메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 31, Issue 1, 2001, Pages 13-39

Work and welfare: Towards a post-productivist welfare regime

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0039298651     PISSN: 00071234     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0007123401000023     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (119)

References (157)
  • 1
    • 0003549074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paris: OECD
    • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment (Paris: OECD, 1997). G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States Without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in G. Esping-Andersen, ed., Welfare States in Transition (London: Sage, 1996), pp. 66-87, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). Parallel concerns with how to articulate the demands of paid and unpaid work are reflected in, e.g.: P. England and B. S. Kilbourne, 'Markets, Marriages and Other Mates', in R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, Beyond the Marketplace (New York: de Gruyter, 1990); J. B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books, 1991); and A. R. Hochschild, The Second Shift (New York: Viking, 1989), and The Time Bind (New York: Metropolitan Books, 1997).
    • (1997) Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment
  • 2
    • 0002639368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Welfare states without work: The impasse of labour shedding and familialism in Continental European social policy
    • G. Esping-Andersen, ed., London: Sage
    • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment (Paris: OECD, 1997). G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States Without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in G. Esping-Andersen, ed., Welfare States in Transition (London: Sage, 1996), pp. 66-87, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). Parallel concerns with how to articulate the demands of paid and unpaid work are reflected in, e.g.: P. England and B. S. Kilbourne, 'Markets, Marriages and Other Mates', in R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, Beyond the Marketplace (New York: de Gruyter, 1990); J. B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books, 1991); and A. R. Hochschild, The Second Shift (New York: Viking, 1989), and The Time Bind (New York: Metropolitan Books, 1997).
    • (1996) Welfare States in Transition , pp. 66-87
    • Esping-Andersen, G.1
  • 3
    • 0003817153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Oxford University Press
    • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment (Paris: OECD, 1997). G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States Without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in G. Esping-Andersen, ed., Welfare States in Transition (London: Sage, 1996), pp. 66-87, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). Parallel concerns with how to articulate the demands of paid and unpaid work are reflected in, e.g.: P. England and B. S. Kilbourne, 'Markets, Marriages and Other Mates', in R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, Beyond the Marketplace (New York: de Gruyter, 1990); J. B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books, 1991); and A. R. Hochschild, The Second Shift (New York: Viking, 1989), and The Time Bind (New York: Metropolitan Books, 1997).
    • (1999) Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics
  • 4
    • 0001037702 scopus 로고
    • Markets, marriages and other mates
    • R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, New York: de Gruyter
    • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment (Paris: OECD, 1997). G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States Without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in G. Esping-Andersen, ed., Welfare States in Transition (London: Sage, 1996), pp. 66-87, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). Parallel concerns with how to articulate the demands of paid and unpaid work are reflected in, e.g.: P. England and B. S. Kilbourne, 'Markets, Marriages and Other Mates', in R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, Beyond the Marketplace (New York: de Gruyter, 1990); J. B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books, 1991); and A. R. Hochschild, The Second Shift (New York: Viking, 1989), and The Time Bind (New York: Metropolitan Books, 1997).
    • (1990) Beyond the Marketplace
    • England, P.1    Kilbourne, B.S.2
  • 5
    • 0004048465 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic Books
    • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment (Paris: OECD, 1997). G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States Without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in G. Esping-Andersen, ed., Welfare States in Transition (London: Sage, 1996), pp. 66-87, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). Parallel concerns with how to articulate the demands of paid and unpaid work are reflected in, e.g.: P. England and B. S. Kilbourne, 'Markets, Marriages and Other Mates', in R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, Beyond the Marketplace (New York: de Gruyter, 1990); J. B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books, 1991); and A. R. Hochschild, The Second Shift (New York: Viking, 1989), and The Time Bind (New York: Metropolitan Books, 1997).
    • (1991) The Overworked American
    • Schor, J.B.1
  • 6
    • 0003426702 scopus 로고
    • New York: Viking
    • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment (Paris: OECD, 1997). G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States Without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in G. Esping-Andersen, ed., Welfare States in Transition (London: Sage, 1996), pp. 66-87, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). Parallel concerns with how to articulate the demands of paid and unpaid work are reflected in, e.g.: P. England and B. S. Kilbourne, 'Markets, Marriages and Other Mates', in R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, Beyond the Marketplace (New York: de Gruyter, 1990); J. B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books, 1991); and A. R. Hochschild, The Second Shift (New York: Viking, 1989), and The Time Bind (New York: Metropolitan Books, 1997).
    • (1989) The Second Shift
    • Hochschild, A.R.1
  • 7
    • 0004216482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Metropolitan Books
    • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Making Work Pay: Taxation, Benefits, Employment and Unemployment (Paris: OECD, 1997). G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States Without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in G. Esping-Andersen, ed., Welfare States in Transition (London: Sage, 1996), pp. 66-87, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). Parallel concerns with how to articulate the demands of paid and unpaid work are reflected in, e.g.: P. England and B. S. Kilbourne, 'Markets, Marriages and Other Mates', in R. Friedland and A. F. Robertson, eds, Beyond the Marketplace (New York: de Gruyter, 1990); J. B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books, 1991); and A. R. Hochschild, The Second Shift (New York: Viking, 1989), and The Time Bind (New York: Metropolitan Books, 1997).
    • (1997) The Time Bind
  • 8
    • 85013940141 scopus 로고
    • New York: Rinehart
    • K. Polanyi, The Great Transformation (New York: Rinehart, 1944), Pt. 2; R. M. Titmuss, Social Policy (London: Allen & Unwin, 1974), p. 30. Tellingly, liberal welfare reformers take as their slogan 'making work pay'; see the 1997 OECD publication of that title and the account of recent US reforms in M. J. Bane and D. T. Ellwood, Welfare Realities (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
    • (1944) The Great Transformation
    • Polanyi, K.1
  • 9
    • 0004062990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Allen & Unwin
    • K. Polanyi, The Great Transformation (New York: Rinehart, 1944), Pt. 2; R. M. Titmuss, Social Policy (London: Allen & Unwin, 1974), p. 30. Tellingly, liberal welfare reformers take as their slogan 'making work pay'; see the 1997 OECD publication of that title and the account of recent US reforms in M. J. Bane and D. T. Ellwood, Welfare Realities (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
    • (1974) Social Policy , pp. 30
    • Titmuss, R.M.1
  • 10
    • 0003687156 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
    • K. Polanyi, The Great Transformation (New York: Rinehart, 1944), Pt. 2; R. M. Titmuss, Social Policy (London: Allen & Unwin, 1974), p. 30. Tellingly, liberal welfare reformers take as their slogan 'making work pay'; see the 1997 OECD publication of that title and the account of recent US reforms in M. J. Bane and D. T. Ellwood, Welfare Realities (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
    • (1994) Welfare Realities
    • Bane, M.J.1    Ellwood, D.T.2
  • 11
    • 0004062990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Titmuss, Social Policy, p. 31. Feminists dub this a 'male breadwinner's welfare state'; H. Land, 'The Family Wage', Feminist Review, 6 (1980), 55-77; J. Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', Journal of European Social Policy, 2 (1992), 159-71; N. Fraser, 'After the Family Wage: Gender Equity and the Welfare State', Political Theory, 22 (1994), 591-618; and D. Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
    • Social Policy , pp. 31
    • Titmuss1
  • 12
    • 84925921310 scopus 로고
    • The family wage
    • Titmuss, Social Policy, p. 31. Feminists dub this a 'male breadwinner's welfare state'; H. Land, 'The Family Wage', Feminist Review, 6 (1980), 55-77; J. Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', Journal of European Social Policy, 2 (1992), 159-71; N. Fraser, 'After the Family Wage: Gender Equity and the Welfare State', Political Theory, 22 (1994), 591-618; and D. Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
    • (1980) Feminist Review , vol.6 , pp. 55-77
    • Land, H.1
  • 13
    • 84965905657 scopus 로고
    • Gender and welfare regimes
    • Titmuss, Social Policy, p. 31. Feminists dub this a 'male breadwinner's welfare state'; H. Land, 'The Family Wage', Feminist Review, 6 (1980), 55-77; J. Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', Journal of European Social Policy, 2 (1992), 159-71; N. Fraser, 'After the Family Wage: Gender Equity and the Welfare State', Political Theory, 22 (1994), 591-618; and D. Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
    • (1992) Journal of European Social Policy , vol.2 , pp. 159-171
    • Lewis, J.1
  • 14
    • 84970392097 scopus 로고
    • After the family wage: Gender equity and the welfare state
    • Titmuss, Social Policy, p. 31. Feminists dub this a 'male breadwinner's welfare state'; H. Land, 'The Family Wage', Feminist Review, 6 (1980), 55-77; J. Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', Journal of European Social Policy, 2 (1992), 159-71; N. Fraser, 'After the Family Wage: Gender Equity and the Welfare State', Political Theory, 22 (1994), 591-618; and D. Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
    • (1994) Political Theory , vol.22 , pp. 591-618
    • Fraser, N.1
  • 15
    • 84901892735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Titmuss, Social Policy, p. 31. Feminists dub this a 'male breadwinner's welfare state'; H. Land, 'The Family Wage', Feminist Review, 6 (1980), 55-77; J. Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', Journal of European Social Policy, 2 (1992), 159-71; N. Fraser, 'After the Family Wage: Gender Equity and the Welfare State', Political Theory, 22 (1994), 591-618; and D. Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
    • (1996) Gender, Equality and Welfare States
    • Sainsbury, D.1
  • 16
    • 0000124199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Welfare states and the economy
    • N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Sweden, Esping-Andersen says, practises 'productivist social justice', wherein the 'welfare state invests in optimizing people's capacity to be productive citizens' (G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy', in N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994), pp. 711-32 at p. 722); see further Esping-Andersen, Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. A more formal analysis is set out in K. O. Moene and M. Wallerstein, 'How Social Democracy Worked: Labor-market Institutions', Politics & Society, 23 (1995), 185-212. It should come as no surprise that 'labourist' ideology animates social democratic welfare regimes, given their political roots in labour movements (W. Korpi, The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983); G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985); and F. G. Castles, The Social Democratic Image of Society (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978)).
    • (1994) The Handbook of Economic Sociology , pp. 711-732
    • Esping-Andersen, G.1
  • 17
    • 0003817153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chap. 4
    • Sweden, Esping-Andersen says, practises 'productivist social justice', wherein the 'welfare state invests in optimizing people's capacity to be productive citizens' (G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy', in N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994), pp. 711-32 at p. 722); see further Esping-Andersen, Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. A more formal analysis is set out in K. O. Moene and M. Wallerstein, 'How Social Democracy Worked: Labor-market Institutions', Politics & Society, 23 (1995), 185-212. It should come as no surprise that 'labourist' ideology animates social democratic welfare regimes, given their political roots in labour movements (W. Korpi, The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983); G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985); and F. G. Castles, The Social Democratic Image of Society (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978)).
    • Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 18
    • 84972769953 scopus 로고
    • How social democracy worked: Labor-market institutions
    • Sweden, Esping-Andersen says, practises 'productivist social justice', wherein the 'welfare state invests in optimizing people's capacity to be productive citizens' (G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy', in N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994), pp. 711-32 at p. 722); see further Esping-Andersen, Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. A more formal analysis is set out in K. O. Moene and M. Wallerstein, 'How Social Democracy Worked: Labor-market Institutions', Politics & Society, 23 (1995), 185-212. It should come as no surprise that 'labourist' ideology animates social democratic welfare regimes, given their political roots in labour movements (W. Korpi, The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983); G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985); and F. G. Castles, The Social Democratic Image of Society (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978)).
    • (1995) Politics & Society , vol.23 , pp. 185-212
    • Moene, K.O.1    Wallerstein, M.2
  • 19
    • 0004099437 scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge & Kegan Paul
    • Sweden, Esping-Andersen says, practises 'productivist social justice', wherein the 'welfare state invests in optimizing people's capacity to be productive citizens' (G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy', in N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994), pp. 711-32 at p. 722); see further Esping-Andersen, Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. A more formal analysis is set out in K. O. Moene and M. Wallerstein, 'How Social Democracy Worked: Labor-market Institutions', Politics & Society, 23 (1995), 185-212. It should come as no surprise that 'labourist' ideology animates social democratic welfare regimes, given their political roots in labour movements (W. Korpi, The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983); G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985); and F. G. Castles, The Social Democratic Image of Society (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978)).
    • (1983) The Democratic Class Struggle
    • Korpi, W.1
  • 20
    • 84936628985 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Sweden, Esping-Andersen says, practises 'productivist social justice', wherein the 'welfare state invests in optimizing people's capacity to be productive citizens' (G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy', in N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994), pp. 711-32 at p. 722); see further Esping-Andersen, Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. A more formal analysis is set out in K. O. Moene and M. Wallerstein, 'How Social Democracy Worked: Labor-market Institutions', Politics & Society, 23 (1995), 185-212. It should come as no surprise that 'labourist' ideology animates social democratic welfare regimes, given their political roots in labour movements (W. Korpi, The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983); G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985); and F. G. Castles, The Social Democratic Image of Society (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978)).
    • (1985) Politics Against Markets
    • Esping-Andersen, G.1
  • 21
    • 0004036858 scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge & Kegan Paul
    • Sweden, Esping-Andersen says, practises 'productivist social justice', wherein the 'welfare state invests in optimizing people's capacity to be productive citizens' (G. Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy', in N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994), pp. 711-32 at p. 722); see further Esping-Andersen, Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. A more formal analysis is set out in K. O. Moene and M. Wallerstein, 'How Social Democracy Worked: Labor-market Institutions', Politics & Society, 23 (1995), 185-212. It should come as no surprise that 'labourist' ideology animates social democratic welfare regimes, given their political roots in labour movements (W. Korpi, The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983); G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985); and F. G. Castles, The Social Democratic Image of Society (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978)).
    • (1978) The Social Democratic Image of Society
    • Castles, F.G.1
  • 22
    • 0000124199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A term Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States and the Economy', p. 713) uses in a rather more specific way to characterize the Swedish model, in particular. Note that they all adopt a fairly narrow understanding of what might count as a 'productive' contribution, defining it in terms of paid but not unpaid labour (which is possibly equally productive, in some broader sense).
    • Welfare States and the Economy , pp. 713
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 23
    • 0002005751 scopus 로고
    • Growth and employment: The scope for a European initiative
    • J. H. Drèze and E. Malinvaud, 'Growth and Employment: The Scope for a European Initiative', European Economy (Reports & Studies), No. 1 (1994), 77-106; T. Iversen and A. Wren, 'Equality, Employment and Budgetary Restraint: The Trilemma of the Service Economy', World Politics, 50 (1998), 507-46.
    • (1994) European Economy (Reports & Studies) , vol.1 , pp. 77-106
    • Drèze, J.H.1    Malinvaud, E.2
  • 24
    • 0031905070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Equality, employment and budgetary restraint: The trilemma of the service economy
    • J. H. Drèze and E. Malinvaud, 'Growth and Employment: The Scope for a European Initiative', European Economy (Reports & Studies), No. 1 (1994), 77-106; T. Iversen and A. Wren, 'Equality, Employment and Budgetary Restraint: The Trilemma of the Service Economy', World Politics, 50 (1998), 507-46.
    • (1998) World Politics , vol.50 , pp. 507-546
    • Iversen, T.1    Wren, A.2
  • 25
    • 0003553554 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
    • A. Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1975); Iversen and Wren, 'Equality, Employment and Budgetary Restraint'. Of course, there may not be any need for tradeoffs, insofar as for example state welfare services serve as investments in human capital; see Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy' and A. B. Atkinson, The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1999).
    • (1975) Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff
    • Okun, A.1
  • 26
    • 0039746238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A. Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1975); Iversen and Wren, 'Equality, Employment and Budgetary Restraint'. Of course, there may not be any need for tradeoffs, insofar as for example state welfare services serve as investments in human capital; see Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy' and A. B. Atkinson, The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1999).
    • Equality, Employment and Budgetary Restraint
    • Iversen1    Wren2
  • 27
    • 0039746237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Welfare states and the economy
    • A. B. Atkinson, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press
    • A. Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1975); Iversen and Wren, 'Equality, Employment and Budgetary Restraint'. Of course, there may not be any need for tradeoffs, insofar as for example state welfare services serve as investments in human capital; see Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare States and the Economy' and A. B. Atkinson, The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1999).
    • (1999) The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 28
    • 0003161931 scopus 로고
    • A non-productivist design for social policies
    • P. Van Parijs, ed., London: Verso
    • The term adapted from C. Offe, 'A Non-productivist Design for Social Policies', in P. Van Parijs, ed., Arguing for Basic Income (London: Verso, 1992), pp. 61-80. My 'post-productivist' phrasing seems to get their emphasis more nearly right: post-productivists are not opposed, or even indifferent, to economic output (as the 'non-productivist' formulation might seem to imply); they have simply 'gotten over' being utterly fixated on it, as productivists have been (something the 'post-productivist' phrasing seems better at capturing).
    • (1992) Arguing for Basic Income , pp. 61-80
    • Offe, C.1
  • 29
    • 85013944589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To embrace what Esping-Andersen intended as an unflattering description of Continental European practices, when writing about 'Welfare states without work'.
  • 31
    • 0039153787 scopus 로고
    • Is there (or should there be) a right to work?
    • A. Gutmann, ed., Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Cf. J. Elster, 'Is There (or Should There Be) a Right to Work?' in A. Gutmann, ed., Democracy and the Welfare State (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), pp. 52-78.
    • (1988) Democracy and the Welfare State , pp. 52-78
    • Elster, J.1
  • 32
    • 0004103770 scopus 로고
    • New York: Columbia University Press
    • S. B. Linder, The Harried Leisure Class (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970); G. Rehn, 'Towards a Society of Free Choice', in J. J. Wiatr and R. Rose, eds, Comparing Public Policies (Wroclaw: Zaklad Narodowy imienia Ossolinskich Wydawnictow Polskiej Akademii Nauk, 1977), pp. 121-57; M. White, Working Hours: Assessing the Potential for Reduction (Geneva: International Labour Organisation, 1987); A. Gorz, Critique of Economic Reason, trans. G. Handyside and C. Turner (London: Verso, 1989); P. Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995).
    • (1970) The Harried Leisure Class
    • Linder, S.B.1
  • 33
    • 0040338207 scopus 로고
    • Towards a society of free choice
    • J. J. Wiatr and R. Rose, eds, Wroclaw: Zaklad Narodowy imienia Ossolinskich Wydawnictow Polskiej Akademii Nauk
    • S. B. Linder, The Harried Leisure Class (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970); G. Rehn, 'Towards a Society of Free Choice', in J. J. Wiatr and R. Rose, eds, Comparing Public Policies (Wroclaw: Zaklad Narodowy imienia Ossolinskich Wydawnictow Polskiej Akademii Nauk, 1977), pp. 121-57; M. White, Working Hours: Assessing the Potential for Reduction (Geneva: International Labour Organisation, 1987); A. Gorz, Critique of Economic Reason, trans. G. Handyside and C. Turner (London: Verso, 1989); P. Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995).
    • (1977) Comparing Public Policies , pp. 121-157
    • Rehn, G.1
  • 34
    • 0039812660 scopus 로고
    • Geneva: International Labour Organisation
    • S. B. Linder, The Harried Leisure Class (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970); G. Rehn, 'Towards a Society of Free Choice', in J. J. Wiatr and R. Rose, eds, Comparing Public Policies (Wroclaw: Zaklad Narodowy imienia Ossolinskich Wydawnictow Polskiej Akademii Nauk, 1977), pp. 121-57; M. White, Working Hours: Assessing the Potential for Reduction (Geneva: International Labour Organisation, 1987); A. Gorz, Critique of Economic Reason, trans. G. Handyside and C. Turner (London: Verso, 1989); P. Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995).
    • (1987) Working Hours: Assessing the Potential for Reduction
    • White, M.1
  • 35
    • 0004246920 scopus 로고
    • trans. G. Handyside and C. Turner London: Verso
    • S. B. Linder, The Harried Leisure Class (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970); G. Rehn, 'Towards a Society of Free Choice', in J. J. Wiatr and R. Rose, eds, Comparing Public Policies (Wroclaw: Zaklad Narodowy imienia Ossolinskich Wydawnictow Polskiej Akademii Nauk, 1977), pp. 121-57; M. White, Working Hours: Assessing the Potential for Reduction (Geneva: International Labour Organisation, 1987); A. Gorz, Critique of Economic Reason, trans. G. Handyside and C. Turner (London: Verso, 1989); P. Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995).
    • (1989) Critique of Economic Reason
    • Gorz, A.1
  • 36
    • 0003895407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • S. B. Linder, The Harried Leisure Class (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970); G. Rehn, 'Towards a Society of Free Choice', in J. J. Wiatr and R. Rose, eds, Comparing Public Policies (Wroclaw: Zaklad Narodowy imienia Ossolinskich Wydawnictow Polskiej Akademii Nauk, 1977), pp. 121-57; M. White, Working Hours: Assessing the Potential for Reduction (Geneva: International Labour Organisation, 1987); A. Gorz, Critique of Economic Reason, trans. G. Handyside and C. Turner (London: Verso, 1989); P. Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995).
    • (1995) Real Freedom for All
    • Van Parijs, P.1
  • 37
    • 0003517108 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • F. Block, Postindustriell Possibilities (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); K. Hinrichs, W. Roche and C. Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition (Philadelphia, Pa: Temple University Press, 1991); B. Jessop, 'The Transition to Post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare State', in R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds, Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State? (London: Routledge, 1994), pp. 13-37; J. Rifkin, The End of Work (New York: Tarcher/Putnam, 1995); C. Offe and R. G. Heinze, Beyond Employment, trans. A. Braley (Oxford: Polity, 1992); C. Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources', in OECD, Social Cohesion and the Globalizing Economy (Paris: OECD, 1997), pp. 81-108.
    • (1990) Postindustriell Possibilities
    • Block, F.1
  • 38
    • 0004131665 scopus 로고
    • Philadelphia, Pa: Temple University Press
    • F. Block, Postindustriell Possibilities (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); K. Hinrichs, W. Roche and C. Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition (Philadelphia, Pa: Temple University Press, 1991); B. Jessop, 'The Transition to Post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare State', in R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds, Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State? (London: Routledge, 1994), pp. 13-37; J. Rifkin, The End of Work (New York: Tarcher/Putnam, 1995); C. Offe and R. G. Heinze, Beyond Employment, trans. A. Braley (Oxford: Polity, 1992); C. Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources', in OECD, Social Cohesion and the Globalizing Economy (Paris: OECD, 1997), pp. 81-108.
    • (1991) Working Time in Transition
    • Hinrichs, K.1    Roche, W.2    Sirianni, C.3
  • 39
    • 0002434635 scopus 로고
    • The transition to post-fordism and the schumpeterian workfare state
    • R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds, London: Routledge
    • F. Block, Postindustriell Possibilities (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); K. Hinrichs, W. Roche and C. Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition (Philadelphia, Pa: Temple University Press, 1991); B. Jessop, 'The Transition to Post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare State', in R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds, Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State? (London: Routledge, 1994), pp. 13-37; J. Rifkin, The End of Work (New York: Tarcher/Putnam, 1995); C. Offe and R. G. Heinze, Beyond Employment, trans. A. Braley (Oxford: Polity, 1992); C. Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources', in OECD, Social Cohesion and the Globalizing Economy (Paris: OECD, 1997), pp. 81-108.
    • (1994) Towards a Post-fordist Welfare State? , pp. 13-37
    • Jessop, B.1
  • 40
    • 0004292341 scopus 로고
    • New York: Tarcher/Putnam
    • F. Block, Postindustriell Possibilities (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); K. Hinrichs, W. Roche and C. Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition (Philadelphia, Pa: Temple University Press, 1991); B. Jessop, 'The Transition to Post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare State', in R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds, Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State? (London: Routledge, 1994), pp. 13-37; J. Rifkin, The End of Work (New York: Tarcher/Putnam, 1995); C. Offe and R. G. Heinze, Beyond Employment, trans. A. Braley (Oxford: Polity, 1992); C. Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources', in OECD, Social Cohesion and the Globalizing Economy (Paris: OECD, 1997), pp. 81-108.
    • (1995) The End of Work
    • Rifkin, J.1
  • 41
    • 0003586390 scopus 로고
    • trans. A. Braley Oxford: Polity
    • F. Block, Postindustriell Possibilities (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); K. Hinrichs, W. Roche and C. Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition (Philadelphia, Pa: Temple University Press, 1991); B. Jessop, 'The Transition to Post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare State', in R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds, Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State? (London: Routledge, 1994), pp. 13-37; J. Rifkin, The End of Work (New York: Tarcher/Putnam, 1995); C. Offe and R. G. Heinze, Beyond Employment, trans. A. Braley (Oxford: Polity, 1992); C. Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources', in OECD, Social Cohesion and the Globalizing Economy (Paris: OECD, 1997), pp. 81-108.
    • (1992) Beyond Employment
    • Offe, C.1    Heinze, R.G.2
  • 42
    • 0010863471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Towards a new equilibrium of citizens' rights and economic resources
    • OECD, Paris: OECD
    • F. Block, Postindustriell Possibilities (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); K. Hinrichs, W. Roche and C. Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition (Philadelphia, Pa: Temple University Press, 1991); B. Jessop, 'The Transition to Post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare State', in R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds, Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State? (London: Routledge, 1994), pp. 13-37; J. Rifkin, The End of Work (New York: Tarcher/Putnam, 1995); C. Offe and R. G. Heinze, Beyond Employment, trans. A. Braley (Oxford: Polity, 1992); C. Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources', in OECD, Social Cohesion and the Globalizing Economy (Paris: OECD, 1997), pp. 81-108.
    • (1997) Social Cohesion and the Globalizing Economy , pp. 81-108
    • Offe, C.1
  • 43
    • 85013885100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Baltimore, Md: Johns Hopkins University Press
    • Hence post-productivist proposals of 'shorter hours' strategies aimed at spreading employment around; S.A. Levitan and R. S. Belous, Shorter Hours, Shorter Weeks (Baltimore, Md: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1977); cf. G. Therborn, Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others (London: Verso, 1986). See also proposals for 'sabbatical accounts' (Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources') and 'labour coupons' (B. Haminga, 'Demoralizing the Labor Market', Journal of Political Philosophy, 3 (1995), 23-35).
    • (1977) Shorter Hours, Shorter Weeks
    • Levitan, S.A.1    Belous, R.S.2
  • 44
    • 85013885100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Verso
    • Hence post-productivist proposals of 'shorter hours' strategies aimed at spreading employment around; S.A. Levitan and R. S. Belous, Shorter Hours, Shorter Weeks (Baltimore, Md: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1977); cf. G. Therborn, Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others (London: Verso, 1986). See also proposals for 'sabbatical accounts' (Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources') and 'labour coupons' (B. Haminga, 'Demoralizing the Labor Market', Journal of Political Philosophy, 3 (1995), 23-35).
    • (1986) Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others
    • Therborn, G.1
  • 45
    • 85013885100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and 'labour coupons'
    • Hence post-productivist proposals of 'shorter hours' strategies aimed at spreading employment around; S.A. Levitan and R. S. Belous, Shorter Hours, Shorter Weeks (Baltimore, Md: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1977); cf. G. Therborn, Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others (London: Verso, 1986). See also proposals for 'sabbatical accounts' (Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources') and 'labour coupons' (B. Haminga, 'Demoralizing the Labor Market', Journal of Political Philosophy, 3 (1995), 23-35).
    • Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources
    • Offe1
  • 46
    • 85013885100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demoralizing the labor market
    • Hence post-productivist proposals of 'shorter hours' strategies aimed at spreading employment around; S.A. Levitan and R. S. Belous, Shorter Hours, Shorter Weeks (Baltimore, Md: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1977); cf. G. Therborn, Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others (London: Verso, 1986). See also proposals for 'sabbatical accounts' (Offe, 'Towards a New Equilibrium of Citizens' Rights and Economic Resources') and 'labour coupons' (B. Haminga, 'Demoralizing the Labor Market', Journal of Political Philosophy, 3 (1995), 23-35).
    • (1995) Journal of Political Philosophy , vol.3 , pp. 23-35
    • Haminga, B.1
  • 47
    • 84927457318 scopus 로고
    • Full employment, new technology and the distribution of income
    • Hence post-productivist proposals for 'basic income'. See J. E. Meade, 'Full Employment, New Technology and the Distribution of Income', Journal of Social Policy, 13 (1984), 129-46; and Van Parijs, Arguing for Basic Income and Real Freedom for All. A variation on 'basic income' is 'participation income', paid conditionally on participation in some socially-useful activity; see A. B. Atkinson, 'The Case for a Participation Income', Political Quarterly, 67 (1996), 67-70.
    • (1984) Journal of Social Policy , vol.13 , pp. 129-146
    • Meade, J.E.1
  • 48
    • 0039746232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hence post-productivist proposals for 'basic income'. See J. E. Meade, 'Full Employment, New Technology and the Distribution of Income', Journal of Social Policy, 13 (1984), 129-46; and Van Parijs, Arguing for Basic Income and Real Freedom for All. A variation on 'basic income' is 'participation income', paid conditionally on participation in some socially-useful activity; see A. B. Atkinson, 'The Case for a Participation Income', Political Quarterly, 67 (1996), 67-70.
    • Arguing for Basic Income and Real Freedom for All
    • Van Parijs1
  • 49
    • 84937277483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The case for a participation income
    • Hence post-productivist proposals for 'basic income'. See J. E. Meade, 'Full Employment, New Technology and the Distribution of Income', Journal of Social Policy, 13 (1984), 129-46; and Van Parijs, Arguing for Basic Income and Real Freedom for All. A variation on 'basic income' is 'participation income', paid conditionally on participation in some socially-useful activity; see A. B. Atkinson, 'The Case for a Participation Income', Political Quarterly, 67 (1996), 67-70.
    • (1996) Political Quarterly , vol.67 , pp. 67-70
    • Atkinson, A.B.1
  • 51
    • 84934454017 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press, chap. 7
    • One of the things we might, and on any sensible description of the good life should, autonomously choose to do is to render ourselves vulnerable to certain others in certain ways. To argue for autonomy is not to enshrine autarky but rather mutually-chosen interdependencies (R. E. Goodin, Protecting the Vulnerable (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1985), chap. 7).
    • (1985) Protecting the Vulnerable
    • Goodin, R.E.1
  • 52
    • 0004098177 scopus 로고
    • London: Macmillan
    • R. Lindley, Autonomy (London: Macmillan, 1986); G. Dworkin, The Theory and Practice of Autonomy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and T. E. Hill Jr, Autonomy and Self-respect (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). The scope for debate over what constitutes 'real freedom' in respect of 'basic income', for example, can be surmised from Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All; B. Barry, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income', Journal of Political Philosophy, 4 (1996), 242-76; R. van der Veen, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income: Comment on Brian Barry', Journal of Political Philosophy, 5 (1997), 274-86, and 'Real Freedom Versus Reciprocity: Competing Views on the Justice of Unconditional Basic Income', Political Studies, 46 (1997), 140-63.
    • (1986) Autonomy
    • Lindley, R.1
  • 53
    • 0004238267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • R. Lindley, Autonomy (London: Macmillan, 1986); G. Dworkin, The Theory and Practice of Autonomy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and T. E. Hill Jr, Autonomy and Self-respect (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). The scope for debate over what constitutes 'real freedom' in respect of 'basic income', for example, can be surmised from Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All; B. Barry, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income', Journal of Political Philosophy, 4 (1996), 242-76; R. van der Veen, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income: Comment on Brian Barry', Journal of Political Philosophy, 5 (1997), 274-86, and 'Real Freedom Versus Reciprocity: Competing Views on the Justice of Unconditional Basic Income', Political Studies, 46 (1997), 140-63.
    • (1988) The Theory and Practice of Autonomy
    • Dworkin, G.1
  • 54
    • 0003426709 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • R. Lindley, Autonomy (London: Macmillan, 1986); G. Dworkin, The Theory and Practice of Autonomy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and T. E. Hill Jr, Autonomy and Self-respect (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). The scope for debate over what constitutes 'real freedom' in respect of 'basic income', for example, can be surmised from Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All; B. Barry, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income', Journal of Political Philosophy, 4 (1996), 242-76; R. van der Veen, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income: Comment on Brian Barry', Journal of Political Philosophy, 5 (1997), 274-86, and 'Real Freedom Versus Reciprocity: Competing Views on the Justice of Unconditional Basic Income', Political Studies, 46 (1997), 140-63.
    • (1991) Autonomy and Self-respect
    • Hill, T.E.1
  • 55
    • 0003895407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • R. Lindley, Autonomy (London: Macmillan, 1986); G. Dworkin, The Theory and Practice of Autonomy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and T. E. Hill Jr, Autonomy and Self-respect (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). The scope for debate over what constitutes 'real freedom' in respect of 'basic income', for example, can be surmised from Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All; B. Barry, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income', Journal of Political Philosophy, 4 (1996), 242-76; R. van der Veen, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income: Comment on Brian Barry', Journal of Political Philosophy, 5 (1997), 274-86, and 'Real Freedom Versus Reciprocity: Competing Views on the Justice of Unconditional Basic Income', Political Studies, 46 (1997), 140-63.
    • Real Freedom for All
    • Van Parijs1
  • 56
    • 0346880336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Real freedom and basic income
    • R. Lindley, Autonomy (London: Macmillan, 1986); G. Dworkin, The Theory and Practice of Autonomy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and T. E. Hill Jr, Autonomy and Self-respect (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). The scope for debate over what constitutes 'real freedom' in respect of 'basic income', for example, can be surmised from Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All; B. Barry, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income', Journal of Political Philosophy, 4 (1996), 242-76; R. van der Veen, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income: Comment on Brian Barry', Journal of Political Philosophy, 5 (1997), 274-86, and 'Real Freedom Versus Reciprocity: Competing Views on the Justice of Unconditional Basic Income', Political Studies, 46 (1997), 140-63.
    • (1996) Journal of Political Philosophy , vol.4 , pp. 242-276
    • Barry, B.1
  • 57
    • 0346880121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Real freedom and basic income: Comment on brian barry
    • R. Lindley, Autonomy (London: Macmillan, 1986); G. Dworkin, The Theory and Practice of Autonomy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and T. E. Hill Jr, Autonomy and Self-respect (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). The scope for debate over what constitutes 'real freedom' in respect of 'basic income', for example, can be surmised from Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All; B. Barry, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income', Journal of Political Philosophy, 4 (1996), 242-76; R. van der Veen, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income: Comment on Brian Barry', Journal of Political Philosophy, 5 (1997), 274-86, and 'Real Freedom Versus Reciprocity: Competing Views on the Justice of Unconditional Basic Income', Political Studies, 46 (1997), 140-63.
    • (1997) Journal of Political Philosophy , vol.5 , pp. 274-286
    • Van Der Veen, R.1
  • 58
    • 0038901902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Real freedom versus reciprocity: Competing views on the justice of unconditional basic income
    • R. Lindley, Autonomy (London: Macmillan, 1986); G. Dworkin, The Theory and Practice of Autonomy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and T. E. Hill Jr, Autonomy and Self-respect (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). The scope for debate over what constitutes 'real freedom' in respect of 'basic income', for example, can be surmised from Van Parijs, Real Freedom for All; B. Barry, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income', Journal of Political Philosophy, 4 (1996), 242-76; R. van der Veen, 'Real Freedom and Basic Income: Comment on Brian Barry', Journal of Political Philosophy, 5 (1997), 274-86, and 'Real Freedom Versus Reciprocity: Competing Views on the Justice of Unconditional Basic Income', Political Studies, 46 (1997), 140-63.
    • (1997) Political Studies , vol.46 , pp. 140-163
  • 59
    • 84925977154 scopus 로고
    • Freedom and the redistribution of resources
    • If what people lose when they have money taxed away is properly described as 'freedom', then what people gain when that tax money is redistributed to them must be properly describable in those same terms, as well; P. Jones, 'Freedom and the Redistribution of Resources', Journal of Social Policy, 11 (1982), 217-38.
    • (1982) Journal of Social Policy , vol.11 , pp. 217-238
    • Jones, P.1
  • 60
    • 0004238267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dworkin, Theory and Practice of Autonomy, p. 31. This strategy of focusing on negative rather than positive conditions of the good in view parallels that of B. Moore Jr, Reflections on the Causes of Human Misery (Boston, Mass.: Beacon Press, 1970).
    • Theory and Practice of Autonomy , pp. 31
    • Dworkin1
  • 61
    • 0040012679 scopus 로고
    • Boston, Mass.: Beacon Press
    • Dworkin, Theory and Practice of Autonomy, p. 31. This strategy of focusing on negative rather than positive conditions of the good in view parallels that of B. Moore Jr, Reflections on the Causes of Human Misery (Boston, Mass.: Beacon Press, 1970).
    • (1970) Reflections on the Causes of Human Misery
    • Moore, B.1
  • 62
    • 0003463955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism , pp. 21-22
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 63
    • 0000861359 scopus 로고
    • The new property
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • (1964) Yale Law Journal , vol.73 , pp. 733-787
    • Reich, C.A.1
  • 64
    • 0003903846 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, chap. 7
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • (1988) Reasons for Welfare
    • Goodin, R.E.1
  • 65
    • 0040932169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • Gender and Welfare Regimes
    • Lewis1
  • 66
    • 84901892735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • Gender, Equality and Welfare States
    • Sainsbury1
  • 67
    • 0027721822 scopus 로고
    • Gender and the social rights of citizenship: The comparative analysis of gender relations and welfare states
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • (1993) American Sociological Review , vol.58 , pp. 303-328
    • Orloff, A.S.1
  • 68
    • 0040932168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • After the Family Wage
    • Fraser1
  • 69
    • 84937297693 scopus 로고
    • Mothers, citizenship and independence: A critique of pure family values
    • Thus, post-productivists would share the social democratic impetus towards 'decommodification', making people's income streams independent of labour market participation; Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, pp. 21-2. They would also insist that those social benefits should come in the form of welfare rights, rather than discretionary payments; C. A. Reich, 'The New Property', Yale Law Journal, 73 (1964), 733-87, and R. E. Goodin, Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), chap. 7. They would also be anxious that women should have an independent claim in their own right; see Lewis, 'Gender and Welfare Regimes', and Sainsbury, Gender, Equality and Welfare States. This is the sense in which US feminists defend Aid to Families with Dependent Children as a contribution to the autonomy of women; see A. S. Orloff, 'Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States', American Sociological Review, 58 (1993), 303-28; Fraser, 'After the Family Wage'; and I. M. Young, 'Mothers, Citizenship and Independence: A Critique of Pure Family Values', Ethics, 105 (1995), 535-56.
    • (1995) Ethics , vol.105 , pp. 535-556
    • Young, I.M.1
  • 70
    • 0000157686 scopus 로고
    • A theory of the allocation of time
    • G. S. Becker, 'A Theory of the Allocation of Time', Economic Journal, 75 (1965), 493-517; R. J. Zeckhauser, 'Time as the Ultimate Source of Utility', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (1973), 668-75; J. N. Morgan, 'The Role of Time in the Measurement of Transfers and Well-being', in M. Moon, ed., Economic Transfers in the United States (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984), pp. 199-238.
    • (1965) Economic Journal , vol.75 , pp. 493-517
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 71
    • 0001071215 scopus 로고
    • Time as the ultimate source of utility
    • G. S. Becker, 'A Theory of the Allocation of Time', Economic Journal, 75 (1965), 493-517; R. J. Zeckhauser, 'Time as the Ultimate Source of Utility', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (1973), 668-75; J. N. Morgan, 'The Role of Time in the Measurement of Transfers and Well-being', in M. Moon, ed., Economic Transfers in the United States (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984), pp. 199-238.
    • (1973) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.87 , pp. 668-675
    • Zeckhauser, R.J.1
  • 72
    • 0039467643 scopus 로고
    • The role of time in the measurement of transfers and well-being
    • M. Moon, ed., Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • G. S. Becker, 'A Theory of the Allocation of Time', Economic Journal, 75 (1965), 493-517; R. J. Zeckhauser, 'Time as the Ultimate Source of Utility', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (1973), 668-75; J. N. Morgan, 'The Role of Time in the Measurement of Transfers and Well-being', in M. Moon, ed., Economic Transfers in the United States (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984), pp. 199-238.
    • (1984) Economic Transfers in the United States , pp. 199-238
    • Morgan, J.N.1
  • 73
    • 0002748320 scopus 로고
    • The time-poor: A new look at poverty
    • C. Vickery, 'The Time-poor: A New Look at Poverty', Journal of Human Resources, 12 (1977), 27-48. The 'time bind' which preoccupies Americans (Schor, The Overworked American; Hochschild, The Time Bind) is also felt in Britain, where fully a third of male manual workers report that they would prefer to work fewer hours in paid labour than they actually do (M. B. Stewart and J. K. Swaffield, 'Constraints on the Desired Hours of Work of British Men', Economic Journal, 107 (1997), 520-35).
    • (1977) Journal of Human Resources , vol.12 , pp. 27-48
    • Vickery, C.1
  • 74
    • 0003781826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • C. Vickery, 'The Time-poor: A New Look at Poverty', Journal of Human Resources, 12 (1977), 27-48. The 'time bind' which preoccupies Americans (Schor, The Overworked American; Hochschild, The Time Bind) is also felt in Britain, where fully a third of male manual workers report that they would prefer to work fewer hours in paid labour than they actually do (M. B. Stewart and J. K. Swaffield, 'Constraints on the Desired Hours of Work of British Men', Economic Journal, 107 (1997), 520-35).
    • The Overworked American
    • Schor1
  • 75
    • 0004216482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • C. Vickery, 'The Time-poor: A New Look at Poverty', Journal of Human Resources, 12 (1977), 27-48. The 'time bind' which preoccupies Americans (Schor, The Overworked American; Hochschild, The Time Bind) is also felt in Britain, where fully a third of male manual workers report that they would prefer to work fewer hours in paid labour than they actually do (M. B. Stewart and J. K. Swaffield, 'Constraints on the Desired Hours of Work of British Men', Economic Journal, 107 (1997), 520-35).
    • The Time Bind
    • Hochschild1
  • 76
    • 0031430327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constraints on the desired hours of work of British men
    • C. Vickery, 'The Time-poor: A New Look at Poverty', Journal of Human Resources, 12 (1977), 27-48. The 'time bind' which preoccupies Americans (Schor, The Overworked American; Hochschild, The Time Bind) is also felt in Britain, where fully a third of male manual workers report that they would prefer to work fewer hours in paid labour than they actually do (M. B. Stewart and J. K. Swaffield, 'Constraints on the Desired Hours of Work of British Men', Economic Journal, 107 (1997), 520-35).
    • (1997) Economic Journal , vol.107 , pp. 520-535
    • Stewart, M.B.1    Swaffield, J.K.2
  • 77
    • 12244302358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Time, work discipline and industrial capitalism
    • On work time and work discipline, see: E. P. Thompson, 'Time, Work Discipline and Industrial Capitalism', Past & Present, 38 (1967), 36-97; Moishe Postone, 'Necessity, Labour and Time: A Reinterpretation of the Marxian Critique of Capitalism', Social Research, 45 (1978), 739-88; and C. Sirianni, 'The Self-management of Time in Post-industrial Society', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition.
    • (1967) Past & Present , vol.38 , pp. 36-97
    • Thompson, E.P.1
  • 78
    • 12244302358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Necessity, labour and time: A reinterpretation of the Marxian critique of capitalism
    • On work time and work discipline, see: E. P. Thompson, 'Time, Work Discipline and Industrial Capitalism', Past & Present, 38 (1967), 36-97; Moishe Postone, 'Necessity, Labour and Time: A Reinterpretation of the Marxian Critique of Capitalism', Social Research, 45 (1978), 739-88; and C. Sirianni, 'The Self-management of Time in Post-industrial Society', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition.
    • (1978) Social Research , vol.45 , pp. 739-788
    • Postone, M.1
  • 79
    • 12244302358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The self-management of time in post-industrial society
    • Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds
    • On work time and work discipline, see: E. P. Thompson, 'Time, Work Discipline and Industrial Capitalism', Past & Present, 38 (1967), 36-97; Moishe Postone, 'Necessity, Labour and Time: A Reinterpretation of the Marxian Critique of Capitalism', Social Research, 45 (1978), 739-88; and C. Sirianni, 'The Self-management of Time in Post-industrial Society', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition.
    • Working Time in Transition
    • Sirianni, C.1
  • 80
    • 0040338204 scopus 로고
    • Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1990) Social Security in the Netherlands
  • 81
    • 0039153783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1996) The Dutch Welfare State from An International and Economic Perspective
  • 82
    • 0003588542 scopus 로고
    • Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague
    • (1993) The Development of the Dutch Welfare State
    • Cox, R.H.1
  • 83
    • 5844347649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where have all the hours gone? Working-time reduction policies in the Netherlands
    • Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • Working Time in Transition , pp. 129-147
    • De Neubourg, C.1
  • 84
    • 0003067797 scopus 로고
    • The Netherlands: An extreme case
    • M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1991) Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force , pp. 97-126
    • De Vroom, B.1    Blomsma, M.2
  • 85
    • 0028551093 scopus 로고
    • Three worlds of welfare capitalism? The welfare state and the post-industrial trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1994) West European Politics , vol.17 , pp. 166-189
    • Kloosterman, R.C.1
  • 86
    • 84937269652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A miraculous model? Explaining the new politics of the welfare state in the Netherlands
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1997) Acta Politica , vol.23 , pp. 258-280
    • Hemerijck, A.1    Van Kersbergen, K.2
  • 87
    • 0004103764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1997) A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands
    • Visser, J.1    Hemerijck, A.2
  • 88
    • 0009757097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social security and labor force participation in the Netherlands
    • May
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1998) American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings) , vol.88 , Issue.2 , pp. 164-167
    • Kapteyn, A.1    De Vos, K.2
  • 89
    • 0039746231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1999) Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000
    • Van Oorschot, W.1    Engerlfriet, R.2
  • 90
    • 0039746234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • Welfare States Without Work
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 91
    • 0039153784 scopus 로고
    • 's-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid
    • Among Dutch scholars and policy makers, there was much discussion of the causes and consequences of the tendency towards 'early retirement' (which used to be effected largely through 'disability' benefits) and towards reduced working hours (which was in part the consequence of a formal agreement between business, labour and government, the 1982 Wassenaar Accord). See, e.g.: Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands (Deventer: Kluwer Law & Taxation Publishers, 1990); and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective (The Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment, 1996); R. H. Cox, The Development of the Dutch Welfare State (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1993); C. de Neubourg, 'Where Have All the Hours Gone? Working-time Reduction Policies in the Netherlands', in Hinrichs, Roche and Sirianni, eds, Working Time in Transition, pp. 129-47; B. de Vroom and M. Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case', in M. Kohli, M. Rein, A. M. Guillemard and H. van Gunsteren, eds, Time for Retirement: Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 97-126; R. C. Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism? The Welfare State and the Post-Industrial Trajectory in the Netherlands after 1980', West European Politics, 17 (1994), 166-89; A. Hemerijck and K. van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model? Explaining the New Politics of the Welfare State in the Netherlands', Acta Politica, 23 (1997), 258-80; J. Visser and A. Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); A. Kapteyn and K. de Vos, 'Social Security and Labor Force Participation in the Netherlands', American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 88 (No. 2) (May 1998), 164-7; and W. van Oorschot and R. Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work: Labour Market Participation Policies in the Netherlands, 1970-2000' (paper presented to Research Committee 19, International Sociological Association, Prague, September 1999). It is fair to say, however, that most of those authors join Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States Without Work') in bemoaning those tendencies rather than embracing them as leading to a positively-valued post-productivist future. Only the old report by M. Rein and R. Freeman, The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work ('s-Gravenhage: HRWB adviescollege voor sociaal en cultureel beleid, 1988), positively embraces the changes, although even then not in unambiguously post-productivist terms.
    • (1988) The Dutch Choice: A Plea for Social Policy Complementary To Work
    • Rein, M.1    Freeman, R.2
  • 92
    • 0003412755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chap. 14
    • As I have argued elsewhere, on the tax-transfer side of public policy the Netherlands is a close approximation to a social democratic welfare regime; Goodin et al., Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, chap. 14, and R. E. Goodin and A. Smitsman, 'Placing Welfare States: The Netherlands as a Crucial Test Case', Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis, 2 (2000), 39-64. My argument here is that, when you look at the labour-market side of the equation, the Netherlands looks more like a post-productivist regime than an old-fashioned Continental corporatist one - contrary to the claims of Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare Without Work', p. 66, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. Given that this article is a follow-on from earlier collaborations, I ought especially to emphasize that none of my previous co-authors necessarily share any of the views expressed in the present article.
    • Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism
    • Goodin1
  • 93
    • 0039153780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Placing welfare states: The Netherlands as a crucial test case
    • As I have argued elsewhere, on the tax-transfer side of public policy the Netherlands is a close approximation to a social democratic welfare regime; Goodin et al., Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, chap. 14, and R. E. Goodin and A. Smitsman, 'Placing Welfare States: The Netherlands as a Crucial Test Case', Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis, 2 (2000), 39-64. My argument here is that, when you look at the labour-market side of the equation, the Netherlands looks more like a post-productivist regime than an old-fashioned Continental corporatist one - contrary to the claims of Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare Without Work', p. 66, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. Given that this article is a follow-on from earlier collaborations, I ought especially to emphasize that none of my previous co-authors necessarily share any of the views expressed in the present article.
    • (2000) Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis , vol.2 , pp. 39-64
    • Goodin, R.E.1    Smitsman, A.2
  • 94
    • 0004351292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As I have argued elsewhere, on the tax-transfer side of public policy the Netherlands is a close approximation to a social democratic welfare regime; Goodin et al., Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, chap. 14, and R. E. Goodin and A. Smitsman, 'Placing Welfare States: The Netherlands as a Crucial Test Case', Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis, 2 (2000), 39-64. My argument here is that, when you look at the labour-market side of the equation, the Netherlands looks more like a post-productivist regime than an old-fashioned Continental corporatist one - contrary to the claims of Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare Without Work', p. 66, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. Given that this article is a follow-on from earlier collaborations, I ought especially to emphasize that none of my previous co-authors necessarily share any of the views expressed in the present article.
    • Welfare Without Work , pp. 66
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 95
    • 0039746235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chap. 4
    • As I have argued elsewhere, on the tax-transfer side of public policy the Netherlands is a close approximation to a social democratic welfare regime; Goodin et al., Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, chap. 14, and R. E. Goodin and A. Smitsman, 'Placing Welfare States: The Netherlands as a Crucial Test Case', Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis, 2 (2000), 39-64. My argument here is that, when you look at the labour-market side of the equation, the Netherlands looks more like a post-productivist regime than an old-fashioned Continental corporatist one - contrary to the claims of Esping-Andersen, 'Welfare Without Work', p. 66, and Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics, chap. 4. Given that this article is a follow-on from earlier collaborations, I ought especially to emphasize that none of my previous co-authors necessarily share any of the views expressed in the present article.
    • Social Foundations of Post-industrial Economics
  • 96
    • 0003463955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Table 2.2
    • For example, Esping-Andersen's measure of 'social democracy' is a composite of: average universalism of pensions and unemployment benefits; and average benefit equality of pensions, sickness and unemployment benefits. His 'liberalism' indicator combines measures of: means-tested benefits as a proportion of total public social expenditure; private pensions as a proportion of total pensions; and private spending on health as a proportion of the total. And his indicator of 'corporatism' combines the number of occupationally distinct public pension schemes and expenditure on pensions to government employees as a percentage of gross domestic product (GDP). See Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Table 2.2, p. 70.
    • Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism , pp. 70
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 97
    • 84910364096 scopus 로고
    • Political structure, economic development and national social security programs
    • P. Cutright, 'Political Structure, Economic Development and National Social Security Programs', American Journal of Sociology, 70 (1965), 537-50; H. L. Wilensky, The Welfare State and Equality (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975); R. Jackman, Politics and Social Equality (New York: Wiley, 1972); A. Hicks and D. H. Swank, 'Politics, Institutions, and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies', American Political Science Review, 86 (1992), 658-74. These data are famously incomplete, failing to count many things (like tax subsidies of mortgages) that really ought to count, but for the OECD do not, as social welfare transfer payments.
    • (1965) American Journal of Sociology , vol.70 , pp. 537-550
    • Cutright, P.1
  • 98
    • 0003574673 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • P. Cutright, 'Political Structure, Economic Development and National Social Security Programs', American Journal of Sociology, 70 (1965), 537-50; H. L. Wilensky, The Welfare State and Equality (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975); R. Jackman, Politics and Social Equality (New York: Wiley, 1972); A. Hicks and D. H. Swank, 'Politics, Institutions, and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies', American Political Science Review, 86 (1992), 658-74. These data are famously incomplete, failing to count many things (like tax subsidies of mortgages) that really ought to count, but for the OECD do not, as social welfare transfer payments.
    • (1975) The Welfare State and Equality
    • Wilensky, H.L.1
  • 99
    • 0004084494 scopus 로고
    • New York: Wiley
    • P. Cutright, 'Political Structure, Economic Development and National Social Security Programs', American Journal of Sociology, 70 (1965), 537-50; H. L. Wilensky, The Welfare State and Equality (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975); R. Jackman, Politics and Social Equality (New York: Wiley, 1972); A. Hicks and D. H. Swank, 'Politics, Institutions, and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies', American Political Science Review, 86 (1992), 658-74. These data are famously incomplete, failing to count many things (like tax subsidies of mortgages) that really ought to count, but for the OECD do not, as social welfare transfer payments.
    • (1972) Politics and Social Equality
    • Jackman, R.1
  • 100
    • 84971698875 scopus 로고
    • Politics, institutions, and welfare spending in industrialized democracies
    • P. Cutright, 'Political Structure, Economic Development and National Social Security Programs', American Journal of Sociology, 70 (1965), 537-50; H. L. Wilensky, The Welfare State and Equality (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975); R. Jackman, Politics and Social Equality (New York: Wiley, 1972); A. Hicks and D. H. Swank, 'Politics, Institutions, and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies', American Political Science Review, 86 (1992), 658-74. These data are famously incomplete, failing to count many things (like tax subsidies of mortgages) that really ought to count, but for the OECD do not, as social welfare transfer payments.
    • (1992) American Political Science Review , vol.86 , pp. 658-674
    • Hicks, A.1    Swank, D.H.2
  • 101
    • 0040338199 scopus 로고
    • Statistical annex
    • Paris: OECD, Annex Table I
    • Labour-force participation rates are taken from OECD, 'Statistical Annex', Employment Outlook (Paris: OECD, 1995), Annex Table I, pp. 203-29, at p. 214. Social security expenditure as a percentage of GDP circa 1995 is taken from OECD, Historical Statistics, 1960-95 (Paris: OECD, 1997), Table 6.3, p. 71; for New Zealand, omitted from that series, I use 'central government expenditure on social security and welfare' as a percentage of GDP, based on OECD, OECD Economic Surveys 1997-98: New Zealand (Paris: OECD, 1998), Table G, p. 181, and Table C, p. 178.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 203-229
  • 102
    • 0003881906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paris: OECD, Table 6.3
    • Labour-force participation rates are taken from OECD, 'Statistical Annex', Employment Outlook (Paris: OECD, 1995), Annex Table I, pp. 203-29, at p. 214. Social security expenditure as a percentage of GDP circa 1995 is taken from OECD, Historical Statistics, 1960-95 (Paris: OECD, 1997), Table 6.3, p. 71; for New Zealand, omitted from that series, I use 'central government expenditure on social security and welfare' as a percentage of GDP, based on OECD, OECD Economic Surveys 1997-98: New Zealand (Paris: OECD, 1998), Table G, p. 181, and Table C, p. 178.
    • (1997) Historical Statistics, 1960-95 , pp. 71
  • 103
    • 0003939711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paris: OECD, Table G, and Table C
    • Labour-force participation rates are taken from OECD, 'Statistical Annex', Employment Outlook (Paris: OECD, 1995), Annex Table I, pp. 203-29, at p. 214. Social security expenditure as a percentage of GDP circa 1995 is taken from OECD, Historical Statistics, 1960-95 (Paris: OECD, 1997), Table 6.3, p. 71; for New Zealand, omitted from that series, I use 'central government expenditure on social security and welfare' as a percentage of GDP, based on OECD, OECD Economic Surveys 1997-98: New Zealand (Paris: OECD, 1998), Table G, p. 181, and Table C, p. 178.
    • (1998) OECD Economic Surveys 1997-98: New Zealand , pp. 181
  • 104
    • 85013954445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Those cutoffs were chosen less to generate exactly the same number of countries in each category (the breakdown is 7/11 on both dimensions) and more to 'carve nature at its joints', maximizing consonance of the resulting Figure 1 with the standard categorizations of countries into regime clusters.
  • 105
    • 0003463955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Table 3.3
    • That is to say, according to the original categorization in Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Table 3.3, p. 74. There has since been much dissent, of course, and Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States and the Economy') has himself conceded the need for some adjustments.
    • Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism , pp. 74
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 106
    • 0000124199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • That is to say, according to the original categorization in Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Table 3.3, p. 74. There has since been much dissent, of course, and Esping-Andersen ('Welfare States and the Economy') has himself conceded the need for some adjustments.
    • Welfare States and the Economy
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 107
    • 0003463955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Also in that cell are New Zealand, the United Kingdom - which Esping-Andersen (Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, p. 74) regards as impure cases - and (more anomalously) Norway, which he classifies as classically social democratic. Norway's social spending is very substantially below that of the other Scandinavian countries, however, which unambiguously forces it into the top-right cell in terms of this classificatory scheme.
    • Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism , pp. 74
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 108
    • 84936628985 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Among Esping-Andersen's strongly social democratic countries, this leaves out only Norway (as discussed in the previous note) and the Netherlands, which Esping-Andersen has never been comfortable regarding as social democratic. See G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985), p. 145, and 'Welfare States Without Work', p. 66.
    • (1985) Politics Against Markets , pp. 145
    • Esping-Andersen, G.1
  • 109
    • 85013986887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Among Esping-Andersen's strongly social democratic countries, this leaves out only Norway (as discussed in the previous note) and the Netherlands, which Esping-Andersen has never been comfortable regarding as social democratic. See G. Esping-Andersen, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985), p. 145, and 'Welfare States Without Work', p. 66.
    • Welfare States Without Work , pp. 66
  • 110
    • 0003463955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Along with Ireland, which Esping-Andersen (Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, p. 74) treats as a mixed case. I will say more shortly about the other classically corporatist countries (Austria, Belgium and France) which are left out of this cell.
    • Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism , pp. 74
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 112
    • 0004174293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: UN, Table 25
    • The average across the eighteen countries of the 'old OECD' is 2.27. The Dutch rate is 2.35. The rates in the other countries are: Austria 2.11; Belgium 2.09; and France 1.92. See United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Information and Policy Analysis, Demographic Yearbook 1995 (New York: UN, 1997), Table 25.
    • (1997) Demographic Yearbook 1995
  • 113
    • 0004059801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Annex Table A, and Annex Table E
    • Employment rates are different from labour-force participation rates, in that the latter also includes the unemployed (who are 'available for work', and hence in the work force). Because OECD statistics report part-time employment as a proportion of total employment, it is more convenient to use employment rates for these purposes. Figures 1 and 2 would have looked much the same had we used employment rates rather than labour-force participation rates. Data are from OECD, Employment Outlook (1995), Annex Table A, p. 204, and Annex Table E, p. 210.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 204
  • 114
    • 0039746188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gender inequality and the conservative welfare state: A four-nation comparison
    • San Francisco
    • A fact that is, of course, widely noted elsewhere. See, e.g.: J. Bussemaker and K. van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State: A Four-nation Comparison' (paper presented to the 1996 Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco); J. Plantenga, 'For Women Only? The Rise of Part-time Work in the Netherlands', Social Politics, 3 (1996), 57-71; and M. Van Berkel and N. D. De Graaf, 'Married Women's Economic Dependency in the Netherlands, 1979-1991', British Journal of Sociology, 49 (1998), 97-117.
    • 1996 Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association
    • Bussemaker, J.1    Van Kersbergen, K.2
  • 115
    • 0030531428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For women only? The rise of part-time work in the Netherlands
    • A fact that is, of course, widely noted elsewhere. See, e.g.: J. Bussemaker and K. van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State: A Four-nation Comparison' (paper presented to the 1996 Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco); J. Plantenga, 'For Women Only? The Rise of Part-time Work in the Netherlands', Social Politics, 3 (1996), 57-71; and M. Van Berkel and N. D. De Graaf, 'Married Women's Economic Dependency in the Netherlands, 1979-1991', British Journal of Sociology, 49 (1998), 97-117.
    • (1996) Social Politics , vol.3 , pp. 57-71
    • Plantenga, J.1
  • 116
    • 0032016588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Married women's economic dependency in the Netherlands, 1979-1991
    • A fact that is, of course, widely noted elsewhere. See, e.g.: J. Bussemaker and K. van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State: A Four-nation Comparison' (paper presented to the 1996 Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco); J. Plantenga, 'For Women Only? The Rise of Part-time Work in the Netherlands', Social Politics, 3 (1996), 57-71; and M. Van Berkel and N. D. De Graaf, 'Married Women's Economic Dependency in the Netherlands, 1979-1991', British Journal of Sociology, 49 (1998), 97-117.
    • (1998) British Journal of Sociology , vol.49 , pp. 97-117
    • Van Berkel, M.1    De Graaf, N.D.2
  • 117
    • 0003412755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chap. 6
    • 'Equivalent income' adjusts, through 'equivalence scales', for family size and associated economies of scale. 'Disposable income' is income net of government taxes and transfers. See Goodin et al., Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, chap. 6.
    • Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism
    • Goodin1
  • 118
    • 0345675846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income distribution and poverty in selected OECD countries
    • Paris: OECD
    • Poverty rates are as reported in OECD, 'Income Distribution and Poverty in Selected OECD Countries', Economic Outlook No. 62 (Paris: OECD, 1997), pp. 49-59 at p. 54.
    • (1997) Economic Outlook No. 62 , pp. 49-59
  • 119
    • 0004059801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Annex Table C
    • Data on the average annual number of hours worked per person in the labour force is given in OECD, Employment Outlook (1995), Annex Table C, p. 208; to get from that the average number of hours worked per person in the working-age population, whether or not they are in the labour-force, I multiply that by the labour force participation rate, given in Annex Table I, p. 214. Whereas all other data are for 1993, the Italian data are for 1983; there has been a steady decline in the number of working hours in most other countries over the intervening period, so as an estimate of 1993 work hours that figure for Italy might be anything up to 100 hours too high. Dutch data refers to 'dependent employment': for other countries for which statistics on both are reported, work hours in 'dependent employment' are marginally lower (by between 32 and 114 hours a year) than 'total employment', which is the more common statistic and hence the one reported here for all other countries.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 208
  • 120
    • 85013966525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Figure 5 is not just the mirror image of Figure 2 rotated around the y axis. High social security expenditures will not necessarily reduce poverty (it all depends on who gets the money). Neither do low labour-force participation rates necessarily translate into low average working hours (it all depends on how many hours are worked by those in work). Figure 5 shows that higher social security spending does actually pay off, in terms of reduced poverty rates, and that countries with fewer people in the labour force do not work them harder in consequence.
  • 121
    • 0006996935 scopus 로고
    • Paris: OECD
    • OECD, Household Production in OECD Countries (Paris: OECD, 1995); L. Goldschmidt-Clermont and E Pagnossin-Aligisakis, Measures of Unrecorded Economic Activities in Fourteen Countries, Occasional Paper No. 20, Human Development Report Office (New York: United Nations Development Program, 1995).
    • (1995) Household Production in Oecd Countries
  • 123
    • 85013974712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The data refer to: Australia 1992; Belgium 1965; Canada 1992; Denmark 1987: Finland 1987; France 1974; Germany 1965; Italy 1980; Netherlands 1985; Norway 1981; Sweden 1991; United Kingdom 1985; United States 1985
    • The data refer to: Australia 1992; Belgium 1965; Canada 1992; Denmark 1987: Finland 1987; France 1974; Germany 1965; Italy 1980; Netherlands 1985; Norway 1981; Sweden 1991; United Kingdom 1985; United States 1985.
  • 124
    • 0009875719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An equivalence scale for time
    • SPRC Discussion Paper No. 85 Kensington, NSW: Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales, forthcoming in
    • Reported in M. Bittman and R. E. Goodin, 'An Equivalence Scale for Time', SPRC Discussion Paper No. 85 (Kensington, NSW: Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales, 1998), forthcoming in Social Indicators Research.
    • (1998) Social Indicators Research
    • Bittman, M.1    Goodin, R.E.2
  • 125
    • 85013874442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • That is not to say that all stay-at-home-mothers do so out of their own free choice: sometimes it is their partners who insist. That, though, is clearly something well beyond the ken ot any ordinary OECD statistics.
  • 126
    • 0040338144 scopus 로고
    • Supplementary measures of labour market slack: An analysis of discouraged and involuntary part-time workers
    • OECD, 'Supplementary Measures of Labour Market Slack: An Analysis of Discouraged and Involuntary Part-time Workers', Employment Outlook (1995), pp. 43-97.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 43-97
  • 127
    • 0004059801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Annex Table A
    • Calculated from OECD, Employment Outlook (1995), Annex Table A, p. 204.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 204
  • 128
    • 85013923970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Anyway, their not being employed in paid labour is not involuntary in the way that would be captured in the OECD definitions of 'unemployment' or 'discouraged worker'.
  • 129
    • 85013934519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The exception which pulls the social-democratic oval way out to the right is Finland, which was suffering unprecedentedly high unemployment rates in 1993.
  • 130
    • 0004059801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Table 2.18
    • OECD, Employment Outlook (1995), Table 2.18, pp. 76-7.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 76-77
  • 131
    • 0004059801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Annex Table E
    • Calculated from OECD, Employment Outlook (1995), Annex Table E, p. 210.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 210
  • 133
    • 0004059801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Annex Table T
    • As reported in OECD, Employment Outlook (1995), Annex Table T, p. 222-9.
    • (1995) Employment Outlook , pp. 222-229
  • 134
    • 0024256237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Netherlands: A passive social democratic welfare state in a christian democratic ruled society
    • As nicely captured in K. van Kersbergen and U. Becker's title, 'The Netherlands: A Passive Social Democratic Welfare State in a Christian Democratic Ruled Society', Journal of Social Policy, 17 (1988), 477-99. See similarly Therborn, '"Pillarization" and "popular movements"'.
    • (1988) Journal of Social Policy , vol.17 , pp. 477-499
    • Van Kersbergen, K.1    Becker, U.2
  • 135
    • 0024256237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As nicely captured in K. van Kersbergen and U. Becker's title, 'The Netherlands: A Passive Social Democratic Welfare State in a Christian Democratic Ruled Society', Journal of Social Policy, 17 (1988), 477-99. See similarly Therborn, '"Pillarization" and "popular movements"'.
    • "Pillarization" and "Popular Movements"
    • Therborn1
  • 136
    • 84937190878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Participate or sink: Threshold equality behind the dykes
    • 'The post-productivist Left in the Netherlands' within the Labour Party (PvdA) is now explicitly calling for a 'relaxed organization of labour'; R. J. van der Veen, 'Participate or Sink: Threshold Equality Behind the Dykes', Acta Politica, 34 (1999), 351-81, at pp. 367-73.
    • (1999) Acta Politica , vol.34 , pp. 351-381
    • Van Der Veen, R.J.1
  • 137
    • 0039746180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the famous exchange between Prime Minister Van Agt, Terlouw (D'66) and Den Uyl (PvdA) during the 1980 Budget debate quoted in Goodin and Smitsman, 'Placing Welfare States'; see also Therborn, Why Some Peoples are More Unemployed than Others.
    • Placing Welfare States
    • Goodin1    Smitsman2
  • 138
    • 0003949859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the famous exchange between Prime Minister Van Agt, Terlouw (D'66) and Den Uyl (PvdA) during the 1980 Budget debate quoted in Goodin and Smitsman, 'Placing Welfare States'; see also Therborn, Why Some Peoples are More Unemployed than Others.
    • Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others
    • Therborn1
  • 139
    • 0007218604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Macmillan, chap. 3
    • This has of course been true in high-spenders among corporatist regimes, as well. On France, for example, see: A. Favell, Philosopies of Integration (London: Macmillan, 1998), chap. 3; and M. Evans, S. Paugam and J. A. Prélis, 'Chunnel Vision: Poverty, Social Exclusion and the Debate on Social Welfare in France and Britain', Discussion Paper WSP/115 (London: Welfare State Programme, STICERD, London School of Economics, 1995).
    • (1998) Philosopies of Integration
    • Favell, A.1
  • 140
    • 0010759096 scopus 로고
    • Discussion Paper WSP/115 London: Welfare State Programme, STICERD, London School of Economics
    • This has of course been true in high-spenders among corporatist regimes, as well. On France, for example, see: A. Favell, Philosopies of Integration (London: Macmillan, 1998), chap. 3; and M. Evans, S. Paugam and J. A. Prélis, 'Chunnel Vision: Poverty, Social Exclusion and the Debate on Social Welfare in France and Britain', Discussion Paper WSP/115 (London: Welfare State Programme, STICERD, London School of Economics, 1995).
    • (1995) Chunnel Vision: Poverty, Social Exclusion and the Debate on Social Welfare in France and Britain
    • Evans, M.1    Paugam, S.2    Prélis, J.A.3
  • 141
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • Social Security in the Netherlands and the Dutch Welfare State from An International and Economic Perspective
  • 142
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Managed liberalization of the Dutch welfare state: A review and analysis of the reform of the Dutch social security system, 1985-98
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • (1999) Governance , vol.12 , pp. 289-310
    • Van Der Veen, R.1    Trommel, W.2
  • 143
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • The Netherlands: An Extreme Case
    • De Vroom1    Blomsma2
  • 144
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?
    • Kloosterman1
  • 145
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • A Miraculous Model?
    • Hemerijck1    Van Kersbergen2
  • 146
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • A Dutch Miracle
    • Visser1    Hemerijck2
  • 147
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • A Miraculous Model? , pp. 270-274
    • Hemerijck1    Van Kersbergen2
  • 148
    • 0033473416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netherlands Ministry of Social Affairs & Employment, Social Security in the Netherlands and The Dutch Welfare State from an International and Economic Perspective; R. van der Veen and W. Trommel, 'Managed Liberalization of the Dutch Welfare State: A Review and Analysis of the Reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-98', Governance, 12 (1999), 289-310; de Vroom and Blomsma, 'The Netherlands: An Extreme Case'; Kloosterman, 'Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism?'; Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?'; Visser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle. While reforms to disability pensions officially took effect in 1987, the numbers of disability claimants continued to rise for another seven years (Hemerijck and van Kersbergen, 'A Miraculous Model?' pp. 270-4). Legislation which took effect in 1996 'requires single mothers to seek employment actively and obliges single mothers to work if day care or care-substitution is available … the responsibility for a child is not an argument any more to exit the labour market or to reject a job' (Bussemaker and van Kersbergen, 'Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State', p. 14) - though those reforms, too, might take some while to have any real effect.
    • Gender Inequality and the Conservative Welfare State , pp. 14
    • Bussemaker1    Van Kersbergen2
  • 149
    • 0004059801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paris: OECD, Table F
    • OECD, Employment Outlook (Paris: OECD, 1997), Table F, p. 178.
    • (1997) Employment Outlook , pp. 178
  • 151
    • 0039746173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Research Paper 99/02. Netherlands School for Social and Economic Policy Research Tilburg: AWSB/ TISSER
    • R. Muffels and B. Steijn, Flexible and Permanent Jobs on the Dutch Labour Market, Research Paper 99/02. Netherlands School for Social and Economic Policy Research (Tilburg: AWSB/ TISSER, 1998), p. 5.
    • (1998) Flexible and Permanent Jobs on the Dutch Labour Market , pp. 5
    • Muffels, R.1    Steijn, B.2
  • 152
    • 0039746177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van Oorschot and Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work'. The 'activation obligation' is an 'availability for work' requirement applying to anyone in receipt of income support, except for single parents of children under 5 and unemployed persons over 57.5 years of age; Viser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle, p. 148.
    • Work, Work, Work
    • Van Oorschot1    Engerlfriet2
  • 153
    • 0004214584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van Oorschot and Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work'. The 'activation obligation' is an 'availability for work' requirement applying to anyone in receipt of income support, except for single parents of children under 5 and unemployed persons over 57.5 years of age; Viser and Hemerijck, A Dutch Miracle, p. 148.
    • A Dutch Miracle , pp. 148
    • Viser1    Hemerijck2
  • 154
    • 0040338131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van der Veen, 'Participate or Sink', pp. 366-73. Whereas some 93 per cent of respondents say that the obligation to find paid employment should be applied 'strictly' to young unemployed persons, only 34 per cent think it should be applied strictly to the 'unemployed who are active in voluntary associations or community', only 16 per cent think it should be applied strictly to 'single parents with children aged 6-12, and less than half that many think it should be applied strictly to children younger than that (van Oorschot and Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work', p. 19). Notice that legislation has done much to facilitate this growth of part-time labour: part-time workers have rights to state pensions, social insurance and health care: and the Labour Time Act of 1996 directs employers to take into consideration employees' care-giving responsibilities.
    • Participate or Sink , pp. 366-373
    • Van Der Veen1
  • 155
    • 0039746177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van der Veen, 'Participate or Sink', pp. 366-73. Whereas some 93 per cent of respondents say that the obligation to find paid employment should be applied 'strictly' to young unemployed persons, only 34 per cent think it should be applied strictly to the 'unemployed who are active in voluntary associations or community', only 16 per cent think it should be applied strictly to 'single parents with children aged 6-12, and less than half that many think it should be applied strictly to children younger than that (van Oorschot and Engerlfriet, 'Work, Work, Work', p. 19). Notice that legislation has done much to facilitate this growth of part-time labour: part-time workers have rights to state pensions, social insurance and health care: and the Labour Time Act of 1996 directs employers to take into consideration employees' care-giving responsibilities.
    • Work, Work, Work , pp. 19
    • Van Oorschot1    Engerlfriet2
  • 156
  • 157
    • 85013977952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Perhaps the explanation is that the 'flexibilization' of the workforce that comes with radically part-time post-productivist arrangements actually suits the needs of a post-modern service economy.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.