메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 93, Issue 3, 1999, Pages 641-707

The future as history: The prospects for global convergence in corporate governance and its implications

(1)  Coffee Jr , John C a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0042261097     PISSN: 00293571     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (834)

References (317)
  • 1
    • 0003846902 scopus 로고
    • See ADOLF A. BERLE & GARDINER C. MEANS, JR., THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932). For the first reconsiderations of this thesis, see Bernard S. Black, Shareholder Passivity Reexamined, 89 MICH. L. REV. 520 (1990); Alfred F. Conard, Beyond Managerialism: Investor Capitalism?, 22 U. MICH. J.L. REFORM 117 (1988).
    • (1932) The Modern Corporation and Private Property
    • Berle, A.A.1    Means G.C., Jr.2
  • 2
    • 0011536823 scopus 로고
    • Shareholder Passivity Reexamined
    • See ADOLF A. BERLE & GARDINER C. MEANS, JR., THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932). For the first reconsiderations of this thesis, see Bernard S. Black, Shareholder Passivity Reexamined, 89 MICH. L. REV. 520 (1990); Alfred F. Conard, Beyond Managerialism: Investor Capitalism?, 22 U. MICH. J.L. REFORM 117 (1988).
    • (1990) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 520
    • Black, B.S.1
  • 3
    • 0000647937 scopus 로고
    • Beyond Managerialism: Investor Capitalism?
    • See ADOLF A. BERLE & GARDINER C. MEANS, JR., THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932). For the first reconsiderations of this thesis, see Bernard S. Black, Shareholder Passivity Reexamined, 89 MICH. L. REV. 520 (1990); Alfred F. Conard, Beyond Managerialism: Investor Capitalism?, 22 U. MICH. J.L. REFORM 117 (1988).
    • (1988) U. Mich. J.L. Reform , vol.22 , pp. 117
    • Conard, A.F.1
  • 4
    • 0043079629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • June, visited March 3, 1999 (unpublished manuscript, available on the Web)
    • For the fullest discussion of this point and detailed evidence from the 27 principal corporate law jurisdictions, see Rafael La Porta et al., Corporate Ownership Around the World (June 1998) (visited March 3, 1999) 〈http://nberws.nber.org/papers/W6625〉 (unpublished manuscript, available on the Web). This study examines the ownership structure of the largest firms in 27 different countries, those with the 26 largest Gross National Products and Mexico. Compiling data on the 10 largest publicly traded nonfinancial companies in each country, the authors found that (i) slightly less than 40% qualified as widely held, (ii) 30% were family controlled, (iii) 18% were state controlled, and (iv) the balance fell into different categories not involving dispersed ownership. See id. It should be underscored that this study focused only on the very largest firms. Once the threshold is lowered, the extent of concentrated ownership becomes even clearer. Estimates differ, but the basic picture is the same across a variety of recent studies. Julian Franks and Colin Mayer found that 85% of large German firms had a shareholder with at least a 25% ownership interest. See Julian Franks & Colin Mayer, Ownership, Control and the Performance of German Corporations (April 1997) (unpublished manuscript prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School, on file with the author). Another recent study estimates that 64% of large German firms have a majority owner, while in France the corresponding figure is 59%. See Paul Windolf, The Governance Structure of Large French Corporations: A Comparative Perspective, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY 695, 714 (1998) [hereinafter CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY]. An even more recent study estimates that 75% of all German listed companies have a majority owner, while 23% had a blockholder group holding in excess of ninety percent of the firm's equity capital. See Tim Jenkinson & Alexander Ljungqvist, Hostile Stakes and the Role of Banks in German Corporate Governance, NBER Discussion Paper No. 1695, at 6 (1997); see also discussion infra note 13.
    • Corporate Ownership Around the World , vol.1998
    • La Porta, R.1
  • 5
    • 0041576795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • April (unpublished manuscript prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School, on file with the author)
    • For the fullest discussion of this point and detailed evidence from the 27 principal corporate law jurisdictions, see Rafael La Porta et al., Corporate Ownership Around the World (June 1998) (visited March 3, 1999) 〈http://nberws.nber.org/papers/W6625〉 (unpublished manuscript, available on the Web). This study examines the ownership structure of the largest firms in 27 different countries, those with the 26 largest Gross National Products and Mexico. Compiling data on the 10 largest publicly traded nonfinancial companies in each country, the authors found that (i) slightly less than 40% qualified as widely held, (ii) 30% were family controlled, (iii) 18% were state controlled, and (iv) the balance fell into different categories not involving dispersed ownership. See id. It should be underscored that this study focused only on the very largest firms. Once the threshold is lowered, the extent of concentrated ownership becomes even clearer. Estimates differ, but the basic picture is the same across a variety of recent studies. Julian Franks and Colin Mayer found that 85% of large German firms had a shareholder with at least a 25% ownership interest. See Julian Franks & Colin Mayer, Ownership, Control and the Performance of German Corporations (April 1997) (unpublished manuscript prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School, on file with the author). Another recent study estimates that 64% of large German firms have a majority owner, while in France the corresponding figure is 59%. See Paul Windolf, The Governance Structure of Large French Corporations: A Comparative Perspective, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY 695, 714 (1998) [hereinafter CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY]. An even more recent study estimates that 75% of all German listed companies have a majority owner, while 23% had a blockholder group holding in excess of ninety percent of the firm's equity capital. See Tim Jenkinson & Alexander Ljungqvist, Hostile Stakes and the Role of Banks in German Corporate Governance, NBER Discussion Paper No. 1695, at 6 (1997); see also discussion infra note 13.
    • (1997) Ownership, Control and the Performance of German Corporations
    • Franks, J.1    Mayer, C.2
  • 6
    • 84920456753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Governance Structure of Large French Corporations: A Comparative Perspective
    • hereinafter CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY
    • For the fullest discussion of this point and detailed evidence from the 27 principal corporate law jurisdictions, see Rafael La Porta et al., Corporate Ownership Around the World (June 1998) (visited March 3, 1999) 〈http://nberws.nber.org/papers/W6625〉 (unpublished manuscript, available on the Web). This study examines the ownership structure of the largest firms in 27 different countries, those with the 26 largest Gross National Products and Mexico. Compiling data on the 10 largest publicly traded nonfinancial companies in each country, the authors found that (i) slightly less than 40% qualified as widely held, (ii) 30% were family controlled, (iii) 18% were state controlled, and (iv) the balance fell into different categories not involving dispersed ownership. See id. It should be underscored that this study focused only on the very largest firms. Once the threshold is lowered, the extent of concentrated ownership becomes even clearer. Estimates differ, but the basic picture is the same across a variety of recent studies. Julian Franks and Colin Mayer found that 85% of large German firms had a shareholder with at least a 25% ownership interest. See Julian Franks & Colin Mayer, Ownership, Control and the Performance of German Corporations (April 1997) (unpublished manuscript prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School, on file with the author). Another recent study estimates that 64% of large German firms have a majority owner, while in France the corresponding figure is 59%. See Paul Windolf, The Governance Structure of Large French Corporations: A Comparative Perspective, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY 695, 714 (1998) [hereinafter CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY]. An even more recent study estimates that 75% of all German listed companies have a majority owner, while 23% had a blockholder group holding in excess of ninety percent of the firm's equity capital. See Tim Jenkinson & Alexander Ljungqvist, Hostile Stakes and the Role of Banks in German Corporate Governance, NBER Discussion Paper No. 1695, at 6 (1997); see also discussion infra note 13.
    • (1998) Corporate Governance Today , vol.695 , pp. 714
    • Windolf, P.1
  • 7
    • 0007709215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hostile Stakes and the Role of Banks in German Corporate Governance
    • discussion infra note 13
    • For the fullest discussion of this point and detailed evidence from the 27 principal corporate law jurisdictions, see Rafael La Porta et al., Corporate Ownership Around the World (June 1998) (visited March 3, 1999) 〈http://nberws.nber.org/papers/W6625〉 (unpublished manuscript, available on the Web). This study examines the ownership structure of the largest firms in 27 different countries, those with the 26 largest Gross National Products and Mexico. Compiling data on the 10 largest publicly traded nonfinancial companies in each country, the authors found that (i) slightly less than 40% qualified as widely held, (ii) 30% were family controlled, (iii) 18% were state controlled, and (iv) the balance fell into different categories not involving dispersed ownership. See id. It should be underscored that this study focused only on the very largest firms. Once the threshold is lowered, the extent of concentrated ownership becomes even clearer. Estimates differ, but the basic picture is the same across a variety of recent studies. Julian Franks and Colin Mayer found that 85% of large German firms had a shareholder with at least a 25% ownership interest. See Julian Franks & Colin Mayer, Ownership, Control and the Performance of German Corporations (April 1997) (unpublished manuscript prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School, on file with the author). Another recent study estimates that 64% of large German firms have a majority owner, while in France the corresponding figure is 59%. See Paul Windolf, The Governance Structure of Large French Corporations: A Comparative Perspective, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY 695, 714 (1998) [hereinafter CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY]. An even more recent study estimates that 75% of all German listed companies have a majority owner, while 23% had a blockholder group holding in excess of ninety percent of the firm's equity capital. See Tim Jenkinson & Alexander Ljungqvist, Hostile Stakes and the Role of Banks in German Corporate Governance, NBER Discussion Paper No. 1695, at 6 (1997); see also discussion infra note 13.
    • (1997) NBER Discussion Paper , vol.1695 , pp. 6
    • Jenkinson, T.1    Ljungqvist, A.2
  • 8
    • 0001310174 scopus 로고
    • Hail Britannia?: Institutional Investor Behavior under Limited Regulation
    • For recent commentary on the impact of ownership concentration on shareholder behavior, see, for example, Bernard S. Black & John C. Coffee, Jr., Hail Britannia?: Institutional Investor Behavior Under Limited Regulation, 92 MICH. L. REV. 1997 (1994); John C. Coffee, Jr., Liquidity Versus Control: The Institutional Investor As Corporate Monitor, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 1277 (1991); Ronald J. Gilson & Mark J. Roe, Understanding the Japanese Keiretsu: Overlaps Between Corporate Governance and Industrial Organization, 102 YALE L.J. 871 (1993); Mark J. Roe, Some Differences in Company Structure in Germany, Japan and the United States, 102 YALE L.J. 1927 (1993).
    • (1994) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1997
    • Black, B.S.1    Coffee J.C., Jr.2
  • 9
    • 84055220949 scopus 로고
    • Liquidity Versus Control: The Institutional Investor As Corporate Monitor
    • For recent commentary on the impact of ownership concentration on shareholder behavior, see, for example, Bernard S. Black & John C. Coffee, Jr., Hail Britannia?: Institutional Investor Behavior Under Limited Regulation, 92 MICH. L. REV. 1997 (1994); John C. Coffee, Jr., Liquidity Versus Control: The Institutional Investor As Corporate Monitor, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 1277 (1991); Ronald J. Gilson & Mark J. Roe, Understanding the Japanese Keiretsu: Overlaps Between Corporate Governance and Industrial Organization, 102 YALE L.J. 871 (1993); Mark J. Roe, Some Differences in Company Structure in Germany, Japan and the United States, 102 YALE L.J. 1927 (1993).
    • (1991) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 1277
    • Coffee J.C., Jr.1
  • 10
    • 84927116611 scopus 로고
    • Understanding the Japanese Keiretsu: Overlaps between Corporate Governance and Industrial Organization
    • For recent commentary on the impact of ownership concentration on shareholder behavior, see, for example, Bernard S. Black & John C. Coffee, Jr., Hail Britannia?: Institutional Investor Behavior Under Limited Regulation, 92 MICH. L. REV. 1997 (1994); John C. Coffee, Jr., Liquidity Versus Control: The Institutional Investor As Corporate Monitor, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 1277 (1991); Ronald J. Gilson & Mark J. Roe, Understanding the Japanese Keiretsu: Overlaps Between Corporate Governance and Industrial Organization, 102 YALE L.J. 871 (1993); Mark J. Roe, Some Differences in Company Structure in Germany, Japan and the United States, 102 YALE L.J. 1927 (1993).
    • (1993) Yale L.J. , vol.102 , pp. 871
    • Gilson, R.J.1    Roe, M.J.2
  • 11
    • 53349177200 scopus 로고
    • Some Differences in Company Structure in Germany, Japan and the United States
    • For recent commentary on the impact of ownership concentration on shareholder behavior, see, for example, Bernard S. Black & John C. Coffee, Jr., Hail Britannia?: Institutional Investor Behavior Under Limited Regulation, 92 MICH. L. REV. 1997 (1994); John C. Coffee, Jr., Liquidity Versus Control: The Institutional Investor As Corporate Monitor, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 1277 (1991); Ronald J. Gilson & Mark J. Roe, Understanding the Japanese Keiretsu: Overlaps Between Corporate Governance and Industrial Organization, 102 YALE L.J. 871 (1993); Mark J. Roe, Some Differences in Company Structure in Germany, Japan and the United States, 102 YALE L.J. 1927 (1993).
    • (1993) Yale L.J. , vol.102 , pp. 1927
    • Roe, M.J.1
  • 12
    • 0000948683 scopus 로고
    • The Rise of the Political Model of Corporate Governance and Corporate Control
    • Many of these efforts explicitly stressed that they were "political" theories. See John Pound, The Rise of the Political Model of Corporate Governance and Corporate Control, 68 N.Y.U. L. REV. 103 (1993); Mark J. Roe, A Political Theory of American Corporate Finance, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 10 (1991). Without question, Professor Roe's work has been the dominant influence in this field and has spurred a new generation of scholars to search for "political" issues and divisions in the area of financial institutional structure.
    • (1993) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 103
    • Pound, J.1
  • 13
    • 12444303962 scopus 로고
    • A Political Theory of American Corporate Finance
    • Many of these efforts explicitly stressed that they were "political" theories. See John Pound, The Rise of the Political Model of Corporate Governance and Corporate Control, 68 N.Y.U. L. REV. 103 (1993); Mark J. Roe, A Political Theory of American Corporate Finance, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 10 (1991). Without question, Professor Roe's work has been the dominant influence in this field and has spurred a new generation of scholars to search for "political" issues and divisions in the area of financial institutional structure.
    • (1991) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 10
    • Roe, M.J.1
  • 14
    • 0026916527 scopus 로고
    • Capital Disadvantage: America's Failing Capital Investment System
    • Sept-Oct.
    • Michael Porter has long been the leading advocate of this point of view. See Michael E. Porter, Capital Disadvantage: America's Failing Capital Investment System, HARV. BUS. REV., Sept-Oct. 1992, at 65.
    • (1992) Harv. Bus. Rev. , pp. 65
    • Porter, M.E.1
  • 15
    • 0002389078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring the Effectiveness of Different Corporate Governance Systems: Toward a More Scientific Approach
    • For the strongest recent statement of this view, see Jonathan R. Macey, Measuring the Effectiveness of Different Corporate Governance Systems: Toward a More Scientific Approach, 10 J. APPLIED CORP. FIN. 16 (1998) (arguing that prevalence of hostile takeovers in stock market centered systems ensures their long-run superiority over blockholder dominated systems); see also Ronald J. Gilson, Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency: When Do Institutions Matter?, 74 WASH. U. L.Q. 327 (1996) (comparing stock market centered versus bank centered systems of corporate governance and emphasizing roles of industrial organization and path dependency). For an earlier view that bank centered systems might have efficiency advantages, at least in connection with particular production systems, see Gilson & Roe, supra note 3.
    • (1998) J. Applied Corp. Fin. , vol.10 , pp. 16
    • Macey, J.R.1
  • 16
    • 0010625251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency: When Do Institutions Matter?
    • For the strongest recent statement of this view, see Jonathan R. Macey, Measuring the Effectiveness of Different Corporate Governance Systems: Toward a More Scientific Approach, 10 J. APPLIED CORP. FIN. 16 (1998) (arguing that prevalence of hostile takeovers in stock market centered systems ensures their long-run superiority over blockholder dominated systems); see also Ronald J. Gilson, Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency: When Do Institutions Matter?, 74 WASH. U. L.Q. 327 (1996) (comparing stock market centered versus bank centered systems of corporate governance and emphasizing roles of industrial organization and path dependency). For an earlier view that bank centered systems might have efficiency advantages, at least in connection with particular production systems, see Gilson & Roe, supra note 3.
    • (1996) Wash. U. L.Q. , vol.74 , pp. 327
    • Gilson, R.J.1
  • 17
    • 0043079624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 3
    • For the strongest recent statement of this view, see Jonathan R. Macey, Measuring the Effectiveness of Different Corporate Governance Systems: Toward a More Scientific Approach, 10 J. APPLIED CORP. FIN. 16 (1998) (arguing that prevalence of hostile takeovers in stock market centered systems ensures their long-run superiority over blockholder dominated systems); see also Ronald J. Gilson, Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency: When Do Institutions Matter?, 74 WASH. U. L.Q. 327 (1996) (comparing stock market centered versus bank centered systems of corporate governance and emphasizing roles of industrial organization and path dependency). For an earlier view that bank centered systems might have efficiency advantages, at least in connection with particular production systems, see Gilson & Roe, supra note 3.
    • Gilson1    Roe2
  • 18
    • 0001503097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Determinants of External Finance
    • See Rafael La Porta et al., Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 J. FIN. 1131 (1997); see also Asli Demirguc-Kunt & Vosislav Maksimovic, Law, Finance and Firm Growth, 53 J. FIN. 2107, 2134 (1998) (finding that firms in countries with active stock market and well-developed legal system were able to obtain greater funds to finance growth).
    • (1997) J. Fin. , vol.52 , pp. 1131
    • Porta, R.L.1
  • 19
    • 0038803366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law, Finance and Firm Growth
    • See Rafael La Porta et al., Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 J. FIN. 1131 (1997); see also Asli Demirguc-Kunt & Vosislav Maksimovic, Law, Finance and Firm Growth, 53 J. FIN. 2107, 2134 (1998) (finding that firms in countries with active stock market and well-developed legal system were able to obtain greater funds to finance growth).
    • (1998) J. Fin. , vol.53 , pp. 2107
    • Demirguc-Kunt, A.1    Maksimovic, V.2
  • 20
    • 0043079628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See La Porta et. al., supra note 7.
    • La Porta1
  • 21
    • 0042578927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1137
    • See id. at 1137.
  • 22
    • 0041576796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 23
    • 0001026456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • This is the explanation given by La Porta et al., supra note 7; see also Andrei Schleifer & Robert W. Vishny, A Survey of Corporate Governance, 52 J. FIN. 737 (1997). In addition, it is, of course, possible that first mover advantages could account for the relative size of stock markets and publicly traded equity, but in this respect it is noteworthy that some European stock exchanges are older than either the London or New York exchanges (Amsterdam is generally recognized as the oldest stock exchange).
    • La Porta1
  • 24
    • 0001026456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Survey of Corporate Governance
    • This is the explanation given by La Porta et al., supra note 7; see also Andrei Schleifer & Robert W. Vishny, A Survey of Corporate Governance, 52 J. FIN. 737 (1997). In addition, it is, of course, possible that first mover advantages could account for the relative size of stock markets and publicly traded equity, but in this respect it is noteworthy that some European stock exchanges are older than either the London or New York exchanges (Amsterdam is generally recognized as the oldest stock exchange).
    • (1997) J. Fin. , vol.52 , pp. 737
    • Schleifer, A.1    Vishny, R.W.2
  • 25
    • 0042578926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While some investors may be willing to buy at greatly discounted prices, the preference of the entrepreneurs running the firm will be logically to organize blockholder structures that thereby maximize the prices they receive for their shares. In short, voting control is the only substitute for legal protections that enables the firm's founders to maximize the value of the shares they wish to sell.
  • 26
    • 0010687668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • submitted to the European Commission on October 27, hereinafter ECGN SURVEY
    • A good sense of the high level of concentration of corporate ownership in European economies is provided by a recent detailed survey by the European Corporate Governance Network. See EUROPEAN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE NETWORK, THE SEPARATION OF OWNERSHIP AND CONTROL: A SURVEY OF SEVEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (submitted to the European Commission on October 27, 1997) [hereinafter ECGN SURVEY]. For example, in Austria, a survey of the 600 largest firms found that the "average fractional ownership of the largest shareholder . . . is over 80%." Klaus Gugler et al., The Separation of Ownership and Control: An Austrian Perspective, in ECGN SURVEY 1. For a world-wide survey that concludes that family controlled firms remain the dominant pattern worldwide (with state controlled firms being the second most observed pattern), see La Porta et al., supra note 2. Other recent studies are discussed supra note 2. The following table, taken from a recent Dutch study, reveals the fundamental differences in share ownership patterns between those Continental European countries characterized by concentrated ownership, here, Germany and the Netherlands, and the Anglo-American market centered systems: Share Ownership (%) Germany NL UK US -households 16.6 20.0 17.7 50.2 -non financial enterprises 38.8 9.6 3.1 14.1 -banks 14.2 0.7 0.6 0.0 -investment funds 7.6 1.5 9.7 5.7 -pension funds 1.9 7.9 34.2 20.1 -insurance companies 5.2 5.5 17.2 4.6 -government 3.4 0.0 1.3 0.0 -foreign shareholders 12.2 54.8 16.3 5.4 Ownership of largest shareholder greater than 25% 85 - 13 - greater than 50% 57 22 6 - See William Bratton & Joseph McCahery, Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm: The Case Against Global Cross Reference (working paper January 1999) (citing CPB NETHERLANDS, BUREAU FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS, CHALLENGING NEIGHBOURS, RETHINKING GERMAN AND DUTCH INSTITUTIONS 357 (1997) (table 10.3) (copy on file with the author)).
    • (1997) The Separation of Ownership and Control: A Survey of Seven European Countries
  • 27
    • 0042077852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Separation of Ownership and Control: An Austrian Perspective
    • A good sense of the high level of concentration of corporate ownership in European economies is provided by a recent detailed survey by the European Corporate Governance Network. See EUROPEAN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE NETWORK, THE SEPARATION OF OWNERSHIP AND CONTROL: A SURVEY OF SEVEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (submitted to the European Commission on October 27, 1997) [hereinafter ECGN SURVEY]. For example, in Austria, a survey of the 600 largest firms found that the "average fractional ownership of the largest shareholder . . . is over 80%." Klaus Gugler et al., The Separation of Ownership and Control: An Austrian Perspective, in ECGN SURVEY 1. For a world-wide survey that concludes that family controlled firms remain the dominant pattern worldwide (with state controlled firms being the second most observed pattern), see La Porta et al., supra note 2. Other recent studies are discussed supra note 2. The following table, taken from a recent Dutch study, reveals the fundamental differences in share ownership patterns between those Continental European countries characterized by concentrated ownership, here, Germany and the Netherlands, and the Anglo-American market centered systems: Share Ownership (%) Germany NL UK US -households 16.6 20.0 17.7 50.2 -non financial enterprises 38.8 9.6 3.1 14.1 -banks 14.2 0.7 0.6 0.0 -investment funds 7.6 1.5 9.7 5.7 -pension funds 1.9 7.9 34.2 20.1 -insurance companies 5.2 5.5 17.2 4.6 -government 3.4 0.0 1.3 0.0 -foreign shareholders 12.2 54.8 16.3 5.4 Ownership of largest shareholder greater than 25% 85 - 13 - greater than 50% 57 22 6 - See William Bratton & Joseph McCahery, Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm: The Case Against Global Cross Reference (working paper January 1999) (citing CPB NETHERLANDS, BUREAU FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS, CHALLENGING NEIGHBOURS, RETHINKING GERMAN AND DUTCH INSTITUTIONS 357 (1997) (table 10.3) (copy on file with the author)).
    • ECGN Survey , vol.1
    • Gugler, K.1
  • 28
    • 0042578925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2
    • A good sense of the high level of concentration of corporate ownership in European economies is provided by a recent detailed survey by the European Corporate Governance Network. See EUROPEAN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE NETWORK, THE SEPARATION OF OWNERSHIP AND CONTROL: A SURVEY OF SEVEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (submitted to the European Commission on October 27, 1997) [hereinafter ECGN SURVEY]. For example, in Austria, a survey of the 600 largest firms found that the "average fractional ownership of the largest shareholder . . . is over 80%." Klaus Gugler et al., The Separation of Ownership and Control: An Austrian Perspective, in ECGN SURVEY 1. For a world-wide survey that concludes that family controlled firms remain the dominant pattern worldwide (with state controlled firms being the second most observed pattern), see La Porta et al., supra note 2. Other recent studies are discussed supra note 2. The following table, taken from a recent Dutch study, reveals the fundamental differences in share ownership patterns between those Continental European countries characterized by concentrated ownership, here, Germany and the Netherlands, and the Anglo-American market centered systems: Share Ownership (%) Germany NL UK US -households 16.6 20.0 17.7 50.2 -non financial enterprises 38.8 9.6 3.1 14.1 -banks 14.2 0.7 0.6 0.0 -investment funds 7.6 1.5 9.7 5.7 -pension funds 1.9 7.9 34.2 20.1 -insurance companies 5.2 5.5 17.2 4.6 -government 3.4 0.0 1.3 0.0 -foreign shareholders 12.2 54.8 16.3 5.4 Ownership of largest shareholder greater than 25% 85 - 13 - greater than 50% 57 22 6 - See William Bratton & Joseph McCahery, Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm: The Case Against Global Cross Reference (working paper January 1999) (citing CPB NETHERLANDS, BUREAU FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS, CHALLENGING NEIGHBOURS, RETHINKING GERMAN AND DUTCH INSTITUTIONS 357 (1997) (table 10.3) (copy on file with the author)).
    • La Porta1
  • 29
    • 0041576786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • working paper January
    • A good sense of the high level of concentration of corporate ownership in European economies is provided by a recent detailed survey by the European Corporate Governance Network. See EUROPEAN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE NETWORK, THE SEPARATION OF OWNERSHIP AND CONTROL: A SURVEY OF SEVEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (submitted to the European Commission on October 27, 1997) [hereinafter ECGN SURVEY]. For example, in Austria, a survey of the 600 largest firms found that the "average fractional ownership of the largest shareholder . . . is over 80%." Klaus Gugler et al., The Separation of Ownership and Control: An Austrian Perspective, in ECGN SURVEY 1. For a world-wide survey that concludes that family controlled firms remain the dominant pattern worldwide (with state controlled firms being the second most observed pattern), see La Porta et al., supra note 2. Other recent studies are discussed supra note 2. The following table, taken from a recent Dutch study, reveals the fundamental differences in share ownership patterns between those Continental European countries characterized by concentrated ownership, here, Germany and the Netherlands, and the Anglo-American market centered systems: Share Ownership (%) Germany NL UK US -households 16.6 20.0 17.7 50.2 -non financial enterprises 38.8 9.6 3.1 14.1 -banks 14.2 0.7 0.6 0.0 -investment funds 7.6 1.5 9.7 5.7 -pension funds 1.9 7.9 34.2 20.1 -insurance companies 5.2 5.5 17.2 4.6 -government 3.4 0.0 1.3 0.0 -foreign shareholders 12.2 54.8 16.3 5.4 Ownership of largest shareholder greater than 25% 85 - 13 - greater than 50% 57 22 6 - See William Bratton & Joseph McCahery, Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm: The Case Against Global Cross Reference (working paper January 1999) (citing CPB NETHERLANDS, BUREAU FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS, CHALLENGING NEIGHBOURS, RETHINKING GERMAN AND DUTCH INSTITUTIONS 357 (1997) (table 10.3) (copy on file with the author)).
    • (1999) Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm: The Case Against Global Cross Reference
    • Bratton, W.1    McCahery, J.2
  • 30
    • 0003673536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BUREAU FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS, table 10.3 (copy on file with the author)
    • A good sense of the high level of concentration of corporate ownership in European economies is provided by a recent detailed survey by the European Corporate Governance Network. See EUROPEAN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE NETWORK, THE SEPARATION OF OWNERSHIP AND CONTROL: A SURVEY OF SEVEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (submitted to the European Commission on October 27, 1997) [hereinafter ECGN SURVEY]. For example, in Austria, a survey of the 600 largest firms found that the "average fractional ownership of the largest shareholder . . . is over 80%." Klaus Gugler et al., The Separation of Ownership and Control: An Austrian Perspective, in ECGN SURVEY 1. For a world-wide survey that concludes that family controlled firms remain the dominant pattern worldwide (with state controlled firms being the second most observed pattern), see La Porta et al., supra note 2. Other recent studies are discussed supra note 2. The following table, taken from a recent Dutch study, reveals the fundamental differences in share ownership patterns between those Continental European countries characterized by concentrated ownership, here, Germany and the Netherlands, and the Anglo-American market centered systems: Share Ownership (%) Germany NL UK US -households 16.6 20.0 17.7 50.2 -non financial enterprises 38.8 9.6 3.1 14.1 -banks 14.2 0.7 0.6 0.0 -investment funds 7.6 1.5 9.7 5.7 -pension funds 1.9 7.9 34.2 20.1 -insurance companies 5.2 5.5 17.2 4.6 -government 3.4 0.0 1.3 0.0 -foreign shareholders 12.2 54.8 16.3 5.4 Ownership of largest shareholder greater than 25% 85 - 13 - greater than 50% 57 22 6 - See William Bratton & Joseph McCahery, Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm: The Case Against Global Cross Reference (working paper January 1999) (citing CPB NETHERLANDS, BUREAU FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS, CHALLENGING NEIGHBOURS, RETHINKING GERMAN AND DUTCH INSTITUTIONS 357 (1997) (table 10.3) (copy on file with the author)).
    • (1997) Challenging Neighbours, Rethinking German and Dutch Institutions , pp. 357
  • 31
    • 0041576792 scopus 로고
    • Is it Time for a Federal Corporation Law?
    • It is impossible to list all the scholars who have made or examined this claim in the 1990s. But for the earliest prediction of corporate convergence on an international scale that I have found in this decade, see Roberta S. Karmel, Is it Time for a Federal Corporation Law?, 57 BROOK. L. REV. 55, 90 (1991).
    • (1991) Brook. L. Rev. , vol.57 , pp. 55
    • Karmel, R.S.1
  • 32
    • 0001763518 scopus 로고
    • The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm
    • This theme that efficiency considerations shape corporate structures has a long history. See generally Harold Demsetz, The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm, 26 J.L. & ECON. 375 (1983); FRANK EASTERBROOK & DANIEL FISCHEL, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF CORPORATE LAW 212-18 (1991).
    • (1983) J.L. & Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 375
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 33
    • 0004126557 scopus 로고
    • This theme that efficiency considerations shape corporate structures has a long history. See generally Harold Demsetz, The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm, 26 J.L. & ECON. 375 (1983); FRANK EASTERBROOK & DANIEL FISCHEL, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF CORPORATE LAW 212-18 (1991).
    • (1991) The Economic Structure of Corporate Law , pp. 212-218
    • Easterbrook, F.1    Fischel, D.2
  • 34
    • 0042077822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nov. 19, unpublished manuscript, prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School
    • See Henry Hansmann & Reiner Kraakman, The End of History for Corporate Law (Nov. 19, 1997) (unpublished manuscript, prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School).
    • (1997) The End of History for Corporate Law
    • Hansmann, H.1    Kraakman, R.2
  • 35
    • 84925041689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics
    • See Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996) (arguing that conditions existing at the time when an institution is formed will influence its functioning far into the future, without respect to efficiency considerations).
    • (1996) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.109 , pp. 641
    • Roe, M.J.1
  • 36
    • 13444289177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Governance and Ownership
    • See Lucian A. Bebchuk & Mark J. Roe, A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Governance and Ownership (forthcoming in Stanford Law Review).
    • Stanford Law Review
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1    Roe, M.J.2
  • 37
    • 0347038982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property Rights in Firms
    • See Curtis J. Milhaupt, Property Rights in Firms, 84 VA. L. REV. 1145 (1998).
    • (1998) Va. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1145
    • Milhaupt, C.J.1
  • 38
    • 0042077729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 3
    • See Coffee, supra note 3, at 1281 (arguing that institutional investors' preference for liquidity explains in part their failure to hold concentrated blocks); see also Amar Bhide, The Hidden Costs of Stock Market Liquidity, 34 J. FIN. ECON. 31 (1993) (same); Thomas A. Smith, Institutions and Entrepreneurs in American Corporate Finance, 85 CAL. L. REV. 1 (1997) (same).
    • Coffee1
  • 39
    • 0000375782 scopus 로고
    • The Hidden Costs of Stock Market Liquidity
    • same
    • See Coffee, supra note 3, at 1281 (arguing that institutional investors' preference for liquidity explains in part their failure to hold concentrated blocks); see also Amar Bhide, The Hidden Costs of Stock Market Liquidity, 34 J. FIN. ECON. 31 (1993) (same); Thomas A. Smith, Institutions and Entrepreneurs in American Corporate Finance, 85 CAL. L. REV. 1 (1997) (same).
    • (1993) J. Fin. Econ. , vol.34 , pp. 31
    • Bhide, A.1
  • 40
    • 0042042031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions and Entrepreneurs in American Corporate Finance
    • same
    • See Coffee, supra note 3, at 1281 (arguing that institutional investors' preference for liquidity explains in part their failure to hold concentrated blocks); see also Amar Bhide, The Hidden Costs of Stock Market Liquidity, 34 J. FIN. ECON. 31 (1993) (same); Thomas A. Smith, Institutions and Entrepreneurs in American Corporate Finance, 85 CAL. L. REV. 1 (1997) (same).
    • (1997) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 1
    • Smith, T.A.1
  • 41
    • 0041576647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See La Porta et al., supra note 7, at 1132; see also La Porta et al., supra note 2.
    • La Porta1
  • 42
    • 0041576644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2
    • See La Porta et al., supra note 7, at 1132; see also La Porta et al., supra note 2.
    • La Porta1
  • 43
    • 0043079625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See La Porta et al., supra note 7, at 1132.
    • La Porta1
  • 45
    • 0042077725 scopus 로고
    • Subordination of American Capitol
    • Sept.-Oct.
    • See MARK J. ROE, STRONG MANAGERS, WEAK OWNERS: THE POLITICAL ROOTS OF AMERICAN CORPORATE FINANCE (1994); see also Joseph A. Grundfest, Subordination of American Capitol, HARV. Bus. REV., Sept.-Oct. 1992, at 65.
    • (1992) Harv. Bus. Rev. , pp. 65
    • Grundfest, J.A.1
  • 46
    • 0042578819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 3
    • Note that an underlying assumption here is that ownership dispersion is the "natural" state for investors in recognition of their preferences for liquidity and diversification. This is consistent with the view taken in Coffee, supra note 3, at 1281.
    • Coffee1
  • 47
    • 0346613552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra notes 39-56 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 39-56 and accompanying text. In turn, enhanced liquidity is believed to facilitate investment in longer-run, higher return projects, such as high technology start-ups, that may spur greater economic growth and productivity. See Ross Levine & Sara Zervos, Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth, 88 AMER. ECON. REV. 537 (1998) (citing Valerie R. Bencivenga et al., Transaction Costs, Technological Choice, and Endogenous Growth, 67 J. ECO. THEORY 53 (1995) and Maurice Obstfeld, Risk-Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth, 84 AMER. ECON. REV. 1310 (1994)).
  • 48
    • 0346613552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth
    • See infra notes 39-56 and accompanying text. In turn, enhanced liquidity is believed to facilitate investment in longer-run, higher return projects, such as high technology start-ups, that may spur greater economic growth and productivity. See Ross Levine & Sara Zervos, Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth, 88 AMER. ECON. REV. 537 (1998) (citing Valerie R. Bencivenga et al., Transaction Costs, Technological Choice, and Endogenous Growth, 67 J. ECO. THEORY 53 (1995) and Maurice Obstfeld, Risk-Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth, 84 AMER. ECON. REV. 1310 (1994)).
    • (1998) Amer. Econ. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 537
    • Levine, R.1    Zervos, S.2
  • 49
    • 58149362380 scopus 로고
    • Transaction Costs, Technological Choice, and Endogenous Growth
    • See infra notes 39-56 and accompanying text. In turn, enhanced liquidity is believed to facilitate investment in longer-run, higher return projects, such as high technology start-ups, that may spur greater economic growth and productivity. See Ross Levine & Sara Zervos, Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth, 88 AMER. ECON. REV. 537 (1998) (citing Valerie R. Bencivenga et al., Transaction Costs, Technological Choice, and Endogenous Growth, 67 J. ECO. THEORY 53 (1995) and Maurice Obstfeld, Risk-Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth, 84 AMER. ECON. REV. 1310 (1994)).
    • (1995) J. Eco. Theory , vol.67 , pp. 53
    • Bencivenga, V.R.1
  • 50
    • 0028560106 scopus 로고
    • Risk-Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth
    • See infra notes 39-56 and accompanying text. In turn, enhanced liquidity is believed to facilitate investment in longer-run, higher return projects, such as high technology start-ups, that may spur greater economic growth and productivity. See Ross Levine & Sara Zervos, Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth, 88 AMER. ECON. REV. 537 (1998) (citing Valerie R. Bencivenga et al., Transaction Costs, Technological Choice, and Endogenous Growth, 67 J. ECO. THEORY 53 (1995) and Maurice Obstfeld, Risk-Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth, 84 AMER. ECON. REV. 1310 (1994)).
    • (1994) Amer. Econ. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1310
    • Obstfeld, M.1
  • 51
    • 0042077851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra notes 51-56 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 51-56 and accompanying text.
  • 52
    • 0042578921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • December 5, unpublished manuscript, prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School
    • A possibly intermediate position should be acknowledged here. Ronald Gilson has predicted that formal institutional variations in corporate law and practice will remain, but will be overshadowed by an increasing degree of functional convergence. See Ronald J. Gilson, Globalizing Corporate Governance: Convergence of Form or Function (December 5, 1998) (unpublished manuscript, prepared for a Sloan Conference at Columbia Law School). Indeed, it is virtually true by definition that if existing corporate governance systems possess sufficient plasticity so that their efficiency can be improved within their existing legal and regulatory parameters, then very different governance systems could exhibit approximately equivalent performance characteristics. But this position frames more of a question than an answer: is there sufficient plasticity within institutional forms to permit functional convergence?
    • (1998) Globalizing Corporate Governance: Convergence of Form or Function
    • Gilson, R.J.1
  • 53
    • 0043079618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2. This theme is further addressed supra notes 138-48 and accompanying text
    • See La Porta et al., supra note 2. This theme is further addressed supra notes 138-48 and accompanying text.
    • La Porta1
  • 54
    • 21344488480 scopus 로고
    • The Value of the Voting Right: A Study of the Milan Stock Exchange Experience
    • At the same time, however, weaker legal protections appear to imply higher control premiums to the controlling shareholder. Much evidence supports the proposition that, under "weaker" legal regimes, the controlling shareholders will be able to command a greater control premium for their shares. See Luigi Zingales, The Value of the Voting Right: A Study of the Milan Stock Exchange Experience, 7 REV. FIN. STUD. 125 (1994) (finding a high 82% premium for control blocks on the Milan Exchange, against an international average of 10 to 20%, and a United States average of 5.24%) [hereinafter Zingales, Voting Right]; Luigi Zingales, What Determines the Value of Corporate Votes, 110 Q.J. ECON. 1047 (1995) [hereinafter Zingales, Corporate Votes]. Such a disparity seems strong evidence of the relative value of control and the relative exposure of the minority. However, such evidence also implies that controlling shareholders outside the United States will resist a premium that could cause U.S. controlling shareholders to sell.
    • (1994) Rev. Fin. Stud. , vol.7 , pp. 125
    • Zingales, L.1
  • 55
    • 0043079626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At the same time, however, weaker legal protections appear to imply higher control premiums to the controlling shareholder. Much evidence supports the proposition that, under "weaker" legal regimes, the controlling shareholders will be able to command a greater control premium for their shares. See Luigi Zingales, The Value of the Voting Right: A Study of the Milan Stock Exchange Experience, 7 REV. FIN. STUD. 125 (1994) (finding a high 82% premium for control blocks on the Milan Exchange, against an international average of 10 to 20%, and a United States average of 5.24%) [hereinafter Zingales, Voting Right]; Luigi Zingales, What Determines the Value of Corporate Votes, 110 Q.J. ECON. 1047 (1995) [hereinafter Zingales, Corporate Votes]. Such a disparity seems strong evidence of the relative value of control and the relative exposure of the minority. However, such evidence also implies that controlling shareholders outside the United States will resist a premium that could cause U.S. controlling shareholders to sell.
    • Voting Right
    • Zingales1
  • 56
    • 55449111485 scopus 로고
    • What Determines the Value of Corporate Votes
    • At the same time, however, weaker legal protections appear to imply higher control premiums to the controlling shareholder. Much evidence supports the proposition that, under "weaker" legal regimes, the controlling shareholders will be able to command a greater control premium for their shares. See Luigi Zingales, The Value of the Voting Right: A Study of the Milan Stock Exchange Experience, 7 REV. FIN. STUD. 125 (1994) (finding a high 82% premium for control blocks on the Milan Exchange, against an international average of 10 to 20%, and a United States average of 5.24%) [hereinafter Zingales, Voting Right]; Luigi Zingales, What Determines the Value of Corporate Votes, 110 Q.J. ECON. 1047 (1995) [hereinafter Zingales, Corporate Votes]. Such a disparity seems strong evidence of the relative value of control and the relative exposure of the minority. However, such evidence also implies that controlling shareholders outside the United States will resist a premium that could cause U.S. controlling shareholders to sell.
    • (1995) Q.J. Econ. , vol.110 , pp. 1047
    • Zingales, L.1
  • 57
    • 0042077847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At the same time, however, weaker legal protections appear to imply higher control premiums to the controlling shareholder. Much evidence supports the proposition that, under "weaker" legal regimes, the controlling shareholders will be able to command a greater control premium for their shares. See Luigi Zingales, The Value of the Voting Right: A Study of the Milan Stock Exchange Experience, 7 REV. FIN. STUD. 125 (1994) (finding a high 82% premium for control blocks on the Milan Exchange, against an international average of 10 to 20%, and a United States average of 5.24%) [hereinafter Zingales, Voting Right]; Luigi Zingales, What Determines the Value of Corporate Votes, 110 Q.J. ECON. 1047 (1995) [hereinafter Zingales, Corporate Votes]. Such a disparity seems strong evidence of the relative value of control and the relative exposure of the minority. However, such evidence also implies that controlling shareholders outside the United States will resist a premium that could cause U.S. controlling shareholders to sell.
    • Corporate Votes
    • Zingales1
  • 58
    • 0042578913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 27
    • I borrow this rhetorical distinction between "formal" and "functional" convergence from Professor Gilson. See Gilson, supra note 27.
    • Gilson1
  • 59
    • 84055220945 scopus 로고
    • Is Corporate Law Trivial?: A Political and Economic Analysis
    • The term "regulatory arbitrage" is a more neutral term for what others call the "race to the bottom," that is, the migration of legal entities to the more lenient regulatory regime, with consequent pressure for regulatory relaxation on all regulators. For the view that migration from incorporation in one U.S. state to another state is relatively costless, see Bernard S. Black, Is Corporate Law Trivial?: A Political And Economic Analysis, 84 NW. U. L. REV. 542, 586-88 (1989).
    • (1989) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 542
    • Black, B.S.1
  • 60
    • 0001570378 scopus 로고
    • Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections Upon Delaware
    • The original debate was between William Cary and Ralph Winter. See William L. Cary, Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections Upon Delaware, 83 YALE L.J. 663 (1974) (arguing that competition for charters produces a race to the bottom); Ralph K. Winter, Jr., State Law, Shareholder Protection and the Theory of the Firm, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 251, 254-62 (1977) (arguing that competition produces a race to the top). Judge Winter's views have been more fully articulated by Professor Roberta Romano. See Roberta Romano, Corporate Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 225 (1985). In contrast, Professor Lucian Bebchuk has emphasized the likely divergences between the incentives of managers and shareholders with the resulting prospect that charter competition could produce at least marginally inefficient outcomes. See Lucian A. Bebchuk, Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law, 105 HARV. L. REV. 1435 (1992). Besides the debate over efficiency, the other major approach in this literature has been to relate regulatory competition among the states to an interest group theory of the states' real interests. For a leading effort, see Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Toward An Interest-Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law, 65 TEX. L. REV. 469 (1987).
    • (1974) Yale L.J. , vol.83 , pp. 663
    • Cary, W.L.1
  • 61
    • 0002575839 scopus 로고
    • State Law, Shareholder Protection and the Theory of the Firm
    • The original debate was between William Cary and Ralph Winter. See William L. Cary, Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections Upon Delaware, 83 YALE L.J. 663 (1974) (arguing that competition for charters produces a race to the bottom); Ralph K. Winter, Jr., State Law, Shareholder Protection and the Theory of the Firm, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 251, 254-62 (1977) (arguing that competition produces a race to the top). Judge Winter's views have been more fully articulated by Professor Roberta Romano. See Roberta Romano, Corporate Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 225 (1985). In contrast, Professor Lucian Bebchuk has emphasized the likely divergences between the incentives of managers and shareholders with the resulting prospect that charter competition could produce at least marginally inefficient outcomes. See Lucian A. Bebchuk, Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law, 105 HARV. L. REV. 1435 (1992). Besides the debate over efficiency, the other major approach in this literature has been to relate regulatory competition among the states to an interest group theory of the states' real interests. For a leading effort, see Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Toward An Interest-Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law, 65 TEX. L. REV. 469 (1987).
    • (1977) J. Legal Stud. , vol.6 , pp. 251
    • Winter R.K., Jr.1
  • 62
    • 0000821053 scopus 로고
    • Corporate Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle
    • The original debate was between William Cary and Ralph Winter. See William L. Cary, Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections Upon Delaware, 83 YALE L.J. 663 (1974) (arguing that competition for charters produces a race to the bottom); Ralph K. Winter, Jr., State Law, Shareholder Protection and the Theory of the Firm, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 251, 254-62 (1977) (arguing that competition produces a race to the top). Judge Winter's views have been more fully articulated by Professor Roberta Romano. See Roberta Romano, Corporate Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 225 (1985). In contrast, Professor Lucian Bebchuk has emphasized the likely divergences between the incentives of managers and shareholders with the resulting prospect that charter competition could produce at least marginally inefficient outcomes. See Lucian A. Bebchuk, Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law, 105 HARV. L. REV. 1435 (1992). Besides the debate over efficiency, the other major approach in this literature has been to relate regulatory competition among the states to an interest group theory of the states' real interests. For a leading effort, see Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Toward An Interest-Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law, 65 TEX. L. REV. 469 (1987).
    • (1985) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.1 , pp. 225
    • Romano, R.1
  • 63
    • 11944265922 scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law
    • The original debate was between William Cary and Ralph Winter. See William L. Cary, Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections Upon Delaware, 83 YALE L.J. 663 (1974) (arguing that competition for charters produces a race to the bottom); Ralph K. Winter, Jr., State Law, Shareholder Protection and the Theory of the Firm, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 251, 254-62 (1977) (arguing that competition produces a race to the top). Judge Winter's views have been more fully articulated by Professor Roberta Romano. See Roberta Romano, Corporate Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 225 (1985). In contrast, Professor Lucian Bebchuk has emphasized the likely divergences between the incentives of managers and shareholders with the resulting prospect that charter competition could produce at least marginally inefficient outcomes. See Lucian A. Bebchuk, Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law, 105 HARV. L. REV. 1435 (1992). Besides the debate over efficiency, the other major approach in this literature has been to relate regulatory competition among the states to an interest group theory of the states' real interests. For a leading effort, see Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Toward An Interest-Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law, 65 TEX. L. REV. 469 (1987).
    • (1992) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.105 , pp. 1435
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1
  • 64
    • 59549099859 scopus 로고
    • Toward An Interest-Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law
    • The original debate was between William Cary and Ralph Winter. See William L. Cary, Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections Upon Delaware, 83 YALE L.J. 663 (1974) (arguing that competition for charters produces a race to the bottom); Ralph K. Winter, Jr., State Law, Shareholder Protection and the Theory of the Firm, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 251, 254-62 (1977) (arguing that competition produces a race to the top). Judge Winter's views have been more fully articulated by Professor Roberta Romano. See Roberta Romano, Corporate Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 225 (1985). In contrast, Professor Lucian Bebchuk has emphasized the likely divergences between the incentives of managers and shareholders with the resulting prospect that charter competition could produce at least marginally inefficient outcomes. See Lucian A. Bebchuk, Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law, 105 HARV. L. REV. 1435 (1992). Besides the debate over efficiency, the other major approach in this literature has been to relate regulatory competition among the states to an interest group theory of the states' real interests. For a leading effort, see Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Toward An Interest-Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law, 65 TEX. L. REV. 469 (1987).
    • (1987) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.65 , pp. 469
    • Macey, J.R.1    Miller, G.P.2
  • 65
    • 0010656680 scopus 로고
    • Should Provinces Compete? The Case for a Competitive Corporate Law Market
    • infra notes 82-89 and accompanying text
    • Although Australia and Canada are also federal systems, competition for corporate charters among their provinces does not appear to be vigorous. See Ronald J. Daniels, Should Provinces Compete? The Case for a Competitive Corporate Law Market, 36 MCGILL L.J. 130, 150 (1991). Within the European Community, only a constrained form of competition is possible, as minimum standards, set forth in directives issued by the Council of the EU bind all members states. See sources cited infra notes 82-89 and accompanying text.
    • (1991) Mcgill L.J. , vol.36 , pp. 130
    • Daniels, R.J.1
  • 66
    • 0042578823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Codetermination and German Securities Markets
    • German courts have struck down a variety of efforts perceived by them as attempts to contract around codetermination. See Mark J. Roe, Codetermination and German Securities Markets, 1998 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 167.
    • (1998) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , pp. 167
    • Roe, M.J.1
  • 67
    • 0041576793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra notes 107-128 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 107-128 and accompanying text.
  • 68
    • 84890635536 scopus 로고
    • Mandatory Disclosure as a Solution to Agency Problems
    • Others have asserted that this function of reducing agency costs is the historic and most important goal of the federal securities laws. See Paul G. Mahoney, Mandatory Disclosure as a Solution to Agency Problems, 62 U. CHI. L. REV. 1047, 1047-51 (1995).
    • (1995) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.62 , pp. 1047
    • Mahoney, P.G.1
  • 69
    • 0347173933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Production of Corporate Law
    • infra notes 223-32 and accompanying text
    • The latest evidence suggests that American corporate law is relatively uniform, whether despite or because of interjurisdictional charter competition. See William J. Carney, The Production of Corporate Law, 71 S. CAL. L. REV. 715, 728 (1998); infra notes 223-32 and accompanying text.
    • (1998) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 715
    • Carney, W.J.1
  • 70
    • 0347989498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Backlash
    • On this theme, see generally Mark J. Roe, Backlash, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 217 (1998).
    • (1998) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 217
    • Roe, M.J.1
  • 71
    • 0348195772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Active Board of Directors and Performance of the Large Publicly Traded Corporation
    • For a recent consensus statement of this view and an attempt to provide empirical support for the proposition that such a board increases corporate efficiency and market value, see Ira M. Millstein & Paul W. MacAvoy, The Active Board of Directors and Performance of the Large Publicly Traded Corporation, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1283 (1998). But see Sanjai Bhagat & Bernard S. Black, Board Composition and Firm Performance, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY, supra note 2, at 291, 292 ("no convincing evidence" exists that firms with majority-independent boards perform better than firms without such boards).
    • (1998) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 1283
    • Millstein, I.M.1    Macavoy, P.W.2
  • 72
    • 0348195772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Board Composition and Firm Performance
    • supra note 2
    • For a recent consensus statement of this view and an attempt to provide empirical support for the proposition that such a board increases corporate efficiency and market value, see Ira M. Millstein & Paul W. MacAvoy, The Active Board of Directors and Performance of the Large Publicly Traded Corporation, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1283 (1998). But see Sanjai Bhagat & Bernard S. Black, Board Composition and Firm Performance, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY, supra note 2, at 291, 292 ("no convincing evidence" exists that firms with majority-independent boards perform better than firms without such boards).
    • Corporate Governance Today , pp. 291
    • Bhagat, S.1    Black, B.S.2
  • 73
    • 0004305444 scopus 로고
    • See MANCUR OLSON, THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION: PUBLIC GOODS AND THE THEORY OF GROUPS (1965). Olson later extended his theory to show how interest groups could (and would) maintain inefficient rules in place even at the cost of national decline. See MANCUR OLSON, THE RISE AND DECLINE OF NATIONS: ECONOMIC GROWTH, STAGFLATION AND SOCIAL RIGIDITIES (1982).
    • (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups
    • Olson, M.1
  • 74
    • 0003461404 scopus 로고
    • See MANCUR OLSON, THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION: PUBLIC GOODS AND THE THEORY OF GROUPS (1965). Olson later extended his theory to show how interest groups could (and would) maintain inefficient rules in place even at the cost of national decline. See MANCUR OLSON, THE RISE AND DECLINE OF NATIONS: ECONOMIC GROWTH, STAGFLATION AND SOCIAL RIGIDITIES (1982).
    • (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation and Social Rigidities
    • Olson, M.1
  • 75
    • 0043079620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Survey - German Banking and Financing 98: A Unique Perspective
    • June 24
    • See Survey - German Banking and Financing 98: A Unique Perspective; FIN. TIMES, June 24, 1998, at 7.
    • (1998) Fin. Times , pp. 7
  • 76
    • 0041576625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deutsche Telekom, German Corporate Governance, and the Transition Costs of Capitalism
    • See Jeffrey N. Gordon, Deutsche Telekom, German Corporate Governance, and the Transition Costs of Capitalism, 1998 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 185, 200.
    • (1998) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , vol.185 , pp. 200
    • Gordon, J.N.1
  • 77
    • 0042077733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 78
    • 0041576650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 27
    • See Gilson, supra note 27.
    • Gilson1
  • 79
    • 0043079626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 29
    • See Zingales, Voting Right, supra note 29; Zingales, Corporate Votes, supra note 29.
    • Voting Right
    • Zingales1
  • 80
    • 0042077847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 29
    • See Zingales, Voting Right, supra note 29; Zingales, Corporate Votes, supra note 29.
    • Corporate Votes
    • Zingales1
  • 81
    • 0042578922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See La Porta et al., supra note 7, at 1132; Schleifer & Vishny, supra note 11.
    • La Porta1
  • 82
    • 0043079508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 11
    • See La Porta et al., supra note 7, at 1132; Schleifer & Vishny, supra note 11.
    • Schleifer1    Vishny2
  • 83
    • 0043079507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 13
    • See ECGN SURVEY, supra note 13.
    • ECGN Survey
  • 84
    • 0043079623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 23
    • See ROE, supra note 23.
    • Roe1
  • 85
    • 85088279758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lifetime Employment: Labor Peace and the Evolution of Japanese Corporate Governance
    • Some have argued that the system of lifetime employment in Japan created a desirable incentive to invest in human capital, but the most recent review doubts that the practice had such an impact and finds that the actual motivation was to reduce worker influence in the factory and to minimize the prospect of socialist electoral victories in post-war Japan. See Ronald Gilson & Mark J. Roe, Lifetime Employment: Labor Peace and the Evolution of Japanese Corporate Governance (forthcoming in the Columbia Law Review).
    • Columbia Law Review
    • Gilson, R.1    Roe, M.J.2
  • 86
    • 0042578827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 42
    • Gordon, supra note 42, at 196.
    • Gordon1
  • 87
    • 0042578824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, even a large institutional investor holding 1 to 2% of a firm's stock must recognize that 98% of the benefit of any gains that flow from its monitoring efforts will be enjoyed by other shareholders. For an 80% blockholder, however, this is a less serious problem.
  • 88
    • 0041576791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 13
    • See Bratton & McCahery, supra note 13; see also Milhaupt, supra note 19, at 1179-84.
    • Bratton1    McCahery2
  • 89
    • 0042077849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 19
    • See Bratton & McCahery, supra note 13; see also Milhaupt, supra note 19, at 1179-84.
    • Milhaupt1
  • 90
    • 0041576788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Italian Corporate Governance: One American's Perspective
    • supra note 2
    • The extreme example is probably Italian corporate governance which relies on small family held firms and has minimized the role of outside investors. See Jonathan R. Macey, Italian Corporate Governance: One American's Perspective, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY, supra note 2, at 677, 692 (noting also that Italian economy "is dominated by small efficient family firms"). French corporate governance also seems to be characterized by "an interpenetration of kinship structures (family owners) and managerial bureaucracy." See Windolf, supra note 2, at 695.
    • Corporate Governance Today , pp. 677
    • Macey, J.R.1
  • 91
    • 0043079621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2
    • The extreme example is probably Italian corporate governance which relies on small family held firms and has minimized the role of outside investors. See Jonathan R. Macey, Italian Corporate Governance: One American's Perspective, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY, supra note 2, at 677, 692 (noting also that Italian economy "is dominated by small efficient family firms"). French corporate governance also seems to be characterized by "an interpenetration of kinship structures (family owners) and managerial bureaucracy." See Windolf, supra note 2, at 695.
    • Windolf1
  • 92
    • 22444452147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transnational Takeover Talk - Regulations Relating to Tender Offers and Insider Trading in the United States, the United Kingdom, Germany, and Australia
    • Revealingly, Germany uses the last major financial marketplace to prohibit insider trading, and it did so two years late in complying with an EU directive requiring such a prohibition. See Roberta S. Karmel, Transnational Takeover Talk - Regulations Relating to Tender Offers and Insider Trading in the United States, the United Kingdom, Germany, and Australia, 66 U. CIN. L. REV. 1133, 1149-52 (1998).
    • (1998) U. Cin. L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 1133
    • Karmel, R.S.1
  • 93
    • 0042077848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 13
    • See Bratton & McCahery, supra note 13, at 8.
    • Bratton1    McCahery2
  • 94
    • 0009247870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Objectivity, Control and Adaptability in Corporate Governance
    • id. at 9, supra note 2
    • See id. at 9; see also Arnold W.A. Boot & Jonathan R. Macey, Objectivity, Control and Adaptability in Corporate Governance, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE TODAY, supra note 2, at 213, 214-15 (1998). This latter problem is a corollary of the greater frequency of hostile control consists in market centered systems.
    • (1998) Corporate Governance Today , pp. 213
    • Boot, A.W.A.1    Macey, J.R.2
  • 95
    • 0009895248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 42
    • See Gordon, supra note 42, at 187; Marco Pagano et al., Why Do Companies Go Public? An Empirical Analysis, 53 J. FIN. 27 (1998).
    • Gordon1
  • 96
    • 0009895248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do Companies Go Public? An Empirical Analysis
    • See Gordon, supra note 42, at 187; Marco Pagano et al., Why Do Companies Go Public? An Empirical Analysis, 53 J. FIN. 27 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Fin. , vol.53 , pp. 27
    • Pagano, M.1
  • 97
    • 26144465721 scopus 로고
    • Cracking the German Market: The Hard Sell, Getting Germans to Invest in Stock
    • Aug. 4
    • See Peter Gumbel, Cracking the German Market: The Hard Sell, Getting Germans to Invest in Stock, WALL ST. J., Aug. 4, 1995, at A4. See Gordon, supra note 42, at 196 (citing study by Theodor Baums, a German law professor); see also The 1996 Guide to Germany, EUROMONEY, June 1996, at A4 tbl. 1 (for 1995, 23.9% for Germany, 130.7% for Great Britain).
    • (1995) Wall St. J.
    • Gumbel, P.1
  • 98
    • 0041576648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 42, citing study by Theodor Baums, a German law professor)
    • See Peter Gumbel, Cracking the German Market: The Hard Sell, Getting Germans to Invest in Stock, WALL ST. J., Aug. 4, 1995, at A4. See Gordon, supra note 42, at 196 (citing study by Theodor Baums, a German law professor); see also The 1996 Guide to Germany, EUROMONEY, June 1996, at A4 tbl. 1 (for 1995, 23.9% for Germany, 130.7% for Great Britain).
    • Gordon1
  • 99
    • 26144460852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The 1996 Guide to Germany
    • June 1996, tbl. 1 (for 1995, 23.9% for Germany, 130.7% for Great Britain)
    • See Peter Gumbel, Cracking the German Market: The Hard Sell, Getting Germans to Invest in Stock, WALL ST. J., Aug. 4, 1995, at A4. See Gordon, supra note 42, at 196 (citing study by Theodor Baums, a German law professor); see also The 1996 Guide to Germany, EUROMONEY, June 1996, at A4 tbl. 1 (for 1995, 23.9% for Germany, 130.7% for Great Britain).
    • Euromoney
  • 100
    • 0042578912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Italian Stock Market Reform
    • Aug. 20
    • See Roberta S. Karmel, Italian Stock Market Reform, N.Y. L.J., Aug. 20, 1998, at 3.
    • (1998) N.Y. L.J. , pp. 3
    • Karmel, R.S.1
  • 101
    • 0042077844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 102
    • 0041576789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 53
    • As of 1989, only seven Italian corporations had offered more than 50% of their shares to the public, and in five of these, voting control remained locked in a small family group. See Macey, supra note 53, at 687-88.
    • Macey1
  • 103
    • 0041576790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 42
    • Gordon, supra note 42, at 186-87.
    • Gordon1
  • 104
    • 0043079513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 186
    • Id. at 186.
  • 105
    • 0042077724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Euro's Warm-Up Act: IPOs
    • June 22
    • See Thane Peterson et al., The Euro's Warm-Up Act: IPOs, BUS. WEEK, June 22, 1998 at 24 (noting that new share offerings exceeded $91 billion in 1997 on European exchanges, a record level, and may exceed this in 1998).
    • (1998) Bus. Week , pp. 24
    • Peterson, T.1
  • 106
    • 0042077754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. (noting that 53% of the $31 billion in new offerings in 1998 have been corporate offerings unrelated to privatizations)
    • See id. (noting that 53% of the $31 billion in new offerings in 1998 have been corporate offerings unrelated to privatizations).
  • 107
    • 0042578918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. (discussing success of the Neuer Market)
    • See id. (discussing success of the Neuer Market).
  • 108
    • 0041576649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A High-Tech Europe Is Finally in Sight
    • Aug. 31, noting also that this market was up 150% in 1998
    • See Thane Peterson, A High-Tech Europe Is Finally In Sight, BUS. WEEK, Aug. 31, 1998, at 120 (noting also that this market was up 150% in 1998).
    • (1998) Bus. Week , pp. 120
    • Peterson, T.1
  • 109
    • 0042578825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Success Worth Replicating
    • Sept. 3
    • See id. Several of these listings appear to have done IPOs in the United States and then listed on the Neuer Market. See Graham Bowley, A Success Worth Replicating, FIN. TIMES, Sept. 3, 1998, at 21 (discussing Quiagen, Germany's first biotech startup).
    • (1998) Fin. Times , pp. 21
    • Bowley, G.1
  • 110
    • 0042578920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 60
    • See Karmel, supra note 60, at 3.
    • Karmel1
  • 111
    • 0043079562 scopus 로고
    • The European Union's Investment Services Directive
    • See Manning G. Warren III, The European Union's Investment Services Directive, 15 U. PA. J. INT'L BUS. L. 181 (1994). The "Investment Services Directive" is more technically referred to as Council Directive 93/22 on
    • (1994) U. Pa. J. Int'l Bus. L. , vol.15 , pp. 181
    • Warren M.G. III1
  • 112
    • 0042578919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 113
    • 0043079561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prodi Rolls Out Reforms
    • Feb. 19
    • See Alan Friedman, Prodi Rolls Out Reforms, INT'L HERALD TRIB., Feb. 19, 1998, at 1.
    • (1998) Int'l Herald Trib. , pp. 1
    • Friedman, A.1
  • 114
    • 0041576671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Italian Takeover Reforms Take Shape
    • Feb. 12
    • James Blitz, Italian Takeover Reforms Take Shape, FIN. TIMES, Feb. 12, 1998, at 2.
    • (1998) Fin. Times , pp. 2
    • Blitz, J.1
  • 115
    • 0043079619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 116
    • 0041576785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 60, at 3. There had been at least 17 such IPOs as of mid-August 1998. See id.
    • See Karmel, supra note 60, at 3. There had been at least 17 such IPOs as of mid-August 1998. See id.; see also Deborah Ball, New Entrepreneurs Fuel IPO Bonanza in Italy, WALL ST. J., July 22, 1998, at B7A (estimating that another five hundred private Italian firms could qualify for stock exchange listing).
    • Karmel1
  • 117
    • 4243491209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Entrepreneurs Fuel IPO Bonanza in Italy
    • July 22, estimating that another five hundred private Italian firms could qualify for stock exchange listing
    • See Karmel, supra note 60, at 3. There had been at least 17 such IPOs as of mid-August 1998. See id.; see also Deborah Ball, New Entrepreneurs Fuel IPO Bonanza in Italy, WALL ST. J., July 22, 1998, at B7A (estimating that another five hundred private Italian firms could qualify for stock exchange listing).
    • (1998) Wall St. J.
    • Ball, D.1
  • 118
    • 16544382312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Europe's IPO Game May Get Tougher
    • Aug. 25
    • See Suzanne McGee, Europe's IPO Game May Get Tougher, WALL ST. J., Aug. 25, 1998, at C1 (noting that "it became almost routine for new stock issues to be sold well above the price range at which they were marketed. Issues have been outscribed tenfold routinely, and many rally in after-market trading").
    • (1998) Wall St. J.
    • McGee, S.1
  • 119
    • 0041576769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 120
    • 4243491210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 77, noting approaching major privatizations in Switzerland, Poland, Greece, and France
    • See McGee, supra note 77, at C1 (noting approaching major privatizations in Switzerland, Poland, Greece, and France).
    • McGee1
  • 121
    • 0042578917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 73
    • See Friedman, supra note 73 (noting that corporate governance and financial transparency reform seem to be issues that are particularly attractive to center-left coalitions in Italy and possibly Holland and Sweden).
    • Friedman1
  • 122
    • 0032161066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Foreign Investors Stimulate or Inhibit Stock Market Development in Latin America
    • reviewing literature
    • See Kent Hargis, Do Foreign Investors Stimulate or Inhibit Stock Market Development in Latin America, 38 Q. REV. ECON. & FIN. 303 (1998) (reviewing literature); Levine & Zervos, supra note 25; Raghuram G. Rajan & Luigi Zingales, Financial Dependence and Growth, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 559 (1998). These studies do not demonstrate the superiority of securities markets over a banking system as an engine of growth, but they do suggest that securities markets stimulate investment in longer term and higher risk projects (such as high technology investments) that have a higher return over the long run.
    • (1998) Q. Rev. Econ. & Fin. , vol.38 , pp. 303
    • Hargis, K.1
  • 123
    • 0032161066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 25
    • See Kent Hargis, Do Foreign Investors Stimulate or Inhibit Stock Market Development in Latin America, 38 Q. REV. ECON. & FIN. 303 (1998) (reviewing literature); Levine & Zervos, supra note 25; Raghuram G. Rajan & Luigi Zingales, Financial Dependence and Growth, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 559 (1998). These studies do not demonstrate the superiority of securities markets over a banking system as an engine of growth, but they do suggest that securities markets stimulate investment in longer term and higher risk projects (such as high technology investments) that have a higher return over the long run.
    • Levine1    Zervos2
  • 124
    • 0001051586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial Dependence and Growth
    • See Kent Hargis, Do Foreign Investors Stimulate or Inhibit Stock Market Development in Latin America, 38 Q. REV. ECON. & FIN. 303 (1998) (reviewing literature); Levine & Zervos, supra note 25; Raghuram G. Rajan & Luigi Zingales, Financial Dependence and Growth, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 559 (1998). These studies do not demonstrate the superiority of securities markets over a banking system as an engine of growth, but they do suggest that securities markets stimulate investment in longer term and higher risk projects (such as high technology investments) that have a higher return over the long run.
    • (1998) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 559
    • Rajan, R.G.1    Zingales, L.2
  • 125
    • 0032378332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market - A Proposal
    • For overviews of this process, see generally Uri Geiger, Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market - A Proposal, 66 FORDHAM L. REV. 1785 (1998); David Reid & Andrew Ballheimer, The Legal Framework of the Securities Industry in the European Community Under the 1992 Program, 29 COLUM. J. TRANSNAT'L L. 103 (1991); Andreas J. Roquette, New Developments Relating to the Internationalization of the Capital Markets: A Comparison of Legislative Reforms in the United States, the European Community, and Germany, 14 U. PA. J. INT'L BUS. L. 565 (1994); Manning G. Warren III, Global Harmonization of Securities Laws: The Achievements of the European Communities, 31 HARV. INT'L L.J. 185 (1990) (describing the development of the disclosure system in the European Union).
    • (1998) Fordham L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 1785
    • Geiger, U.1
  • 126
    • 0032378332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Legal Framework of the Securities Industry in the European Community under the 1992 Program
    • For overviews of this process, see generally Uri Geiger, Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market - A Proposal, 66 FORDHAM L. REV. 1785 (1998); David Reid & Andrew Ballheimer, The Legal Framework of the Securities Industry in the European Community Under the 1992 Program, 29 COLUM. J. TRANSNAT'L L. 103 (1991); Andreas J. Roquette, New Developments Relating to the Internationalization of the Capital Markets: A Comparison of Legislative Reforms in the United States, the European Community, and Germany, 14 U. PA. J. INT'L BUS. L. 565 (1994); Manning G. Warren III, Global Harmonization of Securities Laws: The Achievements of the European Communities, 31 HARV. INT'L L.J. 185 (1990) (describing the development of the disclosure system in the European Union).
    • (1991) Colum. J. Transnat'l L. , vol.29 , pp. 103
    • Reid, D.1    Ballheimer, A.2
  • 127
    • 0032378332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Developments Relating to the Internationalization of the Capital Markets: A Comparison of Legislative Reforms in the United States, the European Community, and Germany
    • For overviews of this process, see generally Uri Geiger, Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market - A Proposal, 66 FORDHAM L. REV. 1785 (1998); David Reid & Andrew Ballheimer, The Legal Framework of the Securities Industry in the European Community Under the 1992 Program, 29 COLUM. J. TRANSNAT'L L. 103 (1991); Andreas J. Roquette, New Developments Relating to the Internationalization of the Capital Markets: A Comparison of Legislative Reforms in the United States, the European Community, and Germany, 14 U. PA. J. INT'L BUS. L. 565 (1994); Manning G. Warren III, Global Harmonization of Securities Laws: The Achievements of the European Communities, 31 HARV. INT'L L.J. 185 (1990) (describing the development of the disclosure system in the European Union).
    • (1994) U. Pa. J. Int'l Bus. L. , vol.14 , pp. 565
    • Roquette, A.J.1
  • 128
    • 0032378332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global Harmonization of Securities Laws: The Achievements of the European Communities
    • For overviews of this process, see generally Uri Geiger, Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market - A Proposal, 66 FORDHAM L. REV. 1785 (1998); David Reid & Andrew Ballheimer, The Legal Framework of the Securities Industry in the European Community Under the 1992 Program, 29 COLUM. J. TRANSNAT'L L. 103 (1991); Andreas J. Roquette, New Developments Relating to the Internationalization of the Capital Markets: A Comparison of Legislative Reforms in the United States, the European Community, and Germany, 14 U. PA. J. INT'L BUS. L. 565 (1994); Manning G. Warren III, Global Harmonization of Securities Laws: The Achievements of the European Communities, 31 HARV. INT'L L.J. 185 (1990) (describing the development of the disclosure system in the European Union).
    • (1990) Harv. Int'l L.J. , vol.31 , pp. 185
    • Warren M.G. III1
  • 129
    • 0041576653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 82
    • See Geiger, supra note 82, at 1788-89.
    • Geiger1
  • 130
    • 0041576767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 82
    • See Geiger, supra note 82, at 1789-90; Reid & Ballheimer, supra note 82, at 124.
    • Geiger1
  • 131
    • 0042077732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 82
    • See Geiger, supra note 82, at 1789-90; Reid & Ballheimer, supra note 82, at 124.
    • Reid1    Ballheimer2
  • 132
    • 0042077836 scopus 로고
    • The Societas European: The Evolving European Corporation Statute
    • For reviews of these efforts, see generally Terence L. Blackburn, The Societas European: The Evolving European Corporation Statute, 61 FORDHAM L. REV. 695 (1993); Amir N. Licht, International Diversity in Securities Regulation: Roadblocks on the Way to Convergence, 20 CARDOZO L. REV. 227, 239-40 (1998).
    • (1993) Fordham L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 695
    • Blackburn, T.L.1
  • 133
    • 0041576626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Diversity in Securities Regulation: Roadblocks on the Way to Convergence
    • For reviews of these efforts, see generally Terence L. Blackburn, The Societas European: The Evolving European Corporation Statute, 61 FORDHAM L. REV. 695 (1993); Amir N. Licht, International Diversity in Securities Regulation: Roadblocks on the Way to Convergence, 20 CARDOZO L. REV. 227, 239-40 (1998).
    • (1998) Cardozo L. Rev. , vol.20 , pp. 227
    • Licht, A.N.1
  • 134
    • 0041576675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Proposal for a Fifth Directive, Foundation Article 54(3)(g) of the EEC Treaty Concerning the Structure of Public Limited Companies and the Powers and Obligations of Their Origins, 1983 O.J. (C240) 2. This draft proposed two optional structures for providing employee representation, but both encountered intense British opposition.
  • 135
    • 0042077728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Governance Update
    • See Corporate Governance Update, 5 CORP. GOVERNANCE INT'L REV. 256 (1997).
    • (1997) Corp. Governance Int'l Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 256
  • 136
    • 0041576758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takeover Directive in Deadlock
    • Oct. 9
    • See Jane Martinson, Takeover Directive in Deadlock, FIN. TIMES, Oct. 9, 1998, at 2.
    • (1998) Fin. Times , pp. 2
    • Martinson, J.1
  • 137
    • 0043079536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More Talks on Defining Takeovers Bids Directive
    • Jan. 9, LEXIS, Nexis Library, curnws file
    • See More Talks on Defining Takeovers Bids Directive, EUR. REP., Jan. 9, 1999, available in LEXIS, Nexis Library, curnws file.
    • (1999) Eur. Rep.
  • 138
    • 0042578911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What the TUPA means for you
    • Dec. 5, at 18
    • The Acquired Rights Directive of 1977 has been implemented by legislation in many EU member states. In Britain, the Transfer of Undertakings (Protection of Employment) Act codifies its obligations. Essentially, on a transfer, the employee staff must be transferred on the same or better terms. For a brief summary, see What the TUPA means for you, GUARDIAN, Dec. 5, 1998, at 18.
    • (1998) Guardian
  • 139
    • 0043079617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Council Directive 88/627 of December 12, 1988 on the Information to be Published when a Major Holding in a Listed Company is Acquired or Disposed of, 1988 O.J. (L. 348) 62
    • See Council Directive 88/627 of December 12, 1988 on the Information to be Published when a Major Holding in a Listed Company is Acquired or Disposed of, 1988 O.J. (L. 348) 62.
  • 140
    • 0043079507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 13
    • See ECGN SURVEY, supra note 13, at 56-57.
    • ECGN Survey , pp. 56-57
  • 141
    • 0043079542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 87-90
    • See id. at 87-90.
  • 142
    • 0042077843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transparency of Ownership and Control in Germany
    • supra note 13
    • See Marco Brecht & Ekkehart Bohmer, Transparency of Ownership and Control in Germany, in ECGN SURVEY, supra note 13, at 23 (noting "clash of cultures" over issue of transparency).
    • ECGN Survey , pp. 23
    • Brecht, M.1    Bohmer, E.2
  • 143
    • 0042077760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 57
    • See id. at 57.
  • 144
    • 0041576652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 145
    • 0043079511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 90-92
    • Id. at 90-92.
  • 146
    • 0043079544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ownership and Control in Belgium
    • supra note 13
    • See Marco Becht, Ownership and Control in Belgium, in ECGN SURVEY, supra note 13, at 13-18.
    • ECGN Survey , pp. 13-18
    • Becht, M.1
  • 147
    • 0042578907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ownership Pyramidal Groups and Separation between Ownership and Control in Italy
    • supra note 13
    • See Marcello Binachi et al., Ownership Pyramidal Groups and Separation Between Ownership and Control in Italy, in ECGN SURVEY, supra note 13, at 13-14.
    • ECGN Survey , pp. 13-14
    • Binachi, M.1
  • 148
    • 0042077757 scopus 로고
    • Fund Managers Call for Relaxation of Restrictions
    • Sept. 11
    • See Fund Managers Call for Relaxation of Restrictions, FIN. TIMES, Sept. 11, 1988, at 2.
    • (1988) Fin. Times , pp. 2
  • 149
    • 0043079548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 150
    • 0041576779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 151
    • 0042077840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Evolving Accounting Standards in the International Markets
    • PLI No. B4-7166
    • See David Mercado, Evolving Accounting Standards in the International Markets, in INTERNATIONAL SECURITIES MARKETS 1996, at 345, 346 (1996) (PLI No. B4-7166); see also Glenn Reiter, International Securities Offerings.- Recent Developments And Current Issues, in 29TH ANNUAL INSTITUTE ON SECURITIES REGULATION (1997) (PLI B4-7206).
    • (1996) International Securities Markets 1996 , pp. 345
    • Mercado, D.1
  • 152
    • 0042578908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Securities Offerings.- Recent Developments and Current Issues
    • PLI B4-7206
    • See David Mercado, Evolving Accounting Standards in the International Markets, in INTERNATIONAL SECURITIES MARKETS 1996, at 345, 346 (1996) (PLI No. B4-7166); see also Glenn Reiter, International Securities Offerings.- Recent Developments And Current Issues, in 29TH ANNUAL INSTITUTE ON SECURITIES REGULATION (1997) (PLI B4-7206).
    • (1997) 29th Annual Institute on Securities Regulation
    • Reiter, G.1
  • 153
    • 0043079545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 103, Exhibit C
    • See Mercado, supra note 103, at 419 (Exhibit C) (setting forth the SEC statement, which was not issued as a formal release).
    • Mercado1
  • 154
    • 0043039767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial Transparency and Corporate Governance: You Manage What You Measure
    • My colleague Louis Lowenstein has argued that the SEC will be under intense pressure to relax standards for domestic issuers if it lowers standards for foreign issuers. See Louis Lowenstein, Financial Transparency and Corporate Governance: You Manage What You Measure, 96 COLUM. L. REV. 1335, 1338 (1996). The counterargument is that institutional investors may force both foreign and domestic issuers to disclose more information than the SEC requires.
    • (1996) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 1335
    • Lowenstein, L.1
  • 155
    • 0037790109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Accounting Standards: The World's Standards by 2002
    • Some predict that the SEC will cross this bridge by no later than 2002. See Paul Pachter, International Accounting Standards: The World's Standards By 2002, 68 CPA J. 14, 15 (1998).
    • (1998) CPA J. , vol.68 , pp. 14
    • Pachter, P.1
  • 156
    • 0010561257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulatory Arbitrage for Real: International Securities Regulation in a World Interacting Securities Markets
    • See Amir N. Licht, Regulatory Arbitrage for Real: International Securities Regulation in A World Interacting Securities Markets, 38 VA. J. INT'L. L. 563, 566 (1998).
    • (1998) Va. J. Int'l. L. , vol.38 , pp. 563
    • Licht, A.N.1
  • 157
    • 4243510820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Big Board Is Hoping Daimler Chrysler Drives in More Foreign Primary Shares
    • Oct. 21
    • See Greg Ip & Gregory L. White, Big Board Is Hoping Daimler Chrysler Drives In More Foreign Primary Shares, WALL ST. J., Oct. 21, 1998, at C1; see also Gerard Achstatter, Foreign Companies Flock to the U.S. But Their Stocks Carry Extra Risks, INVESTOR'S BUS. DAILY, June 2, 1998 at A-7 (noting 50% rise in foreign listings from 1995 to 1998).
    • (1998) Wall St. J.
    • Ip, G.1    White, G.L.2
  • 158
    • 0042578826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foreign Companies Flock to the U.S. but Their Stocks Carry Extra Risks
    • June 2, at A-7
    • See Greg Ip & Gregory L. White, Big Board Is Hoping Daimler Chrysler Drives In More Foreign Primary Shares, WALL ST. J., Oct. 21, 1998, at C1; see also Gerard Achstatter, Foreign Companies Flock to the U.S. But Their Stocks Carry Extra Risks, INVESTOR'S BUS. DAILY, June 2, 1998 at A-7 (noting 50% rise in foreign listings from 1995 to 1998).
    • (1998) Investor's Bus. Daily
    • Achstatter, G.1
  • 159
    • 0042077764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 107, at 566
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 566.
    • Licht1
  • 160
    • 0042077762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 82, at 1786
    • See Geiger, supra note 82, at 1786 (citing data from Office of International Corporate Finance of the SEC); see also Pachter, supra note 106.
    • Geiger1
  • 161
    • 0042578847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 106
    • See Geiger, supra note 82, at 1786 (citing data from Office of International Corporate Finance of the SEC); see also Pachter, supra note 106.
    • Pachter1
  • 162
    • 0041576775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While foreign issuers list, they seldom make primary offerings in the United States. This may be attributable to a fear of the litigation remedies that they would face in the United States under the Securities Act of 1933 or to the additional accounting requirements of the SEC when a foreign issuer seeks to register securities for sale (in which event the SEC requires not simply reconciliation to U.S. Generally Accepted Accounting Principles ("GAAP") but full compliance therewith).
  • 163
    • 0042077842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 107, at 634-35
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 634-35; see also, Gordon Alexander et al., Asset Pricing and Dual Listing on Foreign Capital Markets: A Note, 42 J. FIN. 151 (1987); Gregory Kedlec & John McConnell, The Effect of Market Segmentation and Illiquidity on Asset Prices: Evidence from Exchange Listings, 49 J. FIN. 611 (1994).
    • Licht1
  • 164
    • 84977732409 scopus 로고
    • Asset Pricing and Dual Listing on Foreign Capital Markets: A Note
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 634-35; see also, Gordon Alexander et al., Asset Pricing and Dual Listing on Foreign Capital Markets: A Note, 42 J. FIN. 151 (1987); Gregory Kedlec & John McConnell, The Effect of Market Segmentation and Illiquidity on Asset Prices: Evidence from Exchange Listings, 49 J. FIN. 611 (1994).
    • (1987) J. Fin. , vol.42 , pp. 151
    • Alexander, G.1
  • 165
    • 84993901781 scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Market Segmentation and Illiquidity on Asset Prices: Evidence from Exchange Listings
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 634-35; see also, Gordon Alexander et al., Asset Pricing and Dual Listing on Foreign Capital Markets: A Note, 42 J. FIN. 151 (1987); Gregory Kedlec & John McConnell, The Effect of Market Segmentation and Illiquidity on Asset Prices: Evidence from Exchange Listings, 49 J. FIN. 611 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Fin. , vol.49 , pp. 611
    • Kedlec, G.1    McConnell, J.2
  • 166
    • 0042578910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 106
    • When Daimler listed on the New York Stock Exchange in 1993, it was required to restate its 1992 annual earnings to comply with U.S. GAAP standards. It had reported a gain of DM 615 million to its shareholders, but was required to restate this as a loss of DM 1,839 - or a swing of nearly DM 2,554. See Pachter, supra note 106, at 14. Obviously, this turnaround can both embarrass management and cause uncertainty for investors and thus represents a deterrent to a U.S. listing. Nonetheless, foreign firms continue to list at an increasing rate.
    • Pachter1
  • 167
    • 0039692752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oct. 14, unpublished manuscript
    • Professor Edward Rock has studied the IPO process in Israel, which typically involves a "high-tech" start up company in Israel listing on NASDAQ as an integral part of the offering process. He concludes that an "unappreciated function of the U.S. mandatory disclosure regime is the extent to which it permits issuers to make a credible commitment to a level and permanence of disclosure." See Edward Rock, Mandatory Disclosure As Credible Commitment: Going Public, Opting In, Opting Out and Globalization, at 2 (Oct. 14, 1998) (unpublished manuscript). In essence, this is the same bonding thesis. See also Asher Blass et al., Corporate Governance In An Emerging Market: The Case of Israel, 10 J. APPLIED CORP. FIN. 79, 86-89 (1998) (finding that high quality Israeli IPOs listed on NASDAQ, while lower quality offerings listed on Tel Aviv Stock Exchange and that portfolio investors tended to invest in the former offerings, but not the Tel Aviv offerings). Such self-segregation again seems to support the bonding thesis.
    • (1998) Mandatory Disclosure as Credible Commitment: Going Public, Opting In, Opting Out and Globalization , pp. 2
    • Rock, E.1
  • 168
    • 37949056908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Governance in An Emerging Market: The Case of Israel
    • Professor Edward Rock has studied the IPO process in Israel, which typically involves a "high- tech" start up company in Israel listing on NASDAQ as an integral part of the offering process. He concludes that an "unappreciated function of the U.S. mandatory disclosure regime is the extent to which it permits issuers to make a credible commitment to a level and permanence of disclosure." See Edward Rock, Mandatory Disclosure As Credible Commitment: Going Public, Opting In, Opting Out and Globalization, at 2 (Oct. 14, 1998) (unpublished manuscript). In essence, this is the same bonding thesis. See also Asher Blass et al., Corporate Governance In An Emerging Market: The Case of Israel, 10 J. APPLIED CORP. FIN. 79, 86-89 (1998) (finding that high quality Israeli IPOs listed on NASDAQ, while lower quality offerings listed on Tel Aviv Stock Exchange and that portfolio investors tended to invest in the former offerings, but not the Tel Aviv offerings). Such self-segregation again seems to support the bonding thesis.
    • (1998) J. Applied Corp. Fin. , vol.10 , pp. 79
    • Blass, A.1
  • 169
    • 0041576774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 107
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 634. One study even finds that foreign firms that had listed only their depositary receipts in the bulletin board market in the U.S. experience significant positive returns when they upgrade from this OTC market to the NASDAQ market and, as a consequence, become "reporting" companies subject to the SEC's mandatory disclosure system. See Darius Miller, Why Do Foreign Firms List in the United States: An Empirical Analysis of the Depositary Receipt Market (1996) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the author) (cited in Licht, supra note 107, at 634). The importance of this finding is that these issuers had already overcome market segmentation by establishing an ADR facility, but had not yet become subject to U.S. mandatory disclosure rules. See SEC Rule 12g3- 2(b), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2 (1998) (providing exemption for such foreign issuers upon filing of home country financial statements). Thus, the upgrade isolates the impact of the differential between SEC reporting requirements and home country requirements.
    • Licht1
  • 170
    • 0041576708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • unpublished manuscript, on file with the author
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 634. One study even finds that foreign firms that had listed only their depositary receipts in the bulletin board market in the U.S. experience significant positive returns when they upgrade from this OTC market to the NASDAQ market and, as a consequence, become "reporting" companies subject to the SEC's mandatory disclosure system. See Darius Miller, Why Do Foreign Firms List in the United States: An Empirical Analysis of the Depositary Receipt Market (1996) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the author) (cited in Licht, supra note 107, at 634). The importance of this finding is that these issuers had already overcome market segmentation by establishing an ADR facility, but had not yet become subject to U.S. mandatory disclosure rules. See SEC Rule 12g3- 2(b), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2 (1998) (providing exemption for such foreign issuers upon filing of home country financial statements). Thus, the upgrade isolates the impact of the differential between SEC reporting requirements and home country requirements.
    • (1996) Why Do Foreign Firms List in the United States: An Empirical Analysis of the Depositary Receipt Market
    • Miller, D.1
  • 171
    • 0042077835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 107
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 634. One study even finds that foreign firms that had listed only their depositary receipts in the bulletin board market in the U.S. experience significant positive returns when they upgrade from this OTC market to the NASDAQ market and, as a consequence, become "reporting" companies subject to the SEC's mandatory disclosure system. See Darius Miller, Why Do Foreign Firms List in the United States: An Empirical Analysis of the Depositary Receipt Market (1996) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the author) (cited in Licht, supra note 107, at 634). The importance of this finding is that these issuers had already overcome market segmentation by establishing an ADR facility, but had not yet become subject to U.S. mandatory disclosure rules. See SEC Rule 12g3-2(b), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2 (1998) (providing exemption for such foreign issuers upon filing of home country financial statements). Thus, the upgrade isolates the impact of the differential between SEC reporting requirements and home country requirements.
    • Licht1
  • 172
    • 4243488235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.-Israel Transactions Présent Unique Issue
    • Apr. 27
    • See Ira M. Greenstein and Lloyd Harmetz, U.S.-Israel Transactions Présent Unique Issue, N.Y. L.J.,Apr. 27, 1998, at S2.
    • (1998) N.Y. L.J.
    • Greenstein, I.M.1    Harmetz, L.2
  • 173
    • 0042578896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beating Their Swords into IPO Shares
    • June 1, at 93
    • See Richard Rappaport, Beating Their Swords Into IPO Shares, FORBES ASAP, June 1, 1998, at 93.
    • (1998) Forbes ASAP
    • Rappaport, R.1
  • 174
    • 0041576768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. NASDAQ Wants Share of Israeli Privatization
    • Apr. 16, LEXIS, News Library, Curnws file
    • See U.S. NASDAQ Wants Share of Israeli Privatization, REUTER EUR. BUS. REP., Apr. 16, 1997, available in LEXIS, News Library, Curnws file (quoting Frank Zarb, chief executive officer of the NASD).
    • (1997) Reuter Eur. Bus. Rep.
  • 175
    • 0042578903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 117
    • See Rappaport, supra note 117, at 93. Some 12 Israeli IPOs were effected in 1996 in the United States, more than those of any other foreign country.
    • Rappaport1
  • 176
    • 0041576682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 106
    • See Pachter, supra note 106. In 1997, foreign registrants raised $28 billion in U.S. capital markets - 16 times the 1990 level. See id.
    • Pachter1
  • 177
    • 0041576670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Year End Review: Latin America Markets
    • Jan. 12
    • For example, in 1997, TV Azteca effected a $650 million IPO (as part of a privatization) through Bear Stearns. See Robinson, Year End Review: Latin America Markets, INVESTMENT DEALERS' DIG., Jan. 12, 1998, at 43.
    • (1998) Investment Dealers' Dig. , pp. 43
    • Robinson1
  • 178
    • 0042578904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 107, at 635-36
    • See Licht, supra note 107, at 635-36 (making this point that prior commentary had focused only on competition among different legal regimes and overlooked the possibility of complementary and mutually reinforcing interaction).
    • Licht1
  • 179
    • 0000834617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Market Value of Control in Publicly-Traded Corporations
    • Controlling premiums in Israel appear to be the second highest in the Western world (second to only those in Italy), thereby suggesting that minority protections are limited. See Ronald Lease et al., The Market Value of Control in Publicly-Traded Corporations, 11 J. FIN. ECON. 439 (1982); Macey, supra note 53, at 684.
    • (1982) J. Fin. Econ. , vol.11 , pp. 439
    • Lease, R.1
  • 180
    • 0000834617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 53
    • Controlling premiums in Israel appear to be the second highest in the Western world (second to only those in Italy), thereby suggesting that minority protections are limited. See Ronald Lease et al., The Market Value of Control in Publicly-Traded Corporations, 11 J. FIN. ECON. 439 (1982); Macey, supra note 53, at 684.
    • Macey1
  • 181
    • 0042578849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 57
    • See Pagano et al., supra note 57, at 61.
    • Pagano1
  • 182
    • 0042578893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 36. In the U.S., venture capital backed firms go public after an average period of five years. See id.
    • See id. at 36. In the U.S., venture capital backed firms go public after an average period of five years. See id.
  • 183
    • 84982606850 scopus 로고
    • Going Public in the 1980's: Evidence from Sweden
    • See Kristian Rydqvist & Kenneth Hogholm, Going Public in the 1980's: Evidence from Sweden, 1 EUR. FIN. MGMT. 287, 309 (1995).
    • (1995) Eur. Fin. Mgmt. , vol.1 , pp. 287
    • Rydqvist, K.1    Hogholm, K.2
  • 184
    • 0041576689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 57, at 36
    • See Pagano et al., supra note 57, at 36.
    • Pagano1
  • 185
    • 0041576687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 57, at 29
    • For just this explanation, see Pagano et al., supra note 57, at 29.
    • Pagano1
  • 186
    • 0043079600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Germany Reaping the Rewards of Risk Taking
    • Aug., 11
    • In August 1998, SAP, the fourth largest German company in terms of market capitalization, listed on the New York Stock Exchange. See Corporate Germany Reaping the Rewards of Risk Taking, FIN. TIMES, Aug., 11, 1998, at 20. Hoechst, the German chemical and pharmaceutical giant, has also recently listed. See Survey-German Banking and Finance 1998: A Unique Perspective, FIN. TIMES, June 24, 1998, at 7. Finally, Siemens AG, the largest German industrial corporation next to Daimler, has indicated its intent to shift to U.S. GAAP by 2000 and list on the New York Stock Exchange by 2001. See Nicholas Bray, International Accounting Rules Catch On, WALL ST. J., Oct. 21, 1998, at B19D.
    • (1998) Fin. Times , pp. 20
  • 187
    • 0043079620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Survey-German Banking and Finance 1998: A Unique Perspective
    • June 24
    • In August 1998, SAP, the fourth largest German company in terms of market capitalization, listed on the New York Stock Exchange. See Corporate Germany Reaping the Rewards of Risk Taking, FIN. TIMES, Aug., 11, 1998, at 20. Hoechst, the German chemical and pharmaceutical giant, has also recently listed. See Survey-German Banking and Finance 1998: A Unique Perspective, FIN. TIMES, June 24, 1998, at 7. Finally, Siemens AG, the largest German industrial corporation next to Daimler, has indicated its intent to shift to U.S. GAAP by 2000 and list on the New York Stock Exchange by 2001. See Nicholas Bray, International Accounting Rules Catch On, WALL ST. J., Oct. 21, 1998, at B19D.
    • (1998) Fin. Times , pp. 7
  • 188
    • 26144459255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Accounting Rules Catch On
    • Oct. 21
    • In August 1998, SAP, the fourth largest German company in terms of market capitalization, listed on the New York Stock Exchange. See Corporate Germany Reaping the Rewards of Risk Taking, FIN. TIMES, Aug., 11, 1998, at 20. Hoechst, the German chemical and pharmaceutical giant, has also recently listed. See Survey-German Banking and Finance 1998: A Unique Perspective, FIN. TIMES, June 24, 1998, at 7. Finally, Siemens AG, the largest German industrial corporation next to Daimler, has indicated its intent to shift to U.S. GAAP by 2000 and list on the New York Stock Exchange by 2001. See Nicholas Bray, International Accounting Rules Catch On, WALL ST. J., Oct. 21, 1998, at B19D.
    • (1998) Wall St. J.
    • Bray, N.1
  • 189
    • 0041576773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 53
    • See Macey, supra note 53, at 692 (small Italian firms "unlikely to survive European unification").
    • Macey1
  • 190
    • 0042052427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arbeitspapier No. 68, Universitat Osnabruck
    • See Theodor Baums, Corporate Contracting around Defective Regulations: The Daimler-Chrysler Case (Arbeitspapier No. 68, Universitat Osnabruck, 1998) (noting that some commercial registers in Germany will not register transnational mergers and others will). Or, as one of Chrysler's senior corporate attorneys observed (seemingly ruefully): "There's no such thing in German law as a merger between a German company and a non-German company." Bar Talk: The Gamma Project: The Marriage of Chrysler and Daimler, AM. LAW., June, 1998, at 13 (quoting Meredith Brown of Debevoise & Plimpton).
    • (1998) Corporate Contracting Around Defective Regulations: The Daimler-Chrysler Case
    • Baums, T.1
  • 191
    • 0042578841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bar Talk: The Gamma Project: The Marriage of Chrysler and Daimler
    • June, quoting Meredith Brown of Debevoise & Plimpton
    • See Theodor Baums, Corporate Contracting around Defective Regulations: The Daimler- Chrysler Case (Arbeitspapier No. 68, Universitat Osnabruck, 1998) (noting that some commercial registers in Germany will not register transnational mergers and others will). Or, as one of Chrysler's senior corporate attorneys observed (seemingly ruefully): "There's no such thing in German law as a merger between a German company and a non-German company." Bar Talk: The Gamma Project: The Marriage of Chrysler and Daimler, AM. LAW., June, 1998, at 13 (quoting Meredith Brown of Debevoise & Plimpton).
    • (1998) Am. Law. , pp. 13
  • 192
    • 0041576678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 131
    • See Baums, supra note 131, at 6-8. Indeed, mergers appear to be rarely used as an acquisition method in Germany. See DIETER BEINERT, CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS & MERGERS IN GERMANY 48 (1991). Instead, acquisitions are chiefly accomplished through share or asset purchases. See id. at 45.
    • Baums1
  • 193
    • 0043079540 scopus 로고
    • See Baums, supra note 131, at 6-8. Indeed, mergers appear to be rarely used as an acquisition method in Germany. See DIETER BEINERT, CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS & MERGERS IN GERMANY 48 (1991). Instead, acquisitions are chiefly accomplished through share or asset purchases. See id. at 45.
    • (1991) Corporate Acquisitions & Mergers in Germany , pp. 48
    • Beinert, D.1
  • 194
    • 0041576761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 132, at 87-88
    • Under the Co-Determination Act (Mitbestimmungengesetz) of 1976, the supervisory board of a German corporation (including both AGs and GmbHs) that employs more than two thousand employees must consist of an equal number of shareholders' representatives and labor representatives. See BEINERT, supra note 132, at 87-88. Other co-determination statutes apply to certain smaller companies having more than five hundred employees. See id. Where a controlling foreign parent holds the stock of the German company, the same basic rules apply and codetermination is required if the subsidiary employs over two thousand workers. See THE GERMAN CO-DETERMINATION ACT 23 (Hannes Schneider & David Kingman eds., 1976).
    • Beinert1
  • 195
    • 0042578905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 57
    • For the finding that Italian corporations needed a substantial business history (on average 33 years) before they could effect a successful IPO, see Pagano et al., supra note 57.
    • Pagano1
  • 196
    • 25344432714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Ford-Volvo': A Deal for All Sweden
    • Jan. 30
    • Ford's acquisition of Volvo's automobile assets is another case in point. Volvo's shareholders were adamant that they preferred Ford to Fiat or Renault, the two other most likely merger candidates. See Edmund Andrews, 'Ford-Volvo': A Deal For All Sweden, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 30, 1999, at C5. Renault shares were particularly resisted by Swedish shareholders, because it was viewed as a statecontrolled company, which was unlikely to maximize the share value of Volvo or provide Swedish stockholders with a liquid investment vehicle. See id. at C5.
    • (1999) N.Y. Times
    • Andrews, E.1
  • 197
    • 0042578900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 27
    • See Gilson, supra note 27.
    • Gilson1
  • 198
    • 84937314069 scopus 로고
    • Top Executive Rewards and Firm Performance: A Comparison of Japan and the U.S
    • See Steven N. Kaplan, Top Executive Rewards and Firm Performance: A Comparison of Japan and the U.S., 102 J. POL. ECON. 510 (1994); Steven N. Kaplan, Top Executive Turnover and Firm Performance in Germany, 10 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 142 (1994); Steven N. Kaplan & Bernadette A. Minton, Appointments of Outsiders to Japanese Boards: Determinants and Implications for Managers, 36 J. FIN. ECON. 224 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.102 , pp. 510
    • Kaplan, S.N.1
  • 199
    • 77958402161 scopus 로고
    • Top Executive Turnover and Firm Performance in Germany
    • See Steven N. Kaplan, Top Executive Rewards and Firm Performance: A Comparison of Japan and the U.S., 102 J. POL. ECON. 510 (1994); Steven N. Kaplan, Top Executive Turnover and Firm Performance in Germany, 10 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 142 (1994); Steven N. Kaplan & Bernadette A. Minton, Appointments of Outsiders to Japanese Boards: Determinants and Implications for Managers, 36 J. FIN. ECON. 224 (1994).
    • (1994) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.10 , pp. 142
    • Kaplan, S.N.1
  • 200
    • 43949159746 scopus 로고
    • Appointments of Outsiders to Japanese Boards: Determinants and Implications for Managers
    • See Steven N. Kaplan, Top Executive Rewards and Firm Performance: A Comparison of Japan and the U.S., 102 J. POL. ECON. 510 (1994); Steven N. Kaplan, Top Executive Turnover and Firm Performance in Germany, 10 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 142 (1994); Steven N. Kaplan & Bernadette A. Minton, Appointments of Outsiders to Japanese Boards: Determinants and Implications for Managers, 36 J. FIN. ECON. 224 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Fin. Econ. , vol.36 , pp. 224
    • Kaplan, S.N.1    Minton, B.A.2
  • 201
    • 0042578822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of the recent cross-border mergers, only Deutsche Bank's bid for Bankers Trust has been for cash, and revealingly Deutsche Bank is not listed on the New York Stock Exchange. Also, its acquisition of Bankers Trust is for approximately $9 billion and thus within its financial limits. Larger takeovers in the range of the Amoco-B.P., Exxon-Mobil or Daimler-Chrysler transactions would be extremely difficult to finance for cash
    • Of the recent cross-border mergers, only Deutsche Bank's bid for Bankers Trust has been for cash, and revealingly Deutsche Bank is not listed on the New York Stock Exchange. Also, its acquisition of Bankers Trust is for approximately $9 billion and thus within its financial limits. Larger takeovers in the range of the Amoco-B.P., Exxon-Mobil or Daimler-Chrysler transactions would be extremely difficult to finance for cash.
  • 202
    • 0041576753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is because it can issue listed shares that will be the functional equivalent of cash
    • This is because it can issue listed shares that will be the functional equivalent of cash.
  • 203
    • 4243799480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Germans Reject Challenge to Daimler Stock Options
    • Aug. 13
    • It is estimated that former Chrysler shareholders will receive 44% of the stock in the merged entity. See John Tagliabue, Germans Reject Challenge to Daimler Stock Options, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 13, 1998, at D4. In addition, American institutional investors may have already held significant stakes in Daimler, thus raising at least the possibility that American shareholders may own a majority of the merged entity.
    • (1998) N.Y. Times
    • Tagliabue, J.1
  • 204
    • 0042578844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is also possible that this feature was a major attraction of the merger to Daimler management because it freed them from the supervision of their controlling shareholder
    • It is also possible that this feature was a major attraction of the merger to Daimler management because it freed them from the supervision of their controlling shareholder.
  • 205
    • 0042578898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 44-46 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 44-46 and accompanying text.
  • 206
    • 0042578845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While Deutsche Bank's supervision of Daimler hardly amounted to an "iron hand" rule, the Daimler-Chrysler merger did dilute its stake to 15%, which seems below the level sufficient to confer control
    • While Deutsche Bank's supervision of Daimler hardly amounted to an "iron hand" rule, the Daimler-Chrysler merger did dilute its stake to 15%, which seems below the level sufficient to confer control.
  • 207
    • 0043079550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 112-15 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 112-15 and accompanying text.
  • 208
    • 0041576760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 140
    • See Tagliabue, supra note 140.
    • Tagliabue1
  • 209
    • 0041576692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 210
    • 0043079595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daimler's own CEO was estimated to have been paid between $1.1 and $1.5 million during this same year. See id.
    • Daimler's own CEO was estimated to have been paid between $1.1 and $1.5 million during this same year. See id.
  • 211
    • 0041024212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • American-Style Pay Moves Abroad; Importance of Stock Options Expands in a Global Economy
    • Sept. 3
    • See David Johnston, American-Style Pay Moves Abroad; Importance of Stock Options Expands in a Global Economy, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 3, 1998, at C1. It can be debated whether the new German system for stock options through the conversion of debentures that are sold only to management represents an example of "functional convergence" or "formal convergence," but either way German courts have upheld the practice.
    • (1998) N.Y. Times
    • Johnston, D.1
  • 212
    • 0043079597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Essentially, foreign issuers that have more than 300 shareholders of record in the United States are in theory required to register under § 12(g) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. However, an exemptive rule affords them an easy escape from the U.S. periodic disclosure system so long as they agree to provide the SEC with the same documents and information that they file in their home countries or give their shareholders. See Rule 12g3-2(b), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2 (1998). This exemption is ended, however, once the foreign issuer lists on NASDAQ. See Rule 12g3-2(d), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2 (1998). Listing on an exchange requires the foreign issuer to register under §12(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, and Rule 12g3-2 thereby becomes inapplicable. See also infra notes 178-79 and accompanying text.
  • 213
    • 0043079598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36, at 1048-1100
    • A historical consensus exists that the Securities Act of 1933 was largely modeled after a British statute. Professor Mahoney has argued that the original intent of both the British Parliament and the American Congress was to force promoters to disclose self-dealing relationships with the firm. See Mahoney, supra note 36, at 1048-1100. Professor Mahoney argues that the federal mandatory disclosure system was "an incremental change from a longstanding set of judicial doctrines that were designed to combat a specific agency problem - the promoter problem." Id. at 1111. Related agency problems arise whenever there is a controlling shareholder, as there typically is in legal regimes characterized by concentrated ownership.
    • Mahoney1
  • 214
    • 0042077828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1049, 1111
    • See id. at 1049, 1111.
  • 215
    • 0042578886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1111
    • Id. at 1111.
  • 216
    • 0042578885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The statutory command to make a disclosure filing in § 13(d) is fleshed out by Rule 13d-1(a). Rule 13d-1 (b)(1) then permits institutional investors under certain conditions to file a shorter, less burdensome document, known as a Schedule 13G, within 45 days after the conclusion of the calendar year. Sections 13(d) and 13(g) of the Exchange Act do not apply to equity securities of issuers that must file periodic reports only by reason of § 15(d) of the Exchange Act because the issuer made a public offering in the United States. This exemption, however, will not benefit issuers traded in any public market (other than a very small bulletin board market), as § 12(g) will require registration if there are as few as three hundred shareholders resident in the United States.
  • 217
    • 0042578894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 92-93 and accompanying text for the 10% threshold under the Transparency Directive
    • See supra notes 92-93 and accompanying text for the 10% threshold under the Transparency Directive.
  • 218
    • 0043079596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEC Rule 13d-3, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-3 (1998)
    • See SEC Rule 13d-3, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-3 (1998).
  • 219
    • 0041576747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEC Rule 13d-5(b)(i), 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-5 (1998); see also Wellman v. Dickinson, 682 F.2d 355, 362-63 (2d Cir. 1982), cert. denied, 460 U.S. 1069 (1983). No formal or written agreement is necessary to give rise to a § 13(d) group. See SEC v. Savoy Industries Inc., 587 F.2d 1149, 1162-63 (D.C. Cir. 1978), cert. denied, 440 U.S. 913 (1979); GAF Corp. v. Milstein, 453 F.2d 709, 715-16 (2d Cir. 1971), cert. denied, 406 U.S. 910 (1972)
    • See SEC Rule 13d-5(b)(i), 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-5 (1998); see also Wellman v. Dickinson, 682 F.2d 355, 362-63 (2d Cir. 1982), cert. denied, 460 U.S. 1069 (1983). No formal or written agreement is necessary to give rise to a § 13(d) group. See SEC v. Savoy Industries Inc., 587 F.2d 1149, 1162-63 (D.C. Cir. 1978), cert. denied, 440 U.S. 913 (1979); GAF Corp. v. Milstein, 453 F.2d 709, 715-16 (2d Cir. 1971), cert. denied, 406 U.S. 910 (1972).
  • 220
    • 0042077821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rule 13d-2, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-2 (1998). For a discussion of this "promptness" requirement, see SEC Litigation Release No. 12835 (April 11, 1991), SEC v. Edelman, 49 SEC Docket No.12, at 952, 953 (April 23, 1991)
    • See Rule 13d-2, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-2 (1998). For a discussion of this "promptness" requirement, see SEC Litigation Release No. 12835 (April 11, 1991), SEC v. Edelman, 49 SEC Docket No.12, at 952, 953 (April 23, 1991).
  • 221
    • 0042077824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 13(d)(1), 15 U.S.C. § 78m(d)(1) (1994); see also Schedule 13D, Items 2-6,17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-101 (1998)
    • See Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 13(d)(1), 15 U.S.C. § 78m(d)(1) (1994); see also Schedule 13D, Items 2-6,17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-101 (1998).
  • 223
    • 0042077770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 159, § 7.02, at 7-4
    • See American Depository Receipts Securities Act Release No. 6894, 56 Fed. Reg. 24,420 (1991) (the "ADR Concept Release"); see also Greene et al., supra note 159, § 7.02, at 7-4.
    • Greene1
  • 224
    • 0041576691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 159, § 7.02, at 7-5 n.8
    • See SEC Filing of Schedules 13D and 13G, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-1(b)(2) (1998). Although technically the Schedule 13G is only available to U.S. institutional investors (and only under certain conditions), a series of no-action letters have permitted foreign institutional investors to use this simplified form. See Greene et al., supra note 159, § 7.02, at 7-5 n.8.
    • Greene1
  • 225
    • 0043079551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a 1990 Concept Release, the SEC proposed exempting foreign bidders from the procedural and disclosure provisions of the Williams Act where (1) the target was a foreign corporation, and (2) 10% or less of the target's outstanding shares were held of record by U.S. shareholders (other than U.S. citizens who were 10% or greater shareholders). See Concept Release on Multinational Tender and Exchange Offers, Securities Act Release No. 33-6866, 55 Fed. Reg. 23, 75 (1990). The SEC also indicated that the civil liability provisions in § 14(e) of the Exchange Act would continue to apply. The SEC has recently moved to implement this proposal. See Cross-Border Tender Offers Business Combinations and Rights Offerings, Securities Act Release No. 7611, 63 Fed. Reg. 69,136 (1998). Even if it were adopted, the proposed 10% threshold would leave most large multinational firms listed on the NYSE fully subject to U.S. tender offer law, because U.S. ownership would exceed 10%.
  • 226
    • 0041576690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEC Equal Treatment of Security Holders, 17 C.F.R. § 240.14d-10 (1998)
    • See SEC Equal Treatment of Security Holders, 17 C.F.R. § 240.14d-10 (1998).
  • 227
    • 0041576746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The SEC has long used an eight-factor test to determine whether closely-linked purchases amount to a tender offer. See SEC v. Carter Hawley Hale Stores, Inc., 760 F.2d 945, 949-52 (9th Cir. 1985); Wellman v. Dickinson, 475 F. Supp. 783, 823-26 (S.D.N.Y. 1979). Under this test, efforts by a controlling shareholder to buy shares from insiders at a common price could give rise to a tender offer with a concomitant obligation under Rule 14d-10 to open the offer to all shareholders
    • The SEC has long used an eight-factor test to determine whether closely-linked purchases amount to a tender offer. See SEC v. Carter Hawley Hale Stores, Inc., 760 F.2d 945, 949-52 (9th Cir. 1985); Wellman v. Dickinson, 475 F. Supp. 783, 823-26 (S.D.N.Y. 1979). Under this test, efforts by a controlling shareholder to buy shares from insiders at a common price could give rise to a tender offer with a concomitant obligation under Rule 14d-10 to open the offer to all shareholders.
  • 228
    • 0041576694 scopus 로고
    • supra note 159, § 7.03(3); see also SEC Release No. 34-27671 Feb. 2
    • For a review of SEC policy toward concurrent foreign and domestic tender offers, see Greene et al., supra note 159, § 7.03(3); see also SEC Release No. 34-27671 (Feb. 2, 1990).
    • (1990)
    • Greene1
  • 229
    • 0041576752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 159, § 7.03[4]
    • See Greene et al., supra note 159, § 7.03[4].
    • Greene1
  • 230
    • 0042077731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some informed commentators have opined that the SEC would today likely take the view that the bidder cannot avoid compliance with the Williams Act by excluding U.S. residents from the offer, at least in the case of an issuer whose equity securities were registered under § 12 of the Exchange Act. See id. § 7.03[4][b],at 7-25
    • Some informed commentators have opined that the SEC would today likely take the view that the bidder cannot avoid compliance with the Williams Act by excluding U.S. residents from the offer, at least in the case of an issuer whose equity securities were registered under § 12 of the Exchange Act. See id. § 7.03[4][b],at 7-25.
  • 231
    • 0041576693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of these requirements, see id. § 2.03[2][b]
    • For an overview of these requirements, see id. § 2.03[2][b].
  • 232
    • 0043079552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NYSE LISTED COMPANY MANUAL §§ 303.00, 310.00(A)
    • See NYSE LISTED COMPANY MANUAL §§ 303.00, 310.00(A).
  • 233
    • 0042578828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ have a common voting rights policy that precludes actions that disenfranchise shareholders of stock traded in their markets or dilutes their voting strength. This policy specifically prohibits any disparate reduction of voting rights through any corporate action or issuance of stock, including plans that cap voting rights for any shareholder or that require a holding period before voting rights become fully exercisable. See Order Granting Approval to Rule Changes Relating to Exchanges' and Associations' Rules Regarding Shareholder Voting Rights, SEC Release No. 34-35121, 59 Fed. Reg. 66,570 (1994)
    • The NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ have a common voting rights policy that precludes actions that disenfranchise shareholders of stock traded in their markets or dilutes their voting strength. This policy specifically prohibits any disparate reduction of voting rights through any corporate action or issuance of stock, including plans that cap voting rights for any shareholder or that require a holding period before voting rights become fully exercisable. See Order Granting Approval to Rule Changes Relating to Exchanges' and Associations' Rules Regarding Shareholder Voting Rights, SEC Release No. 34-35121, 59 Fed. Reg. 66,570 (1994).
  • 234
    • 0043079553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 159, § 2.03[2][b], at 2-21 to 2-23
    • See Greene et al., supra note 159, § 2.03[2][b], at 2-21 to 2-23.
    • Greene1
  • 235
    • 0042077771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 2.03[2][b], at 2-23 to 2-24 (discussing nonwaivable provisions of NYSE corporate governance policies)
    • See id. § 2.03[2][b], at 2-23 to 2-24 (discussing nonwaivable provisions of NYSE corporate governance policies).
  • 236
    • 0041576697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 2.03 [2][c], [d]
    • See id. § 2.03 [2][c], [d].
  • 237
    • 0042077781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rule 13e-3 requires a detailed evaluation of the fairness of the proposed transaction, including a detailed assessment of the material factors upon which the issuer's claim that the transaction is fair is based. See Schedule 13E-3, Item 8(b), 17 C.F.R. § 240.13e-100 (1998). Failing this mandatory disclosure, the transaction can be enjoined or damages sought. There is thus no need to prove a material omission if the specific justifications and evaluation strikes the court as inadequate. See Howing Co. v. Nationwide Corp., 826 F.2d 1470, 1478-79 (6th Cir. 1987)
    • Rule 13e-3 requires a detailed evaluation of the fairness of the proposed transaction, including a detailed assessment of the material factors upon which the issuer's claim that the transaction is fair is based. See Schedule 13E-3, Item 8(b), 17 C.F.R. § 240.13e-100 (1998). Failing this mandatory disclosure, the transaction can be enjoined or damages sought. There is thus no need to prove a material omission if the specific justifications and evaluation strikes the court as inadequate. See Howing Co. v. Nationwide Corp., 826 F.2d 1470, 1478-79 (6th Cir. 1987).
  • 238
    • 0042578850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Among other things, the issuer is required to focus on fairness by describing the purpose of the transaction, the alternatives considered, and the effect of the transaction, including the benefits and detriments to the issuer and affected securities holders. See Schedule 13E-3, Item 7, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13e-100 (1998). If an outside report or valuation is utilized, there must be a summary of the report and information about how the outside party was selected and how the compensation of such party was to be determined. See Schedule 13E-3, Item 9, 17 C.F.R § 240.13e-100 (1998). Most importantly, Item 8 of Schedule 13E-3 requires the issuer (or the affiliate filing the Schedule 13E-3) to state that it "reasonably believes that the Rule 13e-3 transaction is fair or unfair to the unaffiliated security holders" and then requires the issuer or affiliate to "discuss in reasonable detail the material factors upon which the belief. . . is based." Schedule 13e-3, Item 8,17 C.F.R. § 240.13e-100 (1998).
  • 239
    • 0041576698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Santa Fe Indus., Inc. v. Green, 430 U.S. 462, 476 (1997)
    • See Santa Fe Indus., Inc. v. Green, 430 U.S. 462, 476 (1997).
  • 240
    • 0041576699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Howing, 826 F.2d at 1474 (upholding private cause of action under Rule 13e-3), aff'd, 927 F.2d 263 (6th Cir. 1991)
    • See, eg., Howing, 826 F.2d at 1474 (upholding private cause of action under Rule 13e-3), aff'd, 927 F.2d 263 (6th Cir. 1991).
  • 241
    • 0042578880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEC Rule 12g3-2(d)(3), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2(d)(3) (1998)
    • See SEC Rule 12g3-2(d)(3), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2(d)(3) (1998).
  • 242
    • 0041576695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEC Rule 12g3-2(d)(2), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2(d)(2) (1998)
    • See SEC Rule 12g3-2(d)(2), 17 C.F.R. § 240.12g3-2(d)(2) (1998).
  • 243
    • 0041576696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securities Exchange Act of 1934, § 13(b)(2)(A), 15 U.S.C. § 78m(b)(2)(A) (1994)
    • See Securities Exchange Act of 1934, § 13(b)(2)(A), 15 U.S.C. § 78m(b)(2)(A) (1994).
  • 244
    • 0043079555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securities Exchange Act of 1934, § 13(b)(2)B, 15 U.S.C. §78m(b)(2)(B) (1994)
    • See Securities Exchange Act of 1934, § 13(b)(2)B), 15 U.S.C. §78m(b)(2)(B) (1994).
  • 245
    • 0043079554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEC Rule 13b2-1, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13b2-1 (1998)
    • See SEC Rule 13b2-1, 17 C.F.R. § 240.13b2-1 (1998).
  • 246
    • 26144452900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress Passes Bill to Curb International Business Bribery
    • Oct. 22
    • In 1998, Congress approved an international convention sponsored by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) that committed each OECD nation to criminalize such bribery. See Congress Passes Bill to Curb International Business Bribery, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 22, 1998, at A5.
    • (1998) N.Y. Times
  • 247
    • 0042578852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leasco Data Processing Equip. v. Maxwell, 468 F.2d 1326, 1335-37 (2d Cir. 1972)
    • See Leasco Data Processing Equip. v. Maxwell, 468 F.2d 1326, 1335-37 (2d Cir. 1972).
  • 248
    • 0042077773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consolidated Gold Fields PLC v. Minorco, S.A., 871 F.2d 252, 263-63 (2d Cir. 1989), cert. denied 492 U.S. 939 (1989); Bersch v. Drexel Firestone, Inc., 519 F.2d 974, 988-90 (2d Cir. 1975), cert. denied, 423 U.S. 1018 (1975)
    • See Consolidated Gold Fields PLC v. Minorco, S.A., 871 F.2d 252, 263-63 (2d Cir. 1989), cert. denied 492 U.S. 939 (1989); Bersch v. Drexel Firestone, Inc., 519 F.2d 974, 988-90 (2d Cir. 1975), cert. denied, 423 U.S. 1018 (1975).
  • 249
    • 0042077772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Itoba Ltd. v. Lep Group Plc, 54 F.3d 118 (2d Cir. 1996), cert. denied, 516 U.S. 1044 (1996)
    • See Itoba Ltd. v. Lep Group Plc, 54 F.3d 118 (2d Cir. 1996), cert. denied, 516 U.S. 1044 (1996).
  • 250
    • 0042949701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dangerous Extraterritoriality of American Securities Law
    • See generally Stephen J. Choi & Andrew T. Guzman, The Dangerous Extraterritoriality of American Securities Law, 17 Nw. J. INT'L L. & BUS. 207 (1996).
    • (1996) Nw. J. Int'l L. & Bus. , vol.17 , pp. 207
    • Choi, S.J.1    Guzman, A.T.2
  • 251
    • 84933494060 scopus 로고
    • Schoenbaum Revisited: Limiting the Scope of Antifraud Protection in an Internationalized Securities Marketplace
    • See Donald C. Langevoort, Schoenbaum Revisited: Limiting the Scope of Antifraud Protection in an Internationalized Securities Marketplace, 55 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 241, 255-60 (1992).
    • (1992) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.55 , pp. 241
    • Langevoort, D.C.1
  • 252
    • 0042077776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. O'Hagan, 117 S.Ct. 2199, 2206-07 (1997)
    • See United States v. O'Hagan, 117 S.Ct. 2199, 2206-07 (1997).
  • 253
    • 0043079566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As noted earlier, foreign listings on the New York Stock Exchange have recently tripled, over one thousand foreign issuers now trade in U.S. markets, and the trend seems to be increasing. See supra notes 107-10 and accompanying text
    • As noted earlier, foreign listings on the New York Stock Exchange have recently tripled, over one thousand foreign issuers now trade in U.S. markets, and the trend seems to be increasing. See supra notes 107-10 and accompanying text.
  • 254
    • 44649197264 scopus 로고
    • Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure
    • "Bonding" is, of course, a term of art in the standard "agency cost" literature. Essentially, the principal can either "monitor" the agent to reduce inappropriate conduct by the agent, or the agent can "bond" its own conduct, for example, by posting a surety bond or otherwise subjecting itself to penalties. See Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305, 308 (1976).
    • (1976) J. Fin. Econ. , vol.3 , pp. 305
    • Jensen, M.C.1    Meckling, W.H.2
  • 255
    • 0003970307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sept. 10
    • While market segmentation; that is, the existence of barriers to cross-border capital flows, supplies an alternative explanation for multiple and global stock listings, financial economists have recently preferred the bonding explanation. See Oren Furst, A Theoretical Analysis of The Investor Protection Regulations Argument for Global Listing of Stocks (Sept. 10, 1998) (working paper, International Center for Finance at Yale University, on file with the author); see also Blass et al., supra note 114, at 86-87 (noting that high quality Israeli IPOs have preferred to list in the United States on NASDAQ, whereas lower quality IPOs have listed on the Tel Aviv Stock Exchange).
    • (1998) A Theoretical Analysis of the Investor Protection Regulations Argument for Global Listing of Stocks
    • Furst, O.1
  • 256
    • 0043079559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 114, at 86-87
    • While market segmentation; that is, the existence of barriers to cross-border capital flows, supplies an alternative explanation for multiple and global stock listings, financial economists have recently preferred the bonding explanation. See Oren Furst, A Theoretical Analysis of The Investor Protection Regulations Argument for Global Listing of Stocks (Sept. 10, 1998) (working paper, International Center for Finance at Yale University, on file with the author); see also Blass et al., supra note 114, at 86-87 (noting that high quality Israeli IPOs have preferred to list in the United States on NASDAQ, whereas lower quality IPOs have listed on the Tel Aviv Stock Exchange).
    • Blass1
  • 257
    • 0042578856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 124-27 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 124-27 and accompanying text.
  • 258
    • 0042077775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The election to comply with "higher" U.S. standards would, however, have to be irrevocable; otherwise, having sold shares to U.S. investors, foreign issuers might reconsider their election and return to a "lower" disclosure standard
    • The election to comply with "higher" U.S. standards would, however, have to be irrevocable; otherwise, having sold shares to U.S. investors, foreign issuers might reconsider their election and return to a "lower" disclosure standard.
  • 259
    • 0347092229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Portable Reciprocity: Rethinking the International Reach of Securities Regulation
    • See Stephen J. Choi & Andrew T. Guzman, Portable Reciprocity: Rethinking the International Reach of Securities Regulation, 71 S. CAL. L. REV. 903, 941-45 (1998); Merritt Fox, Securities Disclosure in a Globalizing Market: Who Should Regulate Whom?, 95 MICH. L. REV. 2498 (1997).
    • (1998) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 903
    • Choi, S.J.1    Guzman, A.T.2
  • 260
    • 0347092229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securities Disclosure in a Globalizing Market: Who Should Regulate Whom?
    • See Stephen J. Choi & Andrew T. Guzman, Portable Reciprocity: Rethinking the International Reach of Securities Regulation, 71 S. CAL. L. REV. 903, 941-45 (1998); Merritt Fox, Securities Disclosure in a Globalizing Market: Who Should Regulate Whom?, 95 MICH. L. REV. 2498 (1997).
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.95 , pp. 2498
    • Fox, M.1
  • 261
    • 0043079591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 195, at 2618
    • See Fox, supra note 195, at 2618.
    • Fox1
  • 262
    • 0042578854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is Professor Fox's position - he doubts the case for investor protection, but believes mandatory disclosure does improve efficient pricing and allocative efficiency. See id.
    • This is Professor Fox's position - he doubts the case for investor protection, but believes mandatory disclosure does improve efficient pricing and allocative efficiency. See id.
  • 263
    • 21844507244 scopus 로고
    • Corporations, Corporate Law, and Networks of Contracts
    • For a recent discussion of "network externalities" as applied to corporate law, see generally Michael Klausner, Corporations, Corporate Law, and Networks of Contracts, 81 VA. L. REV. 757 (1995).
    • (1995) Va. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 757
    • Klausner, M.1
  • 264
    • 0042077774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is well recognized that a security's "spread" (i.e., the distance between its bid and asked price) tends to narrow as trading volume increases. Greater liquidity allows the market-maker to reduce the price it charges for functioning as a financial intermediary
    • It is well recognized that a security's "spread" (i.e., the distance between its bid and asked price) tends to narrow as trading volume increases. Greater liquidity allows the market-maker to reduce the price it charges for functioning as a financial intermediary.
  • 265
    • 0043079557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for the Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market
    • For a good review of these arguments, see Uri Geiger, The Case for the Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market, 1997 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 241; see also Lawrence J. White, Competition versus Harmonization-An Overview of International Regulation of Financial Services, in INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL MARKETS: HARMONIZATION VERSUS COMPETITION 5, 39 (Claude Barfield ed., 1996).
    • (1997) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , pp. 241
    • Geiger, U.1
  • 266
    • 0347472796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition versus Harmonization-An Overview of International Regulation of Financial Services
    • Claude Barfield ed.
    • For a good review of these arguments, see Uri Geiger, The Case for the Harmonization of Securities Disclosure Rules in the Global Market, 1997 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 241; see also Lawrence J. White, Competition versus Harmonization-An Overview of International Regulation of Financial Services, in INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL MARKETS: HARMONIZATION VERSUS COMPETITION 5, 39 (Claude Barfield ed., 1996).
    • (1996) International Financial Markets: Harmonization Versus Competition , vol.5 , pp. 39
    • White, L.J.1
  • 267
    • 0003922787 scopus 로고
    • The counterargument will predictably be made that an efficient market can discount the legal risks associated with foreign stocks. Although this is highly debatable, it misses the key point about the social waste involved. The available empirical evidence suggests that accounting differences do significantly affect the decisions of participants in the capital markets. See FREDERICK D. S. CHOI AND RICHARD M. LEVICH, THE CAPITAL MARKET EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL ACCOUNTING DIVERSITY 90-98 (1990) (emphasizing costs and social waste involved in attempts to compare issues using different accounting systems). In short, even if the approximate adjustments can be made to share price, the effort is costly and wasteful.
    • (1990) The Capital Market Effects of International Accounting Diversity , pp. 90-98
    • Choi, D.S.1    Levich, R.M.2
  • 268
    • 0000463443 scopus 로고
    • Insider Trading. Liquidity, and the Role of the Monopolist Specialist
    • For a fuller discussion of the likelihood that specialists and market makers would react to the possibility of informed trading by insiders, by widening their spreads, see Lawrence R. Glosten, Insider Trading. Liquidity, and the Role of the Monopolist Specialist, 62 J. BUS. 211 (1989). It is, of course, arguable that only foreign issuers will be subject to such wider spreads, as both dealers and investors discount only these stocks. But this exclusive focus on stock price ignores the impact of tolerating insider trading in some cases on the behavior of potential future inside traders. Once it becomes possible to trade some U.S. listed stocks based on nonpublic, "inside" information, the temptation grows to use such information in the case of domestic issuers as well. In effect, the prohibition loses its moral force, and an increased rate of violations becomes predictable.
    • (1989) J. Bus. , vol.62 , pp. 211
    • Glosten, L.R.1
  • 269
    • 0040921733 scopus 로고
    • The Theory and Practice of Securities Disclosure
    • See Edmund W. Kitch, The Theory and Practice of Securities Disclosure, 61 BROOK. L. REV. 763 (1995) (stressing that disclosure to the market also implies disclosure of proprietary plans to competitors).
    • (1995) Brook. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 763
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 270
    • 0041576703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 51-56 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 51-56 and accompanying text.
  • 271
    • 0347510823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trust in Large Organizations
    • For a fuller discussion of the role of trust in firms, markets, and organizations, see Rafael La Porta et al., Trust in Large Organizations, 87 AM. ECON. REV. 333 (1997).
    • (1997) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.87 , pp. 333
    • La Porta, R.1
  • 272
    • 0042077769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, even a foreign, blockholder-dominated firm whose minority shares trade at a greatly discounted price erodes trust when it enters into a deal or transaction that subsidizes its blockholders at the expense of public shareholders
    • Thus, even a foreign, blockholder-dominated firm whose minority shares trade at a greatly discounted price erodes trust when it enters into a deal or transaction that subsidizes its blockholders at the expense of public shareholders.
  • 273
    • 0041576704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 203
    • This point that disclosure to the market also means disclosure to one's competitors and can result in competitive injuries has been stressed by Professor Edmund Kitch. See Kitch, supra note 203.
    • Kitch1
  • 274
    • 0002696810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inventing a Corporate Monitor for Transitional Economics: The Uncertain Lessons from the Czech and Polish Experiences
    • Klaus Hopt et al. eds.
    • For a review of the very different Czech and Polish experiences with voucher privatization, see John C. Coffee, Jr., Inventing a Corporate Monitor for Transitional Economics: The Uncertain Lessons from the Czech and Polish Experiences, in COMPARATIVE CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: THE STATE OF THE ART AND EMERGING RESEARCH 68-138 (Klaus Hopt et al. eds., 1998).
    • (1998) Comparative Corporate Governance: The State of the Art and Emerging Research , pp. 68-138
    • Coffee J.C., Jr.1
  • 275
    • 0042077767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prague Exchange's Failed Reform Efforts Leaves Some Predicting Its Demise
    • Mar. 17
    • See id. at 111-38. In 1995, the Prague Stock Exchange had 1,716 listings; by early 1999, this number had fallen by more than 80% to 301 listings, and it was estimated that fewer than a dozen of these enjoyed any liquidity. See Peter S. Green, Prague Exchange's Failed Reform Efforts Leaves Some Predicting Its Demise, INT'L HERALD TRIB., Mar. 17, 1999, at 16. Correspondingly, over the same period, the value of an investment in an index of the leading 50 stocks on the Prague Stock Exchange would have fallen by over 60%. See id. (noting decline of PX-50 index from 1,000 to 371). In contrast, the Polish experience appears to have been different and dispersed ownership has been more stable, in part
    • (1999) Int'l Herald Trib. , pp. 16
    • Green, P.S.1
  • 276
    • 0041576700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, state law regulates the simplest forms of fiduciary abuse: unfair self-dealing, excess compensation, usurpation of corporate opportunities. But these forms of misconduct rarely have a material impact on share price, In contrast, federal law more directly regulates corporate control transactions that could more severely injure minority shareholders
    • Of course, state law regulates the simplest forms of fiduciary abuse: unfair self-dealing, excess compensation, usurpation of corporate opportunities. But these forms of misconduct rarely have a material impact on share price, In contrast, federal law more directly regulates corporate control transactions that could more severely injure minority shareholders.
  • 277
    • 0041576705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 37, at 717
    • No other commentator to my knowledge has made this argument, but there is recognition that state corporate law has become virtually uniform across the states. See Carney, supra note 37, at 717. Where variations among states may have greater significance is in reducing transaction costs; this is both outside the fiduciary duty context and largely unaffected by the federal securities laws. Although novel, my thesis has a historical foundation. Professor Mahoney has argued that the original purpose of both the U.S. and U.K. securities laws was to reduce the capacity of promoters and insiders to overreach public shareholders. See Mahoney, supra note 36. In that light, this Article's claim is simply that the SEC has substantially succeeded. For earlier assessments of the requirements of federal securities law that implicitly find them as important as state fiduciary duties in preventing misconduct by controlling persons, see Melvin A. Eisenberg, The Structure of Corporation Law, 89 COLUM. L. REV. 1461, 1483- 85 (1989); Joel Seligman, The New Corporate Law, 59 BROOK. L. REV. 1 (1993).
    • Carney1
  • 278
    • 0041576709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36
    • No other commentator to my knowledge has made this argument, but there is recognition that state corporate law has become virtually uniform across the states. See Carney, supra note 37, at 717. Where variations among states may have greater significance is in reducing transaction costs; this is both outside the fiduciary duty context and largely unaffected by the federal securities laws. Although novel, my thesis has a historical foundation. Professor Mahoney has argued that the original purpose of both the U.S. and U.K. securities laws was to reduce the capacity of promoters and insiders to overreach public shareholders. See Mahoney, supra note 36. In that light, this Article's claim is simply that the SEC has substantially succeeded. For earlier assessments of the requirements of federal securities law that implicitly find them as important as state fiduciary duties in preventing misconduct by controlling persons, see Melvin A. Eisenberg, The Structure of Corporation Law, 89 COLUM. L. REV. 1461, 1483- 85 (1989); Joel Seligman, The New Corporate Law, 59 BROOK. L. REV. 1 (1993).
    • Mahoney1
  • 279
    • 77951819963 scopus 로고
    • The Structure of Corporation Law
    • No other commentator to my knowledge has made this argument, but there is recognition that state corporate law has become virtually uniform across the states. See Carney, supra note 37, at 717. Where variations among states may have greater significance is in reducing transaction costs; this is both outside the fiduciary duty context and largely unaffected by the federal securities laws. Although novel, my thesis has a historical foundation. Professor Mahoney has argued that the original purpose of both the U.S. and U.K. securities laws was to reduce the capacity of promoters and insiders to overreach public shareholders. See Mahoney, supra note 36. In that light, this Article's claim is simply that the SEC has substantially succeeded. For earlier assessments of the requirements of federal securities law that implicitly find them as important as state fiduciary duties in preventing misconduct by controlling persons, see Melvin A. Eisenberg, The Structure of Corporation Law, 89 COLUM. L. REV. 1461, 1483-85 (1989); Joel Seligman, The New Corporate Law, 59 BROOK. L. REV. 1 (1993).
    • (1989) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 1461
    • Eisenberg, M.A.1
  • 280
    • 0041576701 scopus 로고
    • The New Corporate Law
    • No other commentator to my knowledge has made this argument, but there is recognition that state corporate law has become virtually uniform across the states. See Carney, supra note 37, at 717. Where variations among states may have greater significance is in reducing transaction costs; this is both outside the fiduciary duty context and largely unaffected by the federal securities laws. Although novel, my thesis has a historical foundation. Professor Mahoney has argued that the original purpose of both the U.S. and U.K. securities laws was to reduce the capacity of promoters and insiders to overreach public shareholders. See Mahoney, supra note 36. In that light, this Article's claim is simply that the SEC has substantially succeeded. For earlier assessments of the requirements of federal securities law that implicitly find them as important as state fiduciary duties in preventing misconduct by controlling persons, see Melvin A. Eisenberg, The Structure of Corporation Law, 89 COLUM. L. REV. 1461, 1483- 85 (1989); Joel Seligman, The New Corporate Law, 59 BROOK. L. REV. 1 (1993).
    • (1993) Brook. L. Rev. , vol.59 , pp. 1
    • Seligman, J.1
  • 281
    • 0043079563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 33, at 182-84
    • See Daniels, supra note 33, at 182-84 (because Canadian securities administrators could in effect countermand provincial law, charter competition among the provinces has not developed).
    • Daniels1
  • 282
    • 0042578855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, it may be very costly to enforce Section 13(d)'s notion of a voting group against European individuals and firms that form voting alliances without disclosure. See supra notes 155-61 and accompanying text. Still, more visible transactions (such as "going private" transactions or voting rights recapitalizations) could be more easily monitored
    • For example, it may be very costly to enforce Section 13(d)'s notion of a voting group against European individuals and firms that form voting alliances without disclosure. See supra notes 155-61 and accompanying text. Still, more visible transactions (such as "going private" transactions or voting rights recapitalizations) could be more easily monitored.
  • 283
    • 0042578876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the principal contending positions, see supra note 32
    • For the principal contending positions, see supra note 32.
  • 284
    • 0003207194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 195, at 930-34
    • See Choi & Guzman, supra note 195, at 930-34; Roberta Romano, Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation, 107 YALE L.J. 2359 (1998).
    • Choi1    Guzman2
  • 285
    • 0003207194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation
    • See Choi & Guzman, supra note 195, at 930-34; Roberta Romano, Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation, 107 YALE L.J. 2359 (1998).
    • (1998) Yale L.J. , vol.107 , pp. 2359
    • Romano, R.1
  • 286
    • 0042077777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adding further complexity is the fact that there is a third potential source of regulation: the rules of the securities exchange(s) on which the issuer's stock trades. For the moment, this complexity can be deferred
    • Adding further complexity is the fact that there is a third potential source of regulation: the rules of the securities exchange(s) on which the issuer's stock trades. For the moment, this complexity can be deferred.
  • 287
    • 0000821053 scopus 로고
    • Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle
    • See generally Roberta Romano, Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 225 (1985).
    • (1985) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.1 , pp. 225
    • Romano, R.1
  • 288
    • 0042578857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 215, at 2389
    • For Delaware, corporate franchise tax revenue has consistently averaged 16.7% of Delaware's total tax revenues. See Romano, supra note 215, at 2389. The potential tax revenues to the United States (or the SEC) from attracting foreign issuers to list in U.S. markets are trivial by comparison.
    • Romano1
  • 289
    • 0042077778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 82-86 and accompanying text. Of course, under the EC model, each jurisdiction must have disclosure standards meeting some minimum level. Hence, the system is not simply a reciprocal one
    • See supra notes 82-86 and accompanying text. Of course, under the EC model, each jurisdiction must have disclosure standards meeting some minimum level. Hence, the system is not simply a reciprocal one.
  • 290
    • 0042578862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 82
    • For a review of this debate, see Geiger, supra note 82; Lowenstein, supra note 105.
    • Geiger1
  • 291
    • 0043079567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 105
    • For a review of this debate, see Geiger, supra note 82; Lowenstein, supra note 105.
    • Lowenstein1
  • 292
    • 0041576713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 37, at 717
    • See Carney, supra note 37, at 717.
    • Carney1
  • 293
    • 0347803930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Regulatory Competition Theory of Indeterminacy in Corporate Law
    • See Ehud Kamar, A Regulatory Competition Theory of Indeterminacy in Corporate Law, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1908 (1998).
    • (1998) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 1908
    • Kamar, E.1
  • 294
    • 0042077818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 198, at 842-47
    • See id. at 1923-27; see also Klausner, supra note 198, at 842-47.
    • Klausner1
  • 295
    • 0025677813 scopus 로고
    • Herd Behavior and Investment
    • For a general discussion of herding, see David S. Scharfstein & Jeremy C. Stein, Herd Behavior and Investment, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 465 (1990).
    • (1990) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 465
    • Scharfstein, D.S.1    Stein, J.C.2
  • 296
    • 0042077779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 222, at 1923-27
    • See Kamar, supra note 222, at 1923-27.
    • Kamar1
  • 297
    • 84928223137 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Corporate Law in the Theory of the Firm
    • See Barry D. Baysinger & Henry N. Butler, The Role of Corporate Law in the Theory of the Firm, 28 J.L. & ECON. 179 (1985); see also Daniels, supra note 33, at 138-40.
    • (1985) J.L. & Econ. , vol.28 , pp. 179
    • Baysinger, B.D.1    Butler, H.N.2
  • 298
    • 0041576745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 33, at 138-40
    • See Barry D. Baysinger & Henry N. Butler, The Role of Corporate Law in the Theory of the Firm, 28 J.L. & ECON. 179 (1985); see also Daniels, supra note 33, at 138-40.
    • Daniels1
  • 299
    • 0041576710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 32, at 491-98 (1987)
    • See Macey & Miller, supra note 32, at 491-98 (1987); see also Kamar, supra note 222, at 1924.
    • Macey1    Miller2
  • 300
    • 0041576711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 222, at 1924
    • See Macey & Miller, supra note 32, at 491-98 (1987); see also Kamar, supra note 222, at 1924.
    • Kamar1
  • 301
    • 0042578860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 215, at 2361
    • This has been the claim of those who wish to substitute state securities regulation for federal regulation. See Romano, supra note 215, at 2361.
    • Romano1
  • 302
    • 0043079560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition is Hotting Up in the Staid World of the Stock Market
    • London, July 24
    • For recent discussions of the London Stock Exchange's strong competitive position and its recent linkage to the Deutsche Borse, see Meg Carter, Competition is Hotting Up in the Staid World of the Stock Market, TIMES (London), July 24, 1998, at 38; Lea Paterson, Don't Write Off the City Just Yet; News Analysis: London Can Fend Off Attacks on its Financial Leadership, INDEPENDENT (London), June 24, 1998, at 18.
    • (1998) Times , pp. 38
    • Carter, M.1
  • 303
    • 0042578851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Don't Write off the City Just Yet; News Analysis: London Can Fend off Attacks on its Financial Leadership
    • London, June 24
    • For recent discussions of the London Stock Exchange's strong competitive position and its recent linkage to the Deutsche Borse, see Meg Carter, Competition is Hotting Up in the Staid World of the Stock Market, TIMES (London), July 24, 1998, at 38; Lea Paterson, Don't Write Off the City Just Yet; News Analysis: London Can Fend Off Attacks on its Financial Leadership, INDEPENDENT (London), June 24, 1998, at 18.
    • (1998) Independent , pp. 18
    • Paterson, L.1
  • 304
    • 0043079556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 108 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 108 and accompanying text.
  • 305
    • 0041576712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 149-83 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 149-83 and accompanying text.
  • 306
    • 0042578858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two advantages have been recurrently stressed in this Article: (1) securities markets facilitate investment in longer-run, higher risk projects that advance technological growth and productivity, see sources cited supra notes 25, 81; and (2) in a world of consolidating mergers, firms with high stock prices for their public shares are likely to be the survivors
    • Two advantages have been recurrently stressed in this Article: (1) securities markets facilitate investment in longer-run, higher risk projects that advance technological growth and productivity, see sources cited supra notes 25, 81; and (2) in a world of consolidating mergers, firms with high stock prices for their public shares are likely to be the survivors.
  • 307
    • 84928457374 scopus 로고
    • SEC Proposals to Facilitate Multinational Securities Offerings: Disclosure Requirements in the United States and United Kingdom
    • note
    • It seems generally recognized that U.S. disclosure standards are more rigorous than those of any other country with the possible exception of Canada. Even the United Kingdom's standards require less line of business data and do not require discussion of management-identified trends that may affect the firm's future liquidity, capital needs or operating results. See David H. Landau, Note, SEC Proposals to Facilitate Multinational Securities Offerings: Disclosure Requirements in the United States and United Kingdom, 19 N.Y.U. J. INT'L. L. & POL. 457, 459-68 (1987).
    • (1987) N.Y.U. J. Int'l. L. & Pol. , vol.19 , pp. 457
    • Landau, D.H.1
  • 308
    • 0042077780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 200
    • These points have been made in great detail by a number of authors. See Geiger, supra note 200; Joel P. Trachtman, International Regulation Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction, 34 HARV. INT'L L.J. 47, 66-67 (1993); White, supra note 200, at 39.
    • Geiger1
  • 309
    • 85050833168 scopus 로고
    • International Regulation Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction
    • These points have been made in great detail by a number of authors. See Geiger, supra note 200; Joel P. Trachtman, International Regulation Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction, 34 HARV. INT'L L.J. 47, 66-67 (1993); White, supra note 200, at 39.
    • (1993) Harv. Int'l L.J. , vol.34 , pp. 47
    • Trachtman, J.P.1
  • 310
    • 0042578861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 200, at 39
    • These points have been made in great detail by a number of authors. See Geiger, supra note 200; Joel P. Trachtman, International Regulation Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction, 34 HARV. INT'L L.J. 47, 66-67 (1993); White, supra note 200, at 39.
    • White1
  • 311
    • 0041576707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 13, at 12-13
    • Some respond that reduction in agency costs is an illusory efficiency gain, because dispersed ownership is the source of most agency costs. See Bratton & McCahery, supra note 13, at 12-13. This response focuses only on the agency costs of controlling management and ignores the agency costs of preventing non-pro-rata distributions to controlling blockholders. While this issue may well remain theoretically indeterminate, the extraordinary size of control premiums in some European markets, see Zingales, supra note 29, suggests that public shareholders lose more from this form of opportunism than from fiduciary misconduct by management.
    • Bratton1    McCahery2
  • 312
    • 0042578859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 25
    • See Levine & Zervos, supra note 25; Rejan & Zingales, supra note 81. Others have argued that legal underdevelopment prevents a national economy from being able to credibly commit to controlling opportunism and hence retards economic growth. See Demirguc-Kunt & Maksimovic, supra note 7. In this light, migration to foreign securities markets or international securities harmonization can be viewed as a "second-best" but politically feasible solution by which firm growth and national economic prosperity can still be pursued.
    • Levine1    Zervos2
  • 313
    • 0043079565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 81
    • See Levine & Zervos, supra note 25; Rejan & Zingales, supra note 81. Others have argued that legal underdevelopment prevents a national economy from being able to credibly commit to controlling opportunism and hence retards economic growth. See Demirguc-Kunt & Maksimovic, supra note 7. In this light, migration to foreign securities markets or international securities harmonization can be viewed as a "second-best" but politically feasible solution by which firm growth and national economic prosperity can still be pursued.
    • Rejan1    Zingales2
  • 314
    • 0041576706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See Levine & Zervos, supra note 25; Rejan & Zingales, supra note 81. Others have argued that legal underdevelopment prevents a national economy from being able to credibly commit to controlling opportunism and hence retards economic growth. See Demirguc-Kunt & Maksimovic, supra note 7. In this light, migration to foreign securities markets or international securities harmonization can be viewed as a "second-best" but politically feasible solution by which firm growth and national economic prosperity can still be pursued.
    • Demirguc-Kunt1    Maksimovic2
  • 315
    • 0001979512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Which Capitalism? Lessons from the East Asian Crisis
    • For this view (as applied to the Asian financial crisis), see Raghuram G. Rajan & Luigi Zingales, Which Capitalism? Lessons from the East Asian Crisis, 11 J. APPLIED CORP. FIN. 40 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Applied Corp. Fin. , vol.11 , pp. 40
    • Rajan, R.G.1    Zingales, L.2
  • 316
    • 0041576702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEC Rule 3al2-3(b) exempts foreign private issuers from Sections 14(a), 14(b), 14(c), 14(f) and 16 of the 1934 Act. See 17 C.F.R. § 240.3a12-3(b) (1998)
    • SEC Rule 3al2-3(b) exempts foreign private issuers from Sections 14(a), 14(b), 14(c), 14(f) and 16 of the 1934 Act. See 17 C.F.R. § 240.3a12-3(b) (1998).
  • 317
    • 0043079564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.