-
1
-
-
84925886269
-
Utility and Rights: Two Justifications for State Action Increasing Equality
-
Edwin Baker, "Utility and Rights: Two Justifications for State Action Increasing Equality," Yale Law Journal, vol. 84 (1974), p. 52.
-
(1974)
Yale Law Journal
, vol.84
, pp. 52
-
-
Baker, E.1
-
2
-
-
0346921951
-
-
Someone could say that redistributive taxation is a government's way of internalizing responsibility - it sees people from whom it takes as part of the same group as people to whom it gives. That is not how I use the term, but I do not want to quibble about definitions. Our task is to explore what makes people better off, not to explore what counts as internalization.
-
Someone could say that redistributive taxation is a government's way of internalizing responsibility - it sees people from whom it takes as part of the same group as people to whom it gives. That is not how I use the term, but I do not want to quibble about definitions. Our task is to explore what makes people better off, not to explore what counts as internalization.
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
0004048289
-
-
Cambridge: Harvard University Press
-
I borrow the phrase from John Rawls, A Theory of Justice (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1971), p. 4, but I do not claim to be interpreting the phrase in a Rawlsian way.
-
(1971)
A Theory of Justice
, pp. 4
-
-
Rawls, J.1
-
4
-
-
0347553038
-
-
My reference to the welfare of "the people around them" is not a throwaway line. Whether a person learns to be self-supporting or learns to expect free access to the fruits of other people's labor will affect the whole community
-
My reference to the welfare of "the people around them" is not a throwaway line. Whether a person learns to be self-supporting or learns to expect free access to the fruits of other people's labor will affect the whole community.
-
-
-
-
5
-
-
0346921940
-
-
Part of this thought is that even people who do need help (children, for example) get the help they need from their families, friends, and neighbors. That is part of the social structure and social process that we should try not to disrupt
-
Part of this thought is that even people who do need help (children, for example) get the help they need from their families, friends, and neighbors. That is part of the social structure and social process that we should try not to disrupt.
-
-
-
-
7
-
-
0001712266
-
How Income Transfer Programs Affect Work, Savings, and the Income Distribution: A Critical Review
-
Sheldon Danzinger, Robert Haveman, and Robert Plotnick, "How Income Transfer Programs Affect Work, Savings, and the Income Distribution: A Critical Review," Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 19 (1981), p. 1020.
-
(1981)
Journal of Economic Literature
, vol.19
, pp. 1020
-
-
Danzinger, S.1
Haveman, R.2
Plotnick, R.3
-
8
-
-
0004158659
-
-
Princeton: Princeton University Press
-
Robert E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1988), p. 233.
-
(1988)
Reasons for Welfare
, pp. 233
-
-
Goodin, R.E.1
-
9
-
-
0348182559
-
The Work vs. Welfare Trade-Off
-
Why do they drop out? There is no simple explanation, but part of the explanation is that AFDC payments, together with food stamps and other benefits that go to AFDC recipients, add up to a pre-tax hourly wage equivalent of $14.76 in New York, $12.45 in Philadelphia, $11.35 in Baltimore, and $10.91 in Detroit. See Michael Tanner, Stephen Moore, and David Hartman, "The Work vs. Welfare Trade-Off," Policy Analysis, vol. 240 (1995), p. 27.
-
(1995)
Policy Analysis
, vol.240
, pp. 27
-
-
Tanner, M.1
Moore, S.2
Hartman, D.3
-
11
-
-
26344468039
-
-
Ibid., p. 196. This characterization will suffice for my purposes, but Goodin himself offers several others (pp. 124, 147). See also his discussion of when dependents are exploitable (pp. 175-76).
-
Reasons for Welfare
, pp. 196
-
-
-
12
-
-
0346291858
-
-
Ibid., p. 19
-
Ibid., p. 19.
-
-
-
-
13
-
-
0347553033
-
-
Ibid., p. 165n
-
Ibid., p. 165n.
-
-
-
-
14
-
-
0348182557
-
-
Ibid., p. 177
-
Ibid., p. 177.
-
-
-
-
15
-
-
0346291876
-
-
Ibid., p. 221ff
-
Ibid., p. 221ff.
-
-
-
-
16
-
-
0346921945
-
-
Ibid., p. 223
-
Ibid., p. 223.
-
-
-
-
17
-
-
0003553554
-
-
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
-
Artur Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution 1975), p. 99. Presumably, one of the dials Okun had in mind was the tax rate. When contemplating tax hikes, even people who know better routinely make budget projections on the assumption that raising tax rates by 20 percent will raise tax revenues by 20 percent as well. But twisting the revenue dial is not so easy. While some people deny that tax rates affect investment decisions, others question whether raising tax rates has much effect on government revenues. W. Kurt Hauser, "The Tax and Revenue Equation," Wall Street Journal, March 25, 1993, says that between 1949 and 1993, top marginal personal income tax rates were as high as 92 percent and as low as 28 percent, but federal tax receipts never went higher than 21.5 percent of gross domestic product (in 1981, when the top tax rate was 50 percent) and never went lower than 17.9 percent of GDP (in 1964 and 1965, when the top tax rate was 77 percent).
-
(1975)
Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff
, pp. 99
-
-
Okun, A.1
-
18
-
-
0348182572
-
The Tax and Revenue Equation
-
March 25
-
Artur Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution 1975), p. 99. Presumably, one of the dials Okun had in mind was the tax rate. When contemplating tax hikes, even people who know better routinely make budget projections on the assumption that raising tax rates by 20 percent will raise tax revenues by 20 percent as well. But twisting the revenue dial is not so easy. While some people deny that tax rates affect investment decisions, others question whether raising tax rates has much effect on government revenues. W. Kurt Hauser, "The Tax and Revenue Equation," Wall Street Journal, March 25, 1993, says that between 1949 and 1993, top marginal personal income tax rates were as high as 92 percent and as low as 28 percent, but federal tax receipts never went higher than 21.5 percent of gross domestic product (in 1981, when the top tax rate was 50 percent) and never went lower than 17.9 percent of GDP (in 1964 and 1965, when the top tax rate was 77 percent).
-
(1993)
Wall Street Journal
-
-
Kurt Hauser, W.1
-
21
-
-
0346921946
-
-
Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, April
-
For those concerned about rich people exploiting poor people, though, one obvious remedy would be to eliminate a program like Social Security. Retired people in the United States today are, as a group, far wealthier than young workers, yet the pay-as-you-go system employed in the United States transferred $334 billion from the latter to the former in 1995 alone, amounting to 22 percent of the entire federal budget. The cost of the system as currently constituted is projected to increase to $566 billion (in constant dollars) by the year 2005, according to the Congressional Budget Office, Baseline Projections for Mandatory Spending (Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, April 1995).
-
(1995)
Baseline Projections for Mandatory Spending
-
-
-
22
-
-
0346291867
-
-
Supporting oneself is not to be equated with living like Robinson Crusoe. What people mean when they speak of supporting oneself is living on one's earnings, however cooperative and interdependent the enterprises may be from which those earnings derive
-
Supporting oneself is not to be equated with living like Robinson Crusoe. What people mean when they speak of supporting oneself is living on one's earnings, however cooperative and interdependent the enterprises may be from which those earnings derive.
-
-
-
-
24
-
-
0346921926
-
-
I thank Dan Russell for discussions of this point
-
I thank Dan Russell for discussions of this point.
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
0031401007
-
The 'Lodge Practice Evil' Reconsidered: Medical Care through Fraternal Societies, 1900-1930
-
July
-
David T. Beito, "The 'Lodge Practice Evil' Reconsidered: Medical Care through Fraternal Societies, 1900-1930," Journal of Urban History, vol. 23 (July 1997).
-
(1997)
Journal of Urban History
, vol.23
-
-
Beito, D.T.1
-
32
-
-
0003858824
-
-
Voluntary hospitals provided free care. Provident dispensaries charged nominal tees. "[T]he provident dispensaries aimed to enable the poor to make as much of a contribution as they could afford to the cost of their health care. It was felt that the beneficiaries would feel greater self-respect if they were able to pay at least something towards their own health care. They therefore paid a low annual contribution, felt to be within the means of the very poor, and the balance was supplied by the honourary members." See Green, Reinventing Civil Society, p. 73.
-
Reinventing Civil Society
, pp. 73
-
-
Green1
-
33
-
-
0003467373
-
-
New York: Alfred A. Knopf, ch. 4
-
England's Poor Law Amendment Act of 1834 sought to limit access to (and desirability of) government poor relief, so as to ensure that it would indeed be treated as a last resort. The general idea was that the standard of living made possible by public assistance ought to be less desirable than that available to the humblest of self-supporting laborers. See Gertrude Himmelfarb, The De-Moralization of Society (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1994), ch. 4.
-
(1994)
The De-Moralization of Society
-
-
Himmelfarb, G.1
-
36
-
-
0003858824
-
-
A Royal Commission assigned to investigate whether the poor were systematically deterred from joining friendly societies found that, in 1901-1902, "registered friendly society membership was highest in rural areas where wages were lowest" (Green, Reinventing Civil Society, p. 68).
-
Reinventing Civil Society
, pp. 68
-
-
Green1
-
39
-
-
0346291861
-
-
Given the lack of modern actuarial and accounting techniques, it is easy to imagine how nineteenth century friendly societies could have run into finanancial difficulties. Yet none of them, to my knowledge, ever appealed to financial hardship as a reason for refusing to provide promised benefits
-
Given the lack of modern actuarial and accounting techniques, it is easy to imagine how nineteenth century friendly societies could have run into finanancial difficulties. Yet none of them, to my knowledge, ever appealed to financial hardship as a reason for refusing to provide promised benefits.
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
0347553029
-
-
As recently as the 1960s, though, the Taborian Hospital of Mound Bayou, Mississippi, provided basic medical coverage for as little as $30 per year, according to David T. Beito, "Our Temple of Health: Black Fraternal Hospitals in the Mississippi Delta, 1942-1967," paper presented to the American Historical Association, January 1996
-
As recently as the 1960s, though, the Taborian Hospital of Mound Bayou, Mississippi, provided basic medical coverage for as little as $30 per year, according to David T. Beito, "Our Temple of Health: Black Fraternal Hospitals in the Mississippi Delta, 1942-1967," paper presented to the American Historical Association, January 1996.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
0346291852
-
The Private Provision of Unemployment Insurance
-
Private unemployment insurance was once available in Michigan, and insurance companies spent decades fighting against laws prohibiting wider selling of unemployment policies. See Michael B. Rappaport, "The Private Provision of Unemployment Insurance," Wisconsin Law Review, vol. 61 (1992), pp. 61-129.
-
(1992)
Wisconsin Law Review
, vol.61
, pp. 61-129
-
-
Rappaport, M.B.1
-
42
-
-
0347553044
-
-
note
-
Lawrence Mead, in conversation, acknowledges that friendly societies were once effective providers of health care to the poor, but questions whether welfare recipients today have the competence to do for themselves what poor people did a century ago. If Mead is right, then we are left with a question of how to instill competence. One might begin by observing that we acquire competence in any particular activity through practice. We are not born with it. One of the ways in which our social environment contributes to our developing competence is by making it clear that we are expected to become competent. An environment that does not present us with such expectations is likely to hold us back.
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
33947542912
-
Property in Land
-
esp. p. 1342ff.
-
There is some evidence, though, that the advantages of communal management as a form of collective responsibility tend to decrease as an economy matures. See Robert C. Ellickson, "Property in Land," Yale Law Journal, vol. 102 (1993), pp. 1315-1400, esp. p. 1342ff. See also my chapter on property rights in Schmidtz and Goodin, Social Welfare as an Individual Responsibility: For and Against.
-
(1993)
Yale Law Journal
, vol.102
, pp. 1315-1400
-
-
Ellickson, R.C.1
-
44
-
-
0003877327
-
-
There is some evidence, though, that the advantages of communal management as a form of collective responsibility tend to decrease as an economy matures. See Robert C. Ellickson, "Property in Land," Yale Law Journal, vol. 102 (1993), pp. 1315-1400, esp. p. 1342ff. See also my chapter on property rights in Schmidtz and Goodin, Social Welfare as an Individual Responsibility: For and Against.
-
Social Welfare as an Individual Responsibility: For and Against
-
-
Schmidtz1
Goodin2
-
45
-
-
0346921936
-
-
In conversation
-
In conversation.
-
-
-
-
46
-
-
0346921938
-
-
I thank James Buchanan for this point
-
I thank James Buchanan for this point.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
0346291862
-
-
The proposal is not to appeal exclusively to self-interest so much as to appeal to interests that people actually have. There is also sometimes a place for appealing to latent interests (in their community, say) that people could have reason to develop and pursue under the right conditions
-
The proposal is not to appeal exclusively to self-interest so much as to appeal to interests that people actually have. There is also sometimes a place for appealing to latent interests (in their community, say) that people could have reason to develop and pursue under the right conditions.
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
0346921925
-
-
Alan Wolfe suggests (in conversation) that we could distinguish between positive and negative guarantees. An adequately enforced system of property rights, for example, provides a negative guarantee to the extent that it secures people against interference with their productive efforts. Positive guarantees secure access to the fruits of other people's productive efforts. Negative guarantees help make for a peaceful and productive society; positive guarantees help make for the opposite
-
Alan Wolfe suggests (in conversation) that we could distinguish between positive and negative guarantees. An adequately enforced system of property rights, for example, provides a negative guarantee to the extent that it secures people against interference with their productive efforts. Positive guarantees secure access to the fruits of other people's productive efforts. Negative guarantees help make for a peaceful and productive society; positive guarantees help make for the opposite.
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
0347553036
-
-
A similar theme is suggested by Howard Husock in "Standards versus Struggle: The Failure of Public Housing and the Welfare-State Impulse," elsewhere in this volume
-
A similar theme is suggested by Howard Husock in "Standards versus Struggle: The Failure of Public Housing and the Welfare-State Impulse," elsewhere in this volume.
-
-
-
-
51
-
-
0346291866
-
Wage Wars
-
April 22
-
Short-run trends are harder to discern, of course. It is often claimed that wages for the poor and middle classes have stagnated since 1980, but data for the United States do not support this claim: The Census Bureau keeps statistics separately for "families" and "unrelated individuals." Census Bureau figures show that between 1980 and 1989, real income for the middle quintile of families increased by 8.3 per cent, while real income for the middle quintile of unrelated individuals increased by 16.3 per cent. The CBO [Congressional Budget Office] manipulated this Census Bureau data by combining "families" and "unrelated individuals" into the single category of "families." Since demographic trends produced more rapid growth in the number of unrelated individuals in the 1980's, and since families headed by two adults on average have far higher incomes than unrelated individuals, combining these groups into a single category of "families" greatly depressed average "family" incomes. Thus, even though the incomes of middle-quintile families increased at the rate of 8.3 per cent and the incomes of middle-quintile individuals increased by 16.3 per cent, middle-quintile "families" in the CBO's new sense saw their total incomes decline by 0.8 per cent over the same period. (John H. Hinderaker and Scott W. Johnson, "Wage Wars," National Review, April 22, 1996, p. 35) Robert Samuelson suggests a further explanation for the misperception of statistical stagnation. "The notion that most people's incomes and living standards are stagnating is simply false. Not only is it contradicted by the outpouring of new consumer products and services. It is also contradicted by official statistics, which, once corrected for slight overstatement of inflation, show sizable gains. No one knows precisely the extent of the overstatement of inflation. A good guess is ten to twenty percent over the past two decades." Robert J. Samuelson, "Great Expectations," Newsweek, January 8, 1996, p. 32.
-
(1996)
National Review
, pp. 35
-
-
Hinderaker, J.H.1
Johnson, S.W.2
-
52
-
-
0346921931
-
Great Expectations
-
January 8
-
Short-run trends are harder to discern, of course. It is often claimed that wages for the poor and middle classes have stagnated since 1980, but data for the United States do not support this claim: The Census Bureau keeps statistics separately for "families" and "unrelated individuals." Census Bureau figures show that between 1980 and 1989, real income for the middle quintile of families increased by 8.3 per cent, while real income for the middle quintile of unrelated individuals increased by 16.3 per cent. The CBO [Congressional Budget Office] manipulated this Census Bureau data by combining "families" and "unrelated individuals" into the single category of "families." Since demographic trends produced more rapid growth in the number of unrelated individuals in the 1980's, and since families headed by two adults on average have far higher incomes than unrelated individuals, combining these groups into a single category of "families" greatly depressed average "family" incomes. Thus, even though the incomes of middle-quintile families increased at the rate of 8.3 per cent and the incomes of middle-quintile individuals increased by 16.3 per cent, middle-quintile "families" in the CBO's new sense saw their total incomes decline by 0.8 per cent over the same period. (John H. Hinderaker and Scott W. Johnson, "Wage Wars," National Review, April 22, 1996, p. 35) Robert Samuelson suggests a further explanation for the misperception of statistical stagnation. "The notion that most people's incomes and living standards are stagnating is simply false. Not only is it contradicted by the outpouring of new consumer products and services. It is also contradicted by official statistics, which, once corrected for slight overstatement of inflation, show sizable gains. No one knows precisely the extent of the overstatement of inflation. A good guess is ten to twenty percent over the past two decades." Robert J. Samuelson, "Great Expectations," Newsweek, January 8, 1996, p. 32.
-
(1996)
Newsweek
, pp. 32
-
-
Samuelson, R.J.1
-
53
-
-
0003437941
-
-
New York: Oxford University Press
-
Thomas Nagel, Equality and Partiality (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991), p. 64.
-
(1991)
Equality and Partiality
, pp. 64
-
-
Nagel, T.1
-
54
-
-
0348182564
-
-
Boulder: Westview Press
-
Reported by D. Eric Schansberg, Poor Policy (Boulder: Westview Press, 1996), p. 8.
-
(1996)
Poor Policy
, pp. 8
-
-
Eric Schansberg, D.1
-
58
-
-
0348182554
-
Workers Take It on the Chin
-
January 22
-
About 9 percent of U. S. families earn under $11,000 in 1996 dollars. (These are Congressional Budget Office numbers, so a graduate student counts as a family, as per Hinderaker and Johnson; see note 49.) A household bringing in two graduate student salaries is still (just barely) in the bottom quintile. See Don L. Boroughs, "Workers Take It on the Chin," U.S. News and World Report, January 22, 1996, p. 50.
-
(1996)
U.S. News and World Report
, pp. 50
-
-
Boroughs, D.L.1
-
59
-
-
24844435926
-
Why We're Living Longer
-
August 28
-
Ann Hardie, "Why We're Living Longer," Atlanta Journal/Constitution, August 28, 1995, p. A3. Hardie does not list original sources, but Samuelson, "Great Expectations," p. 27, says that, according to the U.S. Census Bureau, average life expectancy increased from 65.9 years in 1945 to 75.7 years in 1994.
-
(1995)
Atlanta Journal/Constitution
-
-
Hardie, A.1
|