Paper Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association (Sept. 3-6, 1998) (corrected version). See also David Wippman, Practical and Legal Constraints on Internal Power Sharing, in INTERNATIONAL LAW AND ETHNIC CONFLICT 211 (David Wippman ed., 1998). Arguing from a rational-choice perspective, Alvin Rabushka and Kenneth A. Shepsle reach a far more pessimistic conclusion concerning the potential for democratic stability under any institutional arrangement in multiethnic societies. They view ethnic conflict as a Hobbesian zero-sum game, where there are no win-win solutions. ALVIN RABUSHKA & KENNETH SHEPSLE, POLITICS IN PLURAL SOCIETIES: A THEORY OF DEMOCRATIC INSTABILITY (1972).
    • (1998) International Law and Ethnic Conflict , pp. 211
    • Wippman, D.1
  • 68
    • 0003949427 scopus 로고
    • DONALD L. HOROWITZ, ETHNIC GROUPS IN CONFLICT (1985); DONALD L. HOROWITZ, A DEMOCRATIC SOUTH AFRICA? CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING IN A DIVIDED SOCIETY (1991). For a more recent summary, see Donald L. Horowitz, Constitutional Design: An Oxymoron? Paper Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association (Sept. 3-6, 1998) (corrected version). See also David Wippman, Practical and Legal Constraints on Internal Power Sharing, in INTERNATIONAL LAW AND ETHNIC CONFLICT 211 (David Wippman ed., 1998). Arguing from a rational-choice perspective, Alvin Rabushka and Kenneth A. Shepsle reach a far more pessimistic conclusion concerning the potential for democratic stability under any institutional arrangement in multiethnic societies. They view ethnic conflict as a Hobbesian zero-sum game, where there are no win-win solutions. ALVIN RABUSHKA & KENNETH SHEPSLE, POLITICS IN PLURAL SOCIETIES: A THEORY OF DEMOCRATIC INSTABILITY (1972).
    • (1972) Politics in Plural Societies: A Theory of Democratic Instability
    • Rabushka, A.1    Shepsle, K.2
  • 69
    • 84926359637 scopus 로고
    • 36 REV. POL. 85 Schmitter distinguishes state corporatism from societal corporatism. The former is a "top-down" version inspired by 19th-century Catholic social doctrine and used as the basis for Mussolini's construction of a "corporate" state in Italy, with functional representation through compulsory trade unions and other organizations in a "Chamber of Corporations" that replaced the Chamber of Deputies. It inspired copies with varying degrees of surface credibility in Francoist Spain, Salazar's Portugal, Perón's Argentina, and other authoritarian regimes. Societal corporatism is "bottom up." Membership is voluntary (though pressures to join the dominant organizations are compelling) and is based on independent trade unions and business organizations
    • A seminal article on corporatism is Philippe C. Schmitter, Still the Century of Corporatism? 36 REV. POL. 85 (1974). Schmitter distinguishes state corporatism from societal corporatism. The former is a "top-down" version inspired by 19th-century Catholic social doctrine and used as the basis for Mussolini's construction of a "corporate" state in Italy, with functional representation through compulsory trade unions and other organizations in a "Chamber of Corporations" that replaced the Chamber of Deputies. It inspired copies with varying degrees of surface credibility in Francoist Spain, Salazar's Portugal, Perón's Argentina, and other authoritarian regimes. Societal corporatism is "bottom up." Membership is voluntary (though pressures to join the dominant organizations are compelling) and is based on independent trade unions and business organizations.
    • (1974) Still the Century of Corporatism?
    • Schmitter, P.C.1
  • 70
    • 0038981497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Issues have included income, taxation, health care, education and training, and unemployment and retirement benefits. Trade union and business associations have been convened in "peak" organizations and have met with representatives of the government cabinet to discuss issues and negotiate implementing actions, which they have then recommended both to their constituent organizations and to the parliament. Much of the debate has been held among sectoral professional staffs, largely economists. These representatives speak the same professional language, and yet have been able to integrate political and economic considerations based on experience with their own organizations and the opposing side. Decisions reached were adopted by the constituent organizations and used by the government as the basis for the legislation and policy implementation.
  • 71
    • 0003853324 scopus 로고
    • The corporatist system was really a device for implementing an implicit accord between European social democracy and capitalism (i.e., the owners and managers of industrial and financial institutions). Social democrats renounced any ambitions for nationalization or public ownership and control of industry, and in return gained the guarantee of a substantial share for employees (in the form of both wages and welfare-state benefits) of the increased income achieved through capitalism's productivity and efficiency. See CHARLES S. MAIER, RECASTING BOURGEOIS EUROPE: STABILIZATION IN FRANCE, GERMANY, AND ITALY IN THE DECADE AFTER WORLD WAR I (1975).
    • (1975) Recasting Bourgeois Europe: Stabilization in France, Germany, and Italy in the Decade After World War I
    • Maier, C.S.1
  • 72
    • 0342680234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 51 WORLD POL. 484
    • For example, corporatist models have had great appeal among the equality-minded new democrats of central and Eastern Europe. Anna Seleny argues that a "compromise-corporatist" model characterizes decision making in post-Communist Hungary, while a "confrontation-pluralist" model fits the Polish pattern. Anna Seleny, Old Political Rationalities and New Democracies: Compromise and Confrontation in Hungary and Poland, 51 WORLD POL. 484 (1999).
    • (1999) Old Political Rationalities and New Democracies: Compromise and Confrontation in Hungary and Poland
    • Seleny, A.1
  • 73
    • 0003984012 scopus 로고
    • Phillips Bradley ed., Alfred A. Knopf (1835)
    • See ALEXIS DE TOCQUEVILLE, DEMOCRACY IN AMERICA (Phillips Bradley ed., Alfred A. Knopf 1951) (1835).
    • (1951) Democracy in America
    • De Tocqueville, A.1
  • 75
    • 0000432173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 49 WORLD POL. 401 demonstrating how the rich associational life of Weimar Germany contributed to the discrediting of democracy and facilitated the rise of National Socialism
    • See, e.g., Sheri Berman, Civil Society and the Collapse of the Weimar Republic, 49 WORLD POL. 401 (1997) (demonstrating how the rich associational life of Weimar Germany contributed to the discrediting of democracy and facilitated the rise of National Socialism).
    • (1997) Civil Society and the Collapse of the Weimar Republic
    • Berman, S.1
  • 76
    • 0011105696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The mobilization of political identity in new democracies
    • Samuel H. Barnes & János Simon eds., MCDONOUGH, BARNES, & LÓPEZ PINA, supra note 13
    • This depoliticization was evident throughout Communist Europe and in Spain following the demise of Franco's long reign. See Samuel H. Barnes, The Mobilization of Political Identity in New Democracies, in THE POSTCOMMUNIST CITIZEN 117 (Samuel H. Barnes & János Simon eds., 1998); MCDONOUGH, BARNES, & LÓPEZ PINA, supra note 13.
    • (1998) The Postcommunist Citizen , pp. 117
    • Barnes, S.H.1
  • 77
    • 85050734244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Initiation of new democratic institutions in Eastern Europe and Latin America
    • Arend Lijphart & Carlos H. Waisman eds., The one partial exception, Professor Geddes notes, is labor in Poland
    • Barbara Geddes, Initiation of New Democratic Institutions in Eastern Europe and Latin America, in INSTITUTIONAL DESIGNIN NEW DEMOCRACIES: EASTERN EUROPE AND LATIN AMERICA 15 (Arend Lijphart & Carlos H. Waisman eds., 1996). The one partial exception, Professor Geddes notes, is labor in Poland.
    • (1996) Institutional Designin New Democracies: Eastern Europe and Latin America , pp. 15
    • Geddes, B.1
  • 78
    • 0040759774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 30
    • Id. at 30.
  • 79
    • 0039574251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transformation and the prerequisites of democratic opposition in Central and Eastern Europe
    • supra note 54
    • Employing data from 1990 and 1991, Bernhard Wessels and Hans-Dieter Klingemann explore the possible relationship between social differentiation and the developing party systems in the new democracies of central and Eastern Europe, concluding that there is no close connection. See Bernhard Wessels & Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Transformation and the Prerequisites of Democratic Opposition in Central and Eastern Europe, in THE POSTCOMMUNIST CITIZEN, supra note 54, at 1.
    • The Postcommunist Citizen , pp. 1
    • Wessels, B.1    Klingemann, H.-D.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.