메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn , Issue 41, 2005, Pages 159-209

The transition to digtal television

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

DIGITIZATION; ECONOMIC POLICY; TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE; TELECOMMUNICATION;

EID: 14244250550     PISSN: 02664658     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (34)

References (70)
  • 1
    • 14244253396 scopus 로고
    • The US Federal Communications Commission began its first inquiry into what was then called 'advanced television'
    • The US Federal Communications Commission began its first inquiry into what was then called 'advanced television' in 1987.
    • (1987)
  • 2
    • 14244267551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A few definitions are in order. A good is said to be non-rival if one person's consumption of the good does not reduce the ability of other consumers to consume it. A good is non-excludable if people cannot be excluded from consuming it. A pure public good is non-rival and non-excludable. Before the advent of encryption technology, over the air broadcasting was the perfect example of a pure public good. An excludable public good is non-rival. Since the cost of provision of an excludable public good is constant, the average cost decreases with the number of units sold. An excludable public good is equivalent to a natural monopoly
    • A few definitions are in order. A good is said to be non-rival if one person's consumption of the good does not reduce the ability of other consumers to consume it. A good is non-excludable if people cannot be excluded from consuming it. A pure public good is non-rival and non-excludable. Before the advent of encryption technology, over the air broadcasting was the perfect example of a pure public good. An excludable public good is non-rival. Since the cost of provision of an excludable public good is constant, the average cost decreases with the number of units sold. An excludable public good is equivalent to a natural monopoly.
  • 3
    • 14244254744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Equivalently, the cost of delivery of any given signal does not depend on the number of (connected) viewers who actually tune in. Delivery through broadcasting is effective for the purpose of transmitting a large amount of information to many receivers. One-to-one communication (or 'narrowcasting') requires instead more bandwidth and so can allow the transmission of less content. Nevertheless, in the near future it will be possible to transmit video on demand through broadband and especially optical fibre cable to the home
    • Equivalently, the cost of delivery of any given signal does not depend on the number of (connected) viewers who actually tune in. Delivery through broadcasting is effective for the purpose of transmitting a large amount of information to many receivers. One-to-one communication (or 'narrowcasting') requires instead more bandwidth and so can allow the transmission of less content. Nevertheless, in the near future it will be possible to transmit video on demand through broadband and especially optical fibre cable to the home.
  • 4
    • 14244267968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At each point in time, each viewer then selects the channel to which to tune in
    • At each point in time, each viewer then selects the channel to which to tune in.
  • 5
    • 14244258789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Terrestrial' refers to broadcasting by a land-based radio transmitter
    • 'Terrestrial' refers to broadcasting by a land-based radio transmitter.
  • 6
    • 14244255445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also the action plan of the European Commission on information society entitled 'cEurope 2005' 2002): 'In order to speed up the transition to digital television, Member States should create transparency as far as the conditions for the envisaged switchover are concerned. Member States should publish by end 2003 their intentions regarding a possible switchover. These could include a road map, and an assessment of market conditions, and possibly a date for the closure of analogue terrestrial television broadcasting which would enable the recovery and refarming of frequencies. National switchover plans should also be an opportunity to demonstrate a platform-neutral approach to digital television, taking into account competing delivery mechanisms (primarily satellite, cable and terrestrial).'
    • See also the action plan of the European Commission on information society entitled 'cEurope 2005' 2002): 'In order to speed up the transition to digital television, Member States should create transparency as far as the conditions for the envisaged switchover are concerned. Member States should publish by end 2003 their intentions regarding a possible switchover. These could include a road map, and an assessment of market conditions, and possibly a date for the closure of analogue terrestrial television broadcasting which would enable the recovery and refarming of frequencies. National switchover plans should also be an opportunity to demonstrate a platform-neutral approach to digital television, taking into account competing delivery mechanisms (primarily satellite, cable and terrestrial).'
  • 7
    • 14244261800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Armstrong M. and Rochet, J.-C. and J. Tirole (2003) On the analysis of competition in two-sided markets
    • See Armstrong M. (2002) and Rochet, J.-C. and J. Tirole (2003) on the analysis of competition in two-sided markets.
    • (2002)
  • 8
    • 14244255667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that the public good nature of content production is different from the public good nature of broadcast delivery discussed in the introduction. To appreciate the difference, notice that a film is rival in consumption if distributed through DVD, but nonrival if distributed through a broadcast network. But in both cases, the marginal cost of serving an additional viewer is very small.
  • 9
    • 14244259846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Waterman D. and A. A. Weiss and Crawford G. (2000) for analyses of the US experience in the regulation of vertically integrated cable companies. See Armstrong M. (1999) and Harbord D. and M. Ottaviani (2001 ) for overviews of content provision in the UK pay television market. See Crawford G. (2000) and Goolsbee and Petrin (2004) on competition across platforms in the US
    • See Waterman D. and A. A. Weiss (1997) and Crawford G. (2000) for analyses of the US experience in the regulation of vertically integrated cable companies. See Armstrong M. (1999) and Harbord D. and M. Ottaviani (2001) for overviews of content provision in the UK pay television market. See Crawford G. (2000) and Goolsbee and Petrin (2004) on competition across platforms in the US.
    • (1997)
  • 10
    • 14244252956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, in the UK in 2001 BSkyB offered a choice between three basic packages with increasing number of channels (value, popular and family) and offers two premium film channels (Moviemax and Sky Premiere) and two premium sport channels (Sky Sports 1 and 2)
    • For example, in the UK in 2001 BSkyB offered a choice between three basic packages with increasing number of channels (value, popular and family) and offers two premium film channels (Moviemax and Sky Premiere) and two premium sport channels (Sky Sports 1 and 2).
  • 11
    • 14244250015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Portability is believed to be the main advantage of the DVB-T standard adopted in Europe for terrestrial broadcasting over the American ATSC standard
    • Portability is believed to be the main advantage of the DVB-T standard adopted in Europe for terrestrial broadcasting over the American ATSC standard.
  • 12
    • 14244251773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although most households tend to have more than one television set on average, in our model we focus on the reception equipment necessary for the main television set. Many households currently view FTA analogue television from the secondary television, even though they have access to multichannel television services through their main set. Our model call be extended to consider the incentives for conversion of secondary television sets
    • Although most households tend to have more than one television set on average, in our model we focus on the reception equipment necessary for the main television set. Many households currently view FTA analogue television from the secondary television, even though they have access to multichannel television services through their main set. Our model call be extended to consider the incentives for conversion of secondary television sets.
  • 13
    • 14244259010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Chapter 12 of Rohlfs J.H. for a discussion of the involvement of the US government in co-ordinating television standardization processes. See Faulhaber G. and D. Farber (2004) for an account of how licences for television broadcasting came about in the US
    • See Chapter 12 of Rohlfs, J.H. (2001) for a discussion of the involvement of the US government in co-ordinating television standardization processes. See Faulhaber G. and D. Farber (2004) for an account of how licences for television broadcasting came about in the US.
    • (2001)
  • 14
    • 14244269077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the discussion in Cramton P., et al. on the possibility of designing mechanisms to allocate the spectrum while it is still occupied by analogue broadcasters
    • See the discussion in Cramton P., et al. (1998) on the possibility of designing mechanisms to allocate the spectrum while it is still occupied by analogue broadcasters.
    • (1998)
  • 15
    • 14244268638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an extensive discussion of universal access in broadcasting see the UK Government's Communications White Paper 'A New Future for Communications', Chapter 3 'Ensuring Universal Access' (2000). The government is committed to ensure that people living in all parts of the UK, however remote, should have access to television. Serving residents in remote rural areas is expensive and not economically viable for commercial organizations. Universal access to television has so far been achieved through direct government intervention, rather than regulation of market operators. In the telecommunications industry, regulators have instead introduced schemes to give incentives to private providers for universal provision. We refer to Laffont, J.-J. and J. Tirole A. (2000) for a discussion of the principles of universal service policies and to Riordan (2002) for a recent review of universal service policies applied to fixed telephony. Sorana V. (2000) proposes the use of auction mechanisms to determine universal service subsidies. Similar incentive schemes could be used to ensure universal provision of television services through private providers.
    • (2000)
  • 16
    • 14244251086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is often done by mobile phone operators and pay television networks. Essentially, well-defined property rights on the ownership of the network can alleviate the problem of network externalities
    • This is often done by mobile phone operators and pay television networks. Essentially, well-defined property rights on the ownership of the network can alleviate the problem of network externalities.
  • 17
    • 14244263754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More broadly, this raises the issue of privatization of the UHF spectrum, discussed above. See also Hazlett T. (2001) and Cramton, P., et al
    • More broadly, this raises the issue of privatization of the UHF spectrum, discussed above. See also Hazlett T. (2001) and Cramton, P., et al. (1998).
    • (1998)
  • 18
    • 14244255666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Anderson S. and Coate S. for a model of television competition in which increased availability of television channels can improve social welfare by reducing the cost of advertising. In a recent empirical paper, Djankov, S., et al. (2003) find that concentrated (as well as public) ownership of media tends to be associated with 'bad' social and political outcomes. See Besley T. and A. Prat (2001) for a study of the effect of media competition on government accountability
    • See Anderson, S. and S. Coate (2001) for a model of television competition in which increased availability of television channels can improve social welfare by reducing the cost of advertising. In a recent empirical paper, Djankov, S., et al. (2003) find that concentrated (as well as public) ownership of media tends to be associated with 'bad' social and political outcomes. See Besley T. and A. Prat (2001) for a study of the effect of media competition on government accountability.
    • (2001)
  • 19
    • 14244253840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, there is more spectrum available for simulcasting in the UK than in Italy, because the UK has only five analogue channels, while Italy's spectrum is clogged up by many more local channels
    • For example, there is more spectrum available for simulcasting in the UK than in Italy, because the UK has only five analogue channels, while Italy's spectrum is clogged up by many more local channels.
  • 20
    • 14244269276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levy J., et al. for an overview of the US market, Farrell J. and C. Shapiro (1992) on standard setting and adoption, Goolsbee A. and A. Petrin (2003) on the advent of satellite television, and Hazlett T. (2001) on the transition to digital television
    • See Levy J., et al. (2002) for an overview of the US market, Farrell J. and C. Shapiro (1992 on standard setting and adoption, Goolsbee A. and A. Petrin (2003) on the advent of satellite television, and Hazlett T. (2001) on the transition to digital television.
    • (2002)
  • 21
    • 14244267347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By adding information on the cost structure of platform operators, the model can be extended to allow for endogenous supply-side behaviour. This can he done by following the same methodology we have adopted to endogenize the cost of DTT STBs. See also our discussion of policy scenario 7 in Section 5. We also assume away network externalities. See Farrell J. and Shapiro C. (1992) and Auriol and Benaim (2000) on strategic adoption incentives with network externalities, absent in our model
    • By adding information on the cost structure of platform operators, the model can be extended to allow for endogenous supply-side behaviour. This can he done by following the same methodology we have adopted to endogenize the cost of DTT STBs. See also our discussion of policy scenario 7 in Section 5. We also assume away network externalities. See Farrell J. and C. Shapiro (1992) and Auriol and Benaim (2000) on strategic adoption incentives with network externalities, absent in our model.
  • 22
    • 14244250255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Over time, there is a marked increase in the number of available set-top boxes. As the market matures, two phenomena can be observed. First, many more products are sold at low prices. Second, more products with added features are introduced at the high end of the spectrum. Overall, the trend of the average price is robust to the introduction of new products
    • Over time, there is a marked increase in the number of available set-top boxes. As the market matures, two phenomena can be observed. First, many more products are sold at low prices. Second, more products with added features are introduced at the high end of the spectrum. Overall, the trend of the average price is robust to the introduction of new products.
  • 23
    • 14244258360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is implemented numerically by setting the expected switch-off date at a distant future period
    • This is implemented numerically by setting the expected switch-off date at a distant future period.
  • 24
    • 14244262003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These confidence bands have been computed by Monte Carlo simulations, draws 100 times the parameters for the consumer preferences from the distribution estimated from our survey data
    • These confidence bands have been computed by Monte Carlo simulations, draws 100 times the parameters for the consumer preferences from the distribution estimated from our survey data.
  • 25
    • 14244262635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, the UK pay satellite operator BSkyB has officially announced in June 2004 its intention of doing exactly so. According to the press, this move is a strategic response to the competitive pressure from Freeview
    • Indeed, the UK pay satellite operator BSkyB has officially announced in June 2004 its intention of doing exactly so. According to the press, this move is a strategic response to the competitive pressure from Freeview.
  • 26
    • 14244254743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The social value of the released spectrum is clearly different from its market value, due to the producer and consumer surplus created from the alternative use of the spectrum
    • The social value of the released spectrum is clearly different from its market value, due to the producer and consumer surplus created from the alternative use of the spectrum.
  • 27
    • 14244267348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The learning curve model originated in engineering studies of aircraft production, but has also been applied to other industries, such as chemical processing, energy and semiconductors. See Chapter 2 of Besanko D., et al. (2000) for an accessible introduction to the learning curve and additional references
    • The learning curve model originated in engineering studies of aircraft production, but has also been applied to other industries, such as chemical processing, energy and semiconductors. See Chapter 2 of Besanko D., et al. (2000) for an accessible introduction to the learning curve and additional references.
  • 28
    • 14244258135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More precisely, we are focusing on an equilibrium in which the share of DTT is constant, and so the DTT STBs do not vary in the post-switch phase
    • More precisely, we are focusing on an equilibrium in which the share of DTT is constant, and so the DTT STBs do not vary in the post-switch phase.
  • 29
    • 14244257534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We refer the reader to Adda and Cooper (2003) for a general exposition on how to solve dynamic discrete choice models by value function iteration and to Adda and Cooper (2000) for an application to policy evaluation
    • We refer the reader to Adda and Cooper (2003) for a general exposition on how to solve dynamic discrete choice models by value function iteration and to Adda and Cooper (2000) for an application to policy evaluation.
  • 30
    • 0033850785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Balladurette and Juppette: A discrete analysis of scrapping subsidies'
    • Adda, J. and R. Cooper (2000). 'Balladurette and Juppette: A discrete analysis of scrapping subsidies', Journal of Political Economy, 108(4), 778-806.
    • (2000) Journal of Political Economy , vol.108 , Issue.4 , pp. 778-806
    • Adda, J.1    Cooper, R.2
  • 32
    • 0003617110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Market provision of public goods: The case of broadcasting'
    • NBER Working Paper No. 7513
    • Anderson, S. and S. Coate (2001). 'Market provision of public goods: The case of broadcasting', NBER Working Paper No. 7513.
    • (2001)
    • Anderson, S.1    Coate, S.2
  • 34
    • 14244266665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Competition in two-sides markets'
    • mimeo, University College London
    • Armstrong, M. (2002). 'Competition in two-sides markets', mimeo, University College London.
    • (2002)
    • Armstrong, M.1
  • 35
    • 0040357389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Standardization in decentralized economies'
    • Auriol, E. and M. Benaim (2000). 'Standardization in decentralized economies', American Economic Review, 90(3), 550-70.
    • (2000) American Economic Review , vol.90 , Issue.3 , pp. 550-570
    • Auriol, E.1    Benaim, M.2
  • 37
    • 0037975090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability'
    • mimeo, LSE
    • Besley, T. and A. Prat (2001). 'Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability', mimeo, LSE.
    • (2001)
    • Besley, T.1    Prat, A.2
  • 38
    • 14244254742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Digital switching in broadcasting: A BIPE consulting study for the European Commission (Directorate General Information Society)'
    • BIPE
    • BIPE (2002). 'Digital switching in broadcasting: A BIPE consulting study for the European Commission (Directorate General Information Society)'.
    • (2002)
  • 39
    • 14244266232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Digital terrestrial television in France'
    • A. Brown and R. Picard (eds.), Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJ
    • Bourreau, M. (2004). 'Digital terrestrial television in France', in A. Brown and R. Picard (eds.), Digital Television. in Europe, Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJ.
    • (2004) Digital Television in Europe
    • Bourreau, M.1
  • 40
    • 0035098639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Sports rights and the broadcast industry'
    • Cave, M. and R. Crandall (2001). 'Sports rights and the broadcast industry', Economic Journal, 111(469), F4-26.
    • (2001) Economic Journal , vol.111 , Issue.469
    • Cave, M.1    Crandall, R.2
  • 41
    • 0003185196 scopus 로고
    • 'The Federal Communications Commission'
    • Coase, R. (1959). 'The Federal Communications Commission', Journal of law and Economics, 2, 1-40.
    • (1959) Journal of Law and Economics , vol.2 , pp. 1-40
    • Coase, R.1
  • 42
    • 0038559777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'eEurope 2005: An information society for all'
    • Commission of the European Communities COM (2002) 263 final
    • Commission of the European Communities (2002). 'eEurope 2005: An information society for all', COM (2002) 263 final.
    • (2002)
  • 43
    • 14244253613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, the European Economic and Social Committee of the Regions on the Transition from Analogue to Digital Broadcasting (from Digital "Switchover" to Analogue "Switch-off")'
    • Commission of the European Communities COM (2003) 541 final
    • Commission of the European Communities (2003a). 'Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, the European Economic and Social Committee of the Regions on the Transition from Analogue to Digital Broadcasting (from Digital "Switchover" to Analogue "Switch-off")', COM (2003) 541 final.
    • (2003)
  • 44
    • 14244266663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • '9th Report on the Implementation of the Telecommunications Regulatory Package. Annex 1: Market Overview'
    • Commission of the European Communities COM (2003) 715 final, SEC (2003) 1342
    • Commission of the European Communities (2003b). '9th Report on the Implementation of the Telecommunications Regulatory Package. Annex 1: Market Overview', COM (2003) 715 final, SEC (2003) 1342.
    • (2003)
  • 47
    • 0034356060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'The impact of the 1992 Cable Act on household demand and welfare'
    • Crawford, G. (2000). 'The impact of the 1992 Cable Act on household demand and welfare', RAND, Journal of Economics, 31(3), 422-49.
    • (2000) RAND Journal of Economics , vol.31 , Issue.3 , pp. 422-449
    • Crawford, G.1
  • 50
    • 0002642594 scopus 로고
    • 'Standardization, compatibility, and innovation'
    • Farrell, J. and G. Saloner (1985). 'Standardization, compatibility, and innovation', Rand Journal on Economics, 16(1), 70-83.
    • (1985) Rand Journal on Economics , vol.16 , Issue.1 , pp. 70-83
    • Farrell, J.1    Saloner, G.2
  • 53
    • 1642268919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'The consumer gains from direct broadcast satellite and the competition with cable TV'
    • Goolsbee, A. and A. Petrin (2004). 'The consumer gains from direct broadcast satellite and the competition with cable TV', Econometrica 72(2), 351-81.
    • (2004) Econometrica , vol.72 , Issue.2 , pp. 351-381
    • Goolsbee, A.1    Petrin, A.2
  • 55
    • 14244265471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Contracts and competition in the UK pay-TV market'
    • LBS Discussion Paper 01-5
    • Harbord, D. and M. Ottaviani (2001). 'Contracts and competition in the UK pay-TV market', LBS Discussion Paper 01-5.
    • (2001)
    • Harbord, D.1    Ottaviani, M.2
  • 56
    • 14244249348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'The U.S. Digital TV transition: Time to toss the Negroponte Switch'
    • Working Paper 01-15
    • Hazlett, T. (2001). 'The U.S. digital TV transition: Time to toss the Negroponte Switch', AEI-Brookings Joint Centre for Regulatory Studies Working Paper 01-15.
    • (2001) AEI-Brookings Joint Centre for Regulatory Studies
    • Hazlett, T.1
  • 57
    • 14244263269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Independent Television Commission and British Broadcasting Corporation
    • Independent Television Commission and British Broadcasting Corporation (2003). A Report on Progress Toward Digital Switchover.
    • (2003) A Report on Progress Toward Digital Switchover
  • 58
    • 20444464754 scopus 로고
    • 'Competition when consumers have switching costs: An overview with applications to industrial organization, macroeconomics, and international trade'
    • Klemperer, P.D. (1995). 'Competition when consumers have switching costs: an overview with applications to industrial organization, macroeconomics, and international trade', Review of Economic Studies 62(4), 515-39.
    • (1995) Review of Economic Studies , vol.62 , Issue.4 , pp. 515-539
    • Klemperer, P.D.1
  • 60
    • 12944253746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Broadcast television: Survivor in a sea of competition'
    • OPP Working Paper Series 37, Federal Communications Commission
    • Levy, J., M. Ford-Levy and A. Levine (2002). 'Broadcast television: survivor in a sea of competition', OPP Working Paper Series 37, Federal Communications Commission.
    • (2002)
    • Levy, J.1    Ford-Levy, M.2    Levine, A.3
  • 61
    • 0000184548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Economic choices'
    • McFadden, D. (2001). 'Economic choices', American Economic Review, 91(3), 351-78.
    • (2001) American Economic Review , vol.91 , Issue.3 , pp. 351-378
    • McFadden, D.1
  • 62
    • 0031430647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Concentration and public policies in the broadcasting industry: The future of television'
    • Motta, M. and M. Polo (1997). 'Concentration and public policies in the broadcasting industry: The future of television', Economic Policy, 25, 293-327.
    • (1997) Economic Policy , vol.25 , pp. 293-327
    • Motta, M.1    Polo, M.2
  • 64
    • 0141827216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Universal residential telephone service'
    • M. Cave (ed.), Elsevier Science, North Holland
    • Riordan, M. (2002). 'Universal residential telephone service', in M. Cave (ed.), Handbook of Telecommunications Economics, Elsevier Science, North Holland.
    • (2002) Handbook of Telecommunications Economics
    • Riordan, M.1
  • 67
    • 14244262849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Promoting efficient use of spectrum through elimination of barriers to the development of secondary markets: Comments of 37 concerned economists'
    • WT Docket No. 00-230, Federal Communications Commission
    • Rosston, G.L. and T.W. Hazlett (2001). 'Promoting efficient use of spectrum through elimination of barriers to the development of secondary markets: Comments of 37 concerned economists', WT Docket No. 00-230, Federal Communications Commission.
    • (2001)
    • Rosston, G.L.1    Hazlett, T.W.2
  • 68
    • 0034391920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Auctions for universal service subsidies'
    • Sorana, V (2000). 'Auctions for universal service subsidies', Journal of Regulatory Economics, 18(1), 33-58.
    • (2000) Journal of Regulatory Economics , vol.18 , Issue.1 , pp. 33-58
    • Sorana, V.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.