메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 1, Issue 2, 2005, Pages 339-354

Assessing market power: The trade-off between market concentration and multi-market participation

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 27744574180     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhi011     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (10)

References (63)
  • 1
    • 4444238448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'FCC, Faced With Telecom Crisis, Could Let a Bell Buy WorldCom'
    • There has been significant merger activity in the telecommunications and transportation industries in recent years. See, for example, at
    • There has been significant merger activity in the telecommunications and transportation industries in recent years. See, for example, Yochi J. Dreazen, 'FCC, Faced With Telecom Crisis, Could Let a Bell Buy WorldCom,' The Wall Street Journal (2002), at A1
    • (2002) The Wall Street Journal
    • Dreazen, Y.J.1
  • 2
    • 4444238448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Oligopolies Are on the Rise As the Urge to Merge Grows'
    • at
    • Yochi J. Dreazen, Greg Ip and Nicholas Kulish, 'Oligopolies Are on the Rise As the Urge to Merge Grows,' The Wall Street Journal (2002), at A1
    • (2002) The Wall Street Journal
    • Dreazen, Y.J.1    Ip, G.2    Kulish, N.3
  • 3
    • 84993063438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Footprints In Cyberspace: Toward A Theory of Mergers In Network Industries'
    • and Dennis L. Weisman, 'Footprints In Cyberspace: Toward A Theory of Mergers In Network Industries,' 1 (4) info 305 (1999).
    • (1999) Info. , vol.1 , Issue.4 , pp. 305
    • Weisman, D.L.1
  • 4
    • 0036921736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Does Bell Company Entry into Long-Distance Telecommunications Benefit Consumers?'
    • This argument differs from the familiar double-marginalization rationale for vertical mergers. See, for example
    • This argument differs from the familiar double-marginalization rationale for vertical mergers. See, for example, Jerry A. Hausman, Gregory K. Leonard and J. Gregory Sidak, 'Does Bell Company Entry into Long-Distance Telecommunications Benefit Consumers?', 70 (2) Antitrust Law Journal 463 (2002).
    • (2002) Antitrust Law Journal , vol.70 , Issue.2 , pp. 463
    • Hausman, J.A.1    Leonard, G.K.2    Sidak, J.G.3
  • 5
    • 27744479267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes
    • The term 'footprint' in this context refers to the degree to which the MMP participates in other markets.
  • 6
    • 0001262636 scopus 로고
    • 'Horizontal Mergers: An Equilibrium Analysis'
    • The parallels with Farrell and Shapiro are noteworthy. Welfare can rise with market concentration in the Farrell and Shapiro framework if demand is redistributed from relatively inefficient to relatively efficient firms. In this analysis, welfare can rise with market concentration if demand is redistributed from IMPs to MMPs. This occurs because, in the case of complementary demands, the MMP takes into account, whereas the IMP does not, that a higher price in market i reduces demand in market j, where i ≠ j. In the case of substitutable demands, precisely the opposite is true
    • The parallels with Farrell and Shapiro are noteworthy. Welfare can rise with market concentration in the Farrell and Shapiro framework if demand is redistributed from relatively inefficient to relatively efficient firms. In this analysis, welfare can rise with market concentration if demand is redistributed from IMPs to MMPs. This occurs because, in the case of complementary demands, the MMP takes into account, whereas the IMP does not, that a higher price in market i reduces demand in market j, where i ≠ j. In the case of substitutable demands, precisely the opposite is true. Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro, 'Horizontal Mergers: An Equilibrium Analysis', 80 (1) The American Economic Review 107 (1990).
    • (1990) The American Economic Review , vol.80 , Issue.1 , pp. 107
    • Farrell, J.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 7
    • 24644462122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Network Effects'
    • These are sometimes referred to as 'network effects' or network externalities. For a comprehensive survey of the literature, see Martin Cave, Sumit Majumdar, and Ingo Vogelsang (eds), (Amsterdam: North-Holland)
    • These are sometimes referred to as 'network effects' or network externalities. For a comprehensive survey of the literature, see Stanley J. Liebowitz and Stephen E. Margolis, 'Network Effects', in Martin Cave, Sumit Majumdar, and Ingo Vogelsang (eds), Handbook of Telecommunications Economics (Amsterdam: North-Holland 2002) vol. 1, 75-96.
    • (2002) Handbook of Telecommunications Economics , vol.1 , pp. 75-96
    • Liebowitz, S.J.1    Margolis, S.E.2
  • 8
    • 0348017025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Antitrust Divestiture in Network Industries'
    • For a discussion of network effects and their prominent role in recent high-profile court cases, see (Winter)
    • For a discussion of network effects and their prominent role in recent high-profile court cases, see Howard J. Shelanski and J. Gregory Sidak, 'Antitrust Divestiture in Network Industries,' 68 (1) The University of Chicago Law Review 1 (Winter 2001).
    • (2001) The University of Chicago Law Review , vol.68 , Issue.1 , pp. 1
    • Shelanski, H.J.1    Sidak, J.G.2
  • 9
    • 27744492316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In contrast, when demands are substitutable, multi-market participation serves to compound the price-increasing effect of higher market concentration.
  • 10
    • 0040077830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Trends in Aggregate Concentration in the United States'
    • White conducted a recent analysis of aggregate concentration trends in the U.S. economy. Despite significant merger activity in selected industries, he finds no evidence of a wholesale increase in aggregate market concentration. See
    • White conducted a recent analysis of aggregate concentration trends in the U.S. economy. Despite significant merger activity in selected industries, he finds no evidence of a wholesale increase in aggregate market concentration. See Lawrence J. White, 'Trends in Aggregate Concentration in the United States', 16 (4) Journal of Economic Perspectives 137 (2002).
    • (2002) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.16 , Issue.4 , pp. 137
    • White, L.J.1
  • 11
    • 0035579072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Antitrust in the New Economy'
    • Richard A. Posner, 'Antitrust in the New Economy', 68 Antitrust Law Journal 925 (2001).
    • (2001) Antitrust Law Journal , vol.68 , pp. 925
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 12
    • 0004199595 scopus 로고
    • The guidelines state at section 1.5 that 'Unlike the four-firm concentration ratio, the HHI reflects both the distribution of the market shares of the top four firms, and the composition of the market outside the top four firms.' Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, [Inclusive of 8 April 1997 Revisions]. We argue subsequently that a careful assessment of the merits of a proposed merger requires that antitrust authorities go even further - to investigate the distribution of market concentration across IMPs and MMPs, pre/post-merger
    • The guidelines state at section 1.5 that 'Unlike the four-firm concentration ratio, the HHI reflects both the distribution of the market shares of the top four firms, and the composition of the market outside the top four firms.' Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 1992 [Inclusive of 8 April 1997 Revisions]. We argue subsequently that a careful assessment of the merits of a proposed merger requires that antitrust authorities go even further - to investigate the distribution of market concentration across IMPs and MMPs, pre/post-merger.
    • (1992) Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 13
    • 27744454699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at section 1.51
    • Id., at section 1.51.
  • 14
    • 27744495824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at section 1.51
    • Id.
  • 15
    • 27744489264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the Nash equilibrium of the Cournot game, each firm chooses an output level that maximizes its profit given the output choice of each of its rivals. A Nash equilibrium thus represents a simultaneously rational choice of output for each firm in the market
    • In the Nash equilibrium of the Cournot game, each firm chooses an output level that maximizes its profit given the output choice of each of its rivals. A Nash equilibrium thus represents a simultaneously rational choice of output for each firm in the market.
  • 17
    • 84960612322 scopus 로고
    • 'The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly Power'
    • at
    • Abba P. Lerner, 'The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly Power', 1 (3) The Review of Economic Studies (1934), at 157
    • (1934) The Review of Economic Studies , vol.1 , Issue.3 , pp. 157
    • Lerner, A.P.1
  • 19
    • 84936443416 scopus 로고
    • 'Industrial Economics: An Overview'
    • See at
    • See Richard Schmalensee, 'Industrial Economics: An Overview', 98 (392) The Economic Journal (1988), at 643.
    • (1988) The Economic Journal , vol.98 , Issue.392 , pp. 643
    • Schmalensee, R.1
  • 20
    • 0003851002 scopus 로고
    • Supreme Court affirmed in Reiter v Sonotone
    • Judge Bork argues that 'The Sherman Act was clearly presented and debated as a consumer welfare prescription' - A view the U.S. A consumer welfare prescription is synonymous with the non-increasing price condition, abstracting from quality considerations. (New York: Macmillan)
    • Judge Bork argues that 'The Sherman Act was clearly presented and debated as a consumer welfare prescription' - a view the U.S. Supreme Court affirmed in Reiter v Sonotone. A consumer welfare prescription is synonymous with the non-increasing price condition, abstracting from quality considerations. Robert H. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox (New York: Macmillan 1978) 66
    • (1978) The Antitrust Paradox , pp. 66
    • Bork, R.H.1
  • 21
    • 0346067276 scopus 로고
    • Reiter v Sonotone Corp. et al
    • No. 78-690, Supreme Court of the United States
    • and Reiter v Sonotone Corp. et al., No. 78-690, Supreme Court of the United States. 442 U.S. 343, 1979.
    • (1979) U.S. , vol.442 , pp. 343
  • 22
    • 0001652957 scopus 로고
    • 'Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Trade-offs'
    • For an early formal analysis of the trade-off between market concentration and merger efficiencies, see
    • For an early formal analysis of the trade-off between market concentration and merger efficiencies, see Oliver Williamson, 'Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Trade-offs', 58 American Economic Review 18 (1968).
    • (1968) American Economic Review , vol.58 , pp. 18
    • Williamson, O.1
  • 23
    • 27744595646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An IMP in market i serves only market i. A MMP in market i serves market i and at least one other market h, i ≠ h.
  • 24
    • 0141576778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'A Generalized Pricing Rule For Multi-Market Cournot Oligopoly'
    • See
    • See Dennis L. Weisman, 'A Generalized Pricing Rule For Multi-Market Cournot Oligopoly,' 81 (1) Economics Letters 95 (2003).
    • (2003) Economics Letters , vol.81 , Issue.1 , pp. 95
    • Weisman, D.L.1
  • 25
    • 27744474205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ii for some, but not all, markets i.
  • 26
    • 0004217626 scopus 로고
    • Tirole derives a mark-up rule for a price-setting, multi-product monopolist with interdependent demands. This rule indicates that when the goods are complements, the multi-product monopolist sets a lower price than a single-product monopolist operating independently in each market. The complementary nature of demand forces the multi-product monopolist, but not the single-product monopolist, to account for the fact that a higher price in market i reduces demand in market h. The logic underlying this analysis is similar except that it is cast in terms of MMPs and IMPs rather than multi-product and single-product monopolists, respectively. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press)
    • Tirole derives a mark-up rule for a price-setting, multi-product monopolist with interdependent demands. This rule indicates that when the goods are complements, the multi-product monopolist sets a lower price than a single-product monopolist operating independently in each market. The complementary nature of demand forces the multi-product monopolist, but not the single-product monopolist, to account for the fact that a higher price in market i reduces demand in market h. The logic underlying this analysis is similar except that it is cast in terms of MMPs and IMPs rather than multi-product and single-product monopolists, respectively. Jean Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press 1988) 70.
    • (1988) The Theory of Industrial Organization , pp. 70
    • Tirole, J.1
  • 27
    • 27744597437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The cross-demand elasticity measures the percentage change in (inverse) demand in market i with respect to a 1 % change in quantity demanded in market h. This differs from the more familiar cross-price elasticity, which measures the percentage change in quantity demanded in market i with respect to a 1 % change in price in market h.
  • 28
    • 27744587966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This case raises the possibility that a MMP may have an incentive to set price below marginal cost in selected markets. See, above n 20.
  • 29
    • 27744448156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is important to recognize that the degree of complementarity (substitutability) increases as the cross-demand elasticity decreases in absolute value.
  • 30
    • 27744598829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ih → ∞.
  • 31
    • 27744597157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Market Concentration, Multi-Market Participation and Mergers In Network Industries'
    • It is possible to examine this trade-off when IMPs and MMPs operate simultaneously in a given market, but this requires imposing additional structure on the demand functions. For example, Weisman derives a simple expression for the marginal rate of substitution of MMPs for IMPs that depends only on the parameters of the symmetric, linear demand functions. See (forthcoming)
    • It is possible to examine this trade-off when IMPs and MMPs operate simultaneously in a given market, but this requires imposing additional structure on the demand functions. For example, Weisman derives a simple expression for the marginal rate of substitution of MMPs for IMPs that depends only on the parameters of the symmetric, linear demand functions. See Dennis L. Weisman, 'Market Concentration, Multi-Market Participation and Mergers In Network Industries', 4 (2) The Review of Network Economics (2005 forthcoming).
    • (2005) The Review of Network Economics , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Weisman, D.L.1
  • 32
    • 27744607073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • i (0, 2) = 20 > 15, ceteris paribus. Hence, in the case of substitutes, traditional merger analysis understates the upward pricing pressures resulting from higher market concentration
    • i (0, 2) = 20 > 15, ceteris paribus. Hence, in the case of substitutes, traditional merger analysis understates the upward pricing pressures resulting from higher market concentration.
  • 33
    • 27744566060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • i = 2
    • i = 2.
  • 34
    • 27744471498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The critical value of z is actually 2.5, but recall that z is constrained to take on only integer values
    • The critical value of z is actually 2.5, but recall that z is constrained to take on only integer values.
  • 35
    • 0004004432 scopus 로고
    • Note that this type of market consolidation poses no difficulties for Judge Bork's definition of competition. Judge Bork argues that: 'Competition,' for purposes of antitrust analysis, must be understood as a term of art signifying any state of affairs in which consumer welfare cannot be increased by judicial decree. He therefore rejects the idea that 'competition' is synonymous with 'rivalry.' See at
    • Note that this type of market consolidation poses no difficulties for Judge Bork's definition of competition. Judge Bork argues that: 'Competition,' for purposes of antitrust analysis, must be understood as a term of art signifying any state of affairs in which consumer welfare cannot be increased by judicial decree. He therefore rejects the idea that 'competition' is synonymous with 'rivalry.' See Bork, above n 16, at 58.
    • (1978) The Antitrust Paradox , pp. 58
    • Bork, R.H.1
  • 36
    • 27744507882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This possibility, while perhaps intriguing, would still have to be reconciled with the specific wording contained in Section 7 of the Clayton Act which proscribes acquisitions 'wherein any line of commerce or in any activity affecting commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or tend to create a monopoly.' Clayton Act. 15 USCS §18
    • This possibility, while perhaps intriguing, would still have to be reconciled with the specific wording contained in Section 7 of the Clayton Act which proscribes acquisitions 'wherein any line of commerce or in any activity affecting commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or tend to create a monopoly.' Clayton Act. 15 USCS §18 (2003).
    • (2003)
  • 37
    • 27744520481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Market Concentration, Multi-Market Participation and Antitrust'
    • For a formal derivation of this result, see (November)
    • For a formal derivation of this result, see Dennis L. Weisman, 'Market Concentration, Multi-Market Participation and Antitrust', KSU Working Paper (November 2004).
    • (2004) KSU Working Paper
    • Weisman, D.L.1
  • 38
    • 0010332510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'A Consumer-Welfare Approach to the Mandatory Unbundling of Telecommunications Networks'
    • For an insightful discussion of the consumer welfare standard in antitrust jurisprudence, see at
    • For an insightful discussion of the consumer welfare standard in antitrust jurisprudence, see Jerry A. Hausman and J. Gregory Sidak, 'A Consumer-Welfare Approach to the Mandatory Unbundling of Telecommunications Networks', 109 The Yale Law Journal (1999), at 452-53.
    • (1999) The Yale Law Journal , vol.109 , pp. 452-453
    • Hausman, J.A.1    Sidak, J.G.2
  • 39
    • 27744532791 scopus 로고
    • See also (Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins Press)
    • See also Hans B. Thorelli, The Federal Antitrust Law (Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins Press 1955).
    • (1955) The Federal Antitrust Law
    • Thorelli, H.B.1
  • 40
    • 27744590624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is not to suggest that the applications discussed herein are necessarily restricted to network industries. Consider, for example, the possibility that consumption of a particular good in one geographic market increases the likelihood of consumption of that good in another geographic market.
  • 42
    • 0003889424 scopus 로고
    • Empirical demand analysis in the telecommunications industry confirms the existence of demand complementarities in the form of point-to-point traffic patterns. See, for example, (Boston, MA: Kluwer)
    • Empirical demand analysis in the telecommunications industry confirms the existence of demand complementarities in the form of point-to-point traffic patterns. See, for example, Lester D. Taylor, Telecommunications Demand In Theory and Practice (Boston, MA: Kluwer 1994);
    • (1994) Telecommunications Demand In Theory and Practice
    • Taylor, L.D.1
  • 43
    • 0003317972 scopus 로고
    • 'A General Theory of Point-to-Point Long-Distance Demand'
    • A. de Fontenay, M.H. Shugard and D.S. Sibley (eds), (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co)
    • and Alexander C. Larson, Dale E. Lehman, and Dennis L. Weisman, 'A General Theory of Point-to-Point Long-Distance Demand', in A. de Fontenay, M.H. Shugard and D.S. Sibley (eds), Telecommunications Demand Modelling (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co, 1990) 299-318.
    • (1990) Telecommunications Demand Modelling , pp. 299-318
    • Larson, A.C.1    Lehman, D.E.2    Weisman, D.L.3
  • 44
    • 0009608736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'The Remaining Role for Government Policy in the Deregulated Airline Industry'
    • Sam Peltzman and Clifford Winston (eds), (Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center For Regulatory Studies)
    • Steven A. Morrison and Clifford Winston, 'The Remaining Role for Government Policy in the Deregulated Airline Industry', in Sam Peltzman and Clifford Winston (eds), Deregulation of Network Industries (Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center For Regulatory Studies 2000) 1-40.
    • (2000) Deregulation of Network Industries , pp. 1-40
    • Morrison, S.A.1    Winston, C.2
  • 45
    • 0034353957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'The Price Effects of International Airline Alliances'
    • These findings may have implications not only for mergers, but also for alliances between commercial airlines. For example, Brueckner and Whalen found that international alliances can reduce interline airfares without necessarily raising fares in those markets in which the alliance partners compete directly. See
    • These findings may have implications not only for mergers, but also for alliances between commercial airlines. For example, Brueckner and Whalen found that international alliances can reduce interline airfares without necessarily raising fares in those markets in which the alliance partners compete directly. See Jan K. Brueckner and W. Tom Whalen, 'The Price Effects of International Airline Alliances', 43 Journal of Competition Law and Economics 503 (2000).
    • (2000) Journal of Competition Law and Economics , vol.43 , pp. 503
    • Brueckner, J.K.1    Whalen, W.T.2
  • 46
    • 0141604302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Competition in the Deregulated Railroad Industry: Sources, Effects, and Policy Issues'
    • Sam Peltzman and Clifford Winston (eds), (Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center For Regulatory Studies)
    • Curtis Grimm and Clifford Winston, 'Competition in the Deregulated Railroad Industry: Sources, Effects, and Policy Issues', in Sam Peltzman and Clifford Winston (eds), Deregulation of Network Industries (Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center For Regulatory Studies 2000) 41-71.
    • (2000) Deregulation of Network Industries , pp. 41-71
    • Grimm, C.1    Winston, C.2
  • 48
    • 27744494000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Flawed Efforts to Apply Modern Antitrust Law to Network Industries'
    • For a critique of the application of modern antitrust law to network industries, Robert Hahn (ed), (Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies)
    • For a critique of the application of modern antitrust law to network industries, see George L. Priest, 'Flawed Efforts to Apply Modern Antitrust Law to Network Industries', in Robert Hahn (ed), High Stakes Antitrust: The Last Hurrah? (Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies 2003) 117-57.
    • (2003) High Stakes Antitrust: The Last Hurrah? , pp. 117-157
    • Priest, G.L.1
  • 49
    • 27744434943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'AT&T Wireless, Cingular in Talks on Possible Deal'
    • (On-Line Edition)
    • Jesse Drucker and Almar Latour, 'AT&T Wireless, Cingular in Talks on Possible Deal', The Wall Street Journal (2004) (On-Line Edition).
    • (2004) The Wall Street Journal
    • Drucker, J.1    Latour, A.2
  • 50
    • 27744484855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Applications of AT&T Wireless Services, Inc. and Cingular Wireless Corporation For Consent to Transfer Control of Licenses and Authorizations, WT Docket No. 04-70, 26 October
    • Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Applications of AT&T Wireless Services, Inc. and Cingular Wireless Corporation For Consent to Transfer Control of Licenses and Authorizations, WT Docket No. 04-70, 26 October 2004.
    • (2004)
  • 51
    • 27744567673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These are Cingular, Nextel, Sprint PCS, T-Mobile, and Verizon Wireless. Federal Communications Commission, Annual Report and Analysis of Competitive Market Conditions With Respect to Commercial Mobile Services, Ninth Report. WT Docket No. 04-111, 28 September at para At the time of this writing, a merger between Sprint PCS and Nextel is pending
    • These are Cingular, Nextel, Sprint PCS, T-Mobile, and Verizon Wireless. Federal Communications Commission, Annual Report and Analysis of Competitive Market Conditions With Respect to Commercial Mobile Services, Ninth Report. WT Docket No. 04-111, 28 September 2004, at para 36. At the time of this writing, a merger between Sprint PCS and Nextel is pending.
    • (2004) , pp. 36
  • 52
    • 84889295207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Semi-Annual Wireless Industry Survey'
    • These carriers collectively operate 3,123 wireless systems in the U.S. and serve in excess of 180.46 million subscribers as of 26 March 2005. See CTIA at http://www.ctia.org/and CTIA and Cellular Telecommunications and Internet Association (CTIA)
    • These carriers collectively operate 3,123 wireless systems in the U.S. and serve in excess of 180.46 million subscribers as of 26 March 2005. See CTIA at http://www.ctia.org/and CTIA (2005) and Cellular Telecommunications and Internet Association (CTIA), 'Semi-Annual Wireless Industry Survey', http://www.ctia.org/public_policy/ statistics/index.cfm/AID/10030 (2004).
    • (2004)
  • 53
    • 27744527596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As of 2004, 276 million people, or 97% of the population in the U.S., live in counties in which there are three or more wireless providers. Approximately 250 million people, or 87% of the population in the U.S., live in counties in which there are five or more wireless providers. More than 216 million people, or 76% of the population in the U.S., can now choose from among six or more different wireless providers. Finally, 84 million people, or almost 30% of the population, live in counties served by seven or more different wireless providers. See FCC, above n 44, at para 49. This increasing competition has led to a pronounced reduction in prices. For example, average revenue per minute declined from dollar;0.47 per minute in 1994 to dollar;0.10 at the beginning of 2003, a reduction of 79%
    • As of 2004, 276 million people, or 97% of the population in the U.S., live in counties in which there are three or more wireless providers. Approximately 250 million people, or 87% of the population in the U.S., live in counties in which there are five or more wireless providers. More than 216 million people, or 76% of the population in the U.S., can now choose from among six or more different wireless providers. Finally, 84 million people, or almost 30% of the population, live in counties served by seven or more different wireless providers. See FCC, above n 44, at para 49. This increasing competition has led to a pronounced reduction in prices. For example, average revenue per minute declined from dollar;0.47 per minute in 1994 to dollar;0.10 at the beginning of 2003, a reduction of 79%.
  • 55
    • 27744530304 scopus 로고
    • As a result of consolidation, the number of Class I railroads in the U.S. declined from 40 in 1980 to 12 in 1993. See Association of American Railroads, Washington, DC
    • As a result of consolidation, the number of Class I railroads in the U.S. declined from 40 in 1980 to 12 in 1993. See Association of American Railroads, Washington, DC, 1981, at 2
    • (1981) , pp. 2
  • 56
    • 27744541266 scopus 로고
    • (Class I railroads are defined by operating revenue thresholds that are adjusted annually for inflation. In 2002, a class I railroad was defined as any railroad with at least dollar;272 million in annual revenues. See Association of American Railroads, Washington D.C., 2003, at 3). In 2003, there were only seven remaining Class I Railroads in the U.S. These are the Norfolk Southern, the Kansas City Southern, the Burlington Northern/Santa Fe, the Canadian National, the Soo Line (owned by the Canadian Pacific), the Union Pacific and CSX Transportation. See Surface Transportation Board, Office of Economics, Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended December 31, 2002, at 3
    • 1994, p. 3. (Class I railroads are defined by operating revenue thresholds that are adjusted annually for inflation. In 2002, a class I railroad was defined as any railroad with at least dollar;272 million in annual revenues. See Association of American Railroads, Washington D.C., 2003, at 3). In 2003, there were only seven remaining Class I Railroads in the U.S. These are the Norfolk Southern, the Kansas City Southern, the Burlington Northern/Santa Fe, the Canadian National, the Soo Line (owned by the Canadian Pacific), the Union Pacific and CSX Transportation. See Surface Transportation Board, Office of Economics, Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended December 31, 2002, at 3.
    • (1994) , pp. 3
  • 57
    • 27744463474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Surface Transportation Board, Office of Economics, Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended December 31
    • See Surface Transportation Board, Office of Economics, Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended December 31, 2001, at 9.
    • (2001) , pp. 9
  • 58
    • 27744486135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Surface Transportation Board, Office of Economics, Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended
    • See December 31
    • Id., at 43.
    • (2001) , pp. 43
  • 59
    • 27744486135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Surface Transportation Board, Office of Economics, Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended
    • December 31
    • Id., at 10.
    • (2001) , pp. 10
  • 60
    • 27744480154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Surface Transportation Board, Office of Economics, Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended December 31
    • The STB goes on to note that whereas their previous policy statement on mergers focused on 'greater economic efficiency' and 'improved service' as the most likely and significant public service benefits, the new policy statement adds enhanced competition as an important public interest benefit
    • Id., at 14.
    • (2001) , pp. 14
  • 61
    • 27744513444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Surface Transportation Board Decision, SBC Ex Parte No. 582 (Sub-No.1), Major Rail Consolidation Procedures, 11 June
    • Surface Transportation Board Decision, SBC Ex Parte No. 582 (Sub-No.1), Major Rail Consolidation Procedures, 11 June 2001, at 14.
    • (2001) , pp. 14
  • 62
    • 27744493053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Analysis, and Administration, Statistics of Class I Freight and Railroads in the United States for the Year Ended
    • In fact, despite significant consolidation in the railroad industry, inflation-adjusted, railroad rates have decreased by more than 45% since 1984. See Surface Transportation Board, December 31 note 11
    • In fact, despite significant consolidation in the railroad industry, inflation-adjusted, railroad rates have decreased by more than 45% since 1984. See Surface Transportation Board, above n 48, at n 11.
    • (2001) , pp. 9
  • 63
    • 0004199595 scopus 로고
    • See Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission at section 4
    • See Department of Justice, above n 9, at section 4.
    • (1992) Horizontal Merger Guidelines


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.