메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 31, Issue 5, 2002, Pages 573-621

The state of social capital: Bringing back in power, politics, and history

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0036453705     PISSN: 03042421     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1023/A:1021300217590     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (223)

References (127)
  • 2
    • 0003782709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (1996) Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality
    • Wilkinson, R.G.1
  • 3
    • 0141467028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (1997) American Behavioral Scientist , vol.40 , Issue.5
  • 4
    • 0040517193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does social capital have an economic payoff?
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (1997) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.112 , Issue.4 , pp. 1251-1288
    • Knack, S.1    Keefer, P.2
  • 5
    • 0032713765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cents and sociability: Household income and social capital in rural Tanzania
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (1999) Economic Development and Cultural Change , vol.47 , Issue.4 , pp. 871-897
    • Naryan, D.1    Pritchett, L.2
  • 6
    • 0033437616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital in Britain
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (1999) British Journal of Politics , vol.29 , pp. 417-461
    • Hall, P.A.1
  • 7
    • 0141801850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (1999) Journal of Interdisciplinary History , vol.29 , Issue.PARTS 3 AND 4
  • 8
    • 84978529601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Women and social capital: A comment
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (2000) British Journal of Political Studies , vol.30 , pp. 533-540
    • Lowndes, V.1
  • 9
    • 0003840806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: World Bank
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (2000) Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective
    • Dasgupta, P.1    Sergaldin, I.2
  • 10
    • 0003840807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Oxford U. Press
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (2000) Social Capital: Critical Perspectives
    • Baron, S.1    Field, J.2    Schuller, T.3
  • 11
    • 0141690215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public health and safety: Community and social capital
    • Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press)
    • In addition to all the important contributions that are referenced in the ensuing notes, the following exemplify the multi-disciplinary nature of the intellectual enterprise: Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (London: Routledge, 1996); American Behavioral Scientist 40/5 (1997), special issue, edited by Bob Edwards and Michael Foley, on "Social Capital, Civil Society and Contemporary Democracy"; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/4 (1997): 1251-1288; Deepa Naryan and Lant Pritchett, "Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in Rural Tanzania," Economic Development and Cultural Change 47/4 (1999): 871-897; Peter A. Hall, "Social Capital in Britain," British Journal of Politics 29 (1999): 417-461; Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29, Parts 3 and 4 (1999), special double issue on "Patterns of Social Capital," Parts I and II; Vivien Lowndes, "Women and Social Capital: A Comment,' British Journal of Political Studies 30 (2000): 533-540; Partha Dasgupta and Ismael Sergaldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2000) ; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2000); Robert J. Sampson and Jeffrey D. Morenoff, "Public Health and Safety: Community and Social Capital," in Brian D. Smedley and S. Leonard Syme, editors, Promoting Health (Washington D.C.: Institute of Medicine, National Academy Press 2001).
    • (2001) Promoting Health
    • Sampson, R.J.1    Morenoff, J.D.2
  • 14
    • 0030306461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making social science work across space and time: A critical reflection on Robert Putnam's making democracy work
    • Sidney Tarrow, "Making Social Science Work Across Space and Time: A Critical Reflection on Robert Putnam's Making Democracy Work," American Political Science Review 90/2 (June 1996): 389-397; special section of review articles of Making Democracy Work by Ellis Goldberg, Filippo Sabetti, Margaret Levi, and Daniela Gobetti in Politics and Society 24/1 (March 1996): 3-82.
    • (1996) American Political Science Review , vol.90 , Issue.2 , pp. 389-397
    • Tarrow, S.1
  • 15
    • 0030306461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sidney Tarrow, "Making Social Science Work Across Space and Time: A Critical Reflection on Robert Putnam's Making Democracy Work," American Political Science Review 90/2 (June 1996): 389-397; special section of review articles of Making Democracy Work by Ellis Goldberg, Filippo Sabetti, Margaret Levi, and Daniela Gobetti in Politics and Society 24/1 (March 1996): 3-82.
    • Making Democracy Work
    • Goldberg, E.1    Sabetti, F.2    Levi, M.3
  • 16
    • 0030306693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • March
    • Sidney Tarrow, "Making Social Science Work Across Space and Time: A Critical Reflection on Robert Putnam's Making Democracy Work," American Political Science Review 90/2 (June 1996): 389-397; special section of review articles of Making Democracy Work by Ellis Goldberg, Filippo Sabetti, Margaret Levi, and Daniela Gobetti in Politics and Society 24/1 (March 1996): 3-82.
    • (1996) Politics and Society , vol.24 , Issue.1 , pp. 3-82
    • Gobetti, D.1
  • 17
    • 0027743127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Embeddedness and immigration: Notes on the social determinants of economic action
    • Alejandro Portes and Julia Sensenbrenner, "Embeddedness and Immigration: Notes on the Social Determinants of Economic Action," American Journal of Sociology 98/6 (1993): 1320-1350; Alejandro Portes, editor, The Economic Sociology of Immigration (New York: Russell Sage, 1995); Alejandro Portes and Patricia Landolt, "The Downside of Social Capital," American Prospect 26 (1996): 18-22. Putnam devotes chapter 22 of Bowling Alone to a discussion of "The Dark Side of Social Capital."
    • (1993) American Journal of Sociology , vol.98 , Issue.6 , pp. 1320-1350
    • Portes, A.1    Sensenbrenner, J.2
  • 18
    • 0027743127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Russell Sage
    • Alejandro Portes and Julia Sensenbrenner, "Embeddedness and Immigration: Notes on the Social Determinants of Economic Action," American Journal of Sociology 98/6 (1993): 1320-1350; Alejandro Portes, editor, The Economic Sociology of Immigration (New York: Russell Sage, 1995); Alejandro Portes and Patricia Landolt, "The Downside of Social Capital," American Prospect 26 (1996): 18-22. Putnam devotes chapter 22 of Bowling Alone to a discussion of "The Dark Side of Social Capital."
    • (1995) The Economic Sociology of Immigration
    • Portes, A.1
  • 19
    • 0027743127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The downside of social capital
    • Alejandro Portes and Julia Sensenbrenner, "Embeddedness and Immigration: Notes on the Social Determinants of Economic Action," American Journal of Sociology 98/6 (1993): 1320-1350; Alejandro Portes, editor, The Economic Sociology of Immigration (New York: Russell Sage, 1995); Alejandro Portes and Patricia Landolt, "The Downside of Social Capital," American Prospect 26 (1996): 18-22. Putnam devotes chapter 22 of Bowling Alone to a discussion of "The Dark Side of Social Capital."
    • (1996) American Prospect , vol.26 , pp. 18-22
    • Portes, A.1    Landolt, P.2
  • 20
    • 0027743127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • devotes chapter 22
    • Alejandro Portes and Julia Sensenbrenner, "Embeddedness and Immigration: Notes on the Social Determinants of Economic Action," American Journal of Sociology 98/6 (1993): 1320-1350; Alejandro Portes, editor, The Economic Sociology of Immigration (New York: Russell Sage, 1995); Alejandro Portes and Patricia Landolt, "The Downside of Social Capital," American Prospect 26 (1996): 18-22. Putnam devotes chapter 22 of Bowling Alone to a discussion of "The Dark Side of Social Capital."
    • Bowling Alone
    • Putnam1
  • 22
    • 34247960076 scopus 로고
    • The strength of weak ties
    • Ross Gittell and Avis Vidal, Community Organization: Building Social Capital as a Development Strategy (London: Sage Publications, 1998), 8; Mark S. Granovetter, " The Strength of Weak Ties," American Journal of Sociology 78 (1973): 1360-1380.
    • (1973) American Journal of Sociology , vol.78 , pp. 1360-1380
    • Granovetter, M.S.1
  • 23
    • 0141578636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For instance, affiliation to a religious denomination looks as though it ought to be a classic example of bonding social capital - a network of persons who are alike in their cosmological orientation. When such denominational congregations form clearly defined minority groups within larger polities, as during periods of religious ferment when new congregations come into being or else under circumstances of migration, this is certainly true and their bonding social capital has been well-documented. But when the religious denomination is a large and populous, well-established one with full and equal rights in the polity in question and with members drawn from all walks of life, it is likely to function more as a source of bridging social capital for members of its networks. See also the work by Portes cited in note 5 on the varying functions that networks play for immigrants.
  • 24
    • 0002932610 scopus 로고
    • A dynamic theory of racial income differences
    • P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, (Lexington, MA: Lexington)
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • (1977) Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination , pp. 153-188
    • Loury, G.C.1
  • 25
    • 84936823500 scopus 로고
    • Social capital in the creation of human capital
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • (1988) American Journal of Sociology , vol.94
    • Coleman, J.S.1
  • 26
    • 0004078737 scopus 로고
    • (London: Belknap Press), Chapter 12, "Social Capital"
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • (1990) Foundations of Social Theory
    • Coleman, J.S.1
  • 27
    • 0032384959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital and economic development: Toward a theoretical synthesis and policy framework
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • (1998) Theory and Society , vol.27 , pp. 151-208
    • Woolcock, M.1
  • 28
    • 0032331809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital: Its origins and applications in modern sociology
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • (1998) Annual Review of Sociology , vol.24 , pp. 1-24
    • Portes, A.1
  • 29
    • 0032697009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is it time to disinvest in social capital?
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • (1999) Journal of Public Policy , vol.19 , pp. 141-173
    • Foley, M.1    Edwards, B.2
  • 30
    • 0003840807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Oxford: Oxford University Press), Chapter 1
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • (2000) Social Capital: Critical Perspectives
    • Baron, S.1    Field, J.2    Schuller, T.3
  • 31
    • 0141801848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota
    • G. C. Loury, "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences," in P. A. Wallace and A. LeMund, editors, Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination (Lexington, MA: Lexington, 1977), 153-88; James S. Coleman, "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S95-120; James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (London: Belknap Press, 1990), Chapter 12, "Social Capital." On the intellectual genealogy of the term and its early users, see Michael Woolcock, "Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward A Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework," Theory and Society 27 (1998): 151-208; Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology 24 (1998): 1-24; Michael Foley and Bob Edwards, "Is It Time to Disinvest in Social Capital?" Journal of Public Policy 19 (1999): 141-173; Steve Baron, John Field, and Tom Schuller, editors, Social Capital: Critical Perspectives (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), Chapter 1; James Farr, "The secret history of social capital, " unpublished ms., Political Science Department, University of Minnesota.
    • The Secret History of Social Capital
    • Farr, J.1
  • 32
    • 0001986533 scopus 로고
    • Le capital social: Notes provisoires
    • Pierre Bourdieu, "Le capital social: Notes provisoires," Actes de la Recherche Sciences Sociales 31 (1980): 2-3; Pierre Bourdieu, "The Forms of Capital," in John G. Richardson, editor, Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education (New York: Greenwood, 1985), 241-258.
    • (1980) Actes de la Recherche Sciences Sociales , vol.31 , pp. 2-3
    • Bourdieu, P.1
  • 33
    • 0002538481 scopus 로고
    • The forms of capital
    • John G. Richardson, editor, (New York: Greenwood)
    • Pierre Bourdieu, "Le capital social: Notes provisoires," Actes de la Recherche Sciences Sociales 31 (1980): 2-3; Pierre Bourdieu, "The Forms of Capital," in John G. Richardson, editor, Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education (New York: Greenwood, 1985), 241-258.
    • (1985) Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education , pp. 241-258
    • Bourdieu, P.1
  • 34
    • 0003583974 scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge and Kegan Paul
    • Pierre Bourdieu, Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgement of Taste (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1984). Of course the elite do, of necessity, find themselves interacting sometimes intimately in their own homes - with individuals from much poorer or even marginalized social groups (immigrant domestic workers), but the mere fact of knowledge and contact does not amount to any necessary form of social capital, especially as relationships in these circumstances are typically governed by the highly (but subtly) inegalitarian conventions of deference, on which see Erving Goffman, "The Nature of Deference and Demeanour," in E. Goffman, Interaction Ritual. Essays on Face-to-Face Behavior (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1972), 47-95.
    • (1984) Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgement of Taste
    • Bourdieu, P.1
  • 35
    • 0010708777 scopus 로고
    • The nature of deference and demeanour
    • E. Goffman, (Harmondsworth: Penguin)
    • Pierre Bourdieu, Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgement of Taste (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1984). Of course the elite do, of necessity, find themselves interacting sometimes intimately in their own homes - with individuals from much poorer or even marginalized social groups (immigrant domestic workers), but the mere fact of knowledge and contact does not amount to any necessary form of social capital, especially as relationships in these circumstances are typically governed by the highly (but subtly) inegalitarian conventions of deference, on which see Erving Goffman, "The Nature of Deference and Demeanour," in E. Goffman, Interaction Ritual. Essays on Face-to-Face Behavior (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1972), 47-95.
    • (1972) Interaction Ritual. Essays on Face-to-Face Behavior , pp. 47-95
    • Goffman, E.1
  • 36
    • 0001094329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Managing risk, shocks, and opportunity in developing economies: The role of social capital
    • Gustav Ranis, editor, (New Haven, Conn.: Yale Center for International and Area Studies)
    • Michael Woolcock, "Managing Risk, Shocks, and Opportunity in Developing Economies: The Role of Social Capital," in Gustav Ranis, editor, Dimensions of Development (New Haven, Conn.: Yale Center for International and Area Studies, 2000), 197-212; World Bank, World Development Report 2000/01 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), Chapter 7; Michael Woolcock, Using Social Capital: Getting the Social Relations Right in the Theory and Practice of Economic Development (Princeton: Princeton University Press, forthcoming 2003).
    • (2000) Dimensions of Development , pp. 197-212
    • Woolcock, M.1
  • 37
    • 0003517331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Oxford: Oxford University Press), Chapter 7
    • Michael Woolcock, "Managing Risk, Shocks, and Opportunity in Developing Economies: The Role of Social Capital," in Gustav Ranis, editor, Dimensions of Development (New Haven, Conn.: Yale Center for International and Area Studies, 2000), 197-212; World Bank, World Development Report 2000/01 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), Chapter 7; Michael Woolcock, Using Social Capital: Getting the Social Relations Right in the Theory and Practice of Economic Development (Princeton: Princeton University Press, forthcoming 2003).
    • (2001) World Development Report 2000/01
  • 38
    • 0004304314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton: Princeton University Press, forthcoming
    • Michael Woolcock, "Managing Risk, Shocks, and Opportunity in Developing Economies: The Role of Social Capital," in Gustav Ranis, editor, Dimensions of Development (New Haven, Conn.: Yale Center for International and Area Studies, 2000), 197-212; World Bank, World Development Report 2000/01 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), Chapter 7; Michael Woolcock, Using Social Capital: Getting the Social Relations Right in the Theory and Practice of Economic Development (Princeton: Princeton University Press, forthcoming 2003).
    • (2003) Using Social Capital: Getting the Social Relations Right in the Theory and Practice of Economic Development
    • Woolcock, M.1
  • 39
    • 0004186551 scopus 로고
    • New Haven: Yale U. Press
    • Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven: Yale U. Press, 1958); Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P. 1967); Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmayer, and Theda Skocpol, editors, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press 1985); Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 1989); Robert Wade, Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1990); Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1995); special section of World Development 24/ 6 (1996): 1033-1132, introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China).
    • (1958) The Strategy of Economic Development
    • Hirschman, A.O.1
  • 40
    • 0003948935 scopus 로고
    • Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P.
    • Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven: Yale U. Press, 1958); Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P. 1967); Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmayer, and Theda Skocpol, editors, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press 1985); Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 1989); Robert Wade, Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1990); Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1995); special section of World Development 24/ 6 (1996): 1033-1132, introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China).
    • (1967) Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach
    • Adelman, I.1    Morris, C.T.2
  • 41
    • 0004212175 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press
    • Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven: Yale U. Press, 1958); Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P. 1967); Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmayer, and Theda Skocpol, editors, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press 1985); Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 1989); Robert Wade, Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1990); Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1995); special section of World Development 24/ 6 (1996): 1033-1132, introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China).
    • (1985) Bringing the State Back In
    • Evans, P.1    Rueschmayer, D.2    Skocpol, T.3
  • 42
    • 0004016989 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Oxford U. Press
    • Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven: Yale U. Press, 1958); Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P. 1967); Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmayer, and Theda Skocpol, editors, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press 1985); Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 1989); Robert Wade, Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1990); Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1995); special section of World Development 24/ 6 (1996): 1033-1132, introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China).
    • (1989) Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization
    • Amsden, A.1
  • 43
    • 0003515053 scopus 로고
    • Princeton: Princeton U. Press
    • Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven: Yale U. Press, 1958); Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P. 1967); Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmayer, and Theda Skocpol, editors, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press 1985); Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 1989); Robert Wade, Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1990); Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1995); special section of World Development 24/ 6 (1996): 1033-1132, introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China).
    • (1990) Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization
    • Wade, R.1
  • 44
    • 84890678774 scopus 로고
    • Princeton: Princeton U. Press
    • Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven: Yale U. Press, 1958); Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P. 1967); Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmayer, and Theda Skocpol, editors, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press 1985); Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 1989); Robert Wade, Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1990); Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1995); special section of World Development 24/ 6 (1996): 1033-1132, introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China).
    • (1995) Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation
    • Evans, P.1
  • 45
    • 0001619626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China)
    • Albert O. Hirschman, The Strategy of Economic Development (New Haven: Yale U. Press, 1958); Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, Society, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P. 1967); Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmayer, and Theda Skocpol, editors, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press 1985); Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 1989); Robert Wade, Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1990); Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton: Princeton U. Press, 1995); special section of World Development 24/ 6 (1996): 1033-1132, introduced by Peter Evans, presenting a set of five empirical studies contributed by Wai Fung Lam (Taiwan), Patrick Heller (Kerala), Elinor Ostrom (Brazil and Nigeria), Jonathan Fox (Mexico), and Michael Burawoy (Russia and China).
    • (1996) World Development , vol.24 , Issue.6 , pp. 1033-1132
  • 46
    • 0141801846 scopus 로고
    • Aspects of group relations in a complex society: Mexico
    • Teodor Shanin, editor, (Harmondsworth)
    • Eric R. Wolf, "Aspects of Group Relations in a Complex Society: Mexico," in Teodor Shanin, editor, Peasants and Peasant Society (Harmondsworth, 1971), 50-68.
    • (1971) Peasants and Peasant Society , pp. 50-68
    • Wolf, E.R.1
  • 47
    • 0003692257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge
    • The extensive critique of social capital theory, published by Ben Fine, Social Capital Versus Social Theory. Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium (London: Routledge 2001), has accused it of evading these issues. It is true that certain social capital exponents, including notably Robert Putnam, have tended to fight shy of these issues. Fine, however, would like to advance the much stronger argument that social capital theory, per se, is intrinsically incapable of addressing these key questions. Such an attempt at summary execution depends on a highly selective reading, both of its historiographical origins and of the most important currents in the theoretical debate. It is symptomatic of Fine's selectivity that he spends a lot of time (Chapter 3) in critique of an author who perfectly suits his allegation, Gary Becker, but whose work on social capital plays almost no role in the current debate and is hardly ever cited. Fine gives Becker an equivalent space allocation to Pierre Bourdieu, who, by contrast, is certainly one of the two key early theorists (along with James S. Coleman) of the concept, whose influence is property considered as such in all serious examinations of the early development of social capital theory (such as the frequently cited reviews by Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards - see note 8, above). This is awkward for Fine, given Bourdieu's impeccable credentials as one of his generation's foremost critical sociologists, who is certainly centrally interested in issues of power, conflict, inequality, and the state. Consequently Fine's text is slippery and internally self-contradictory on Bourdieu's role in social capital theory, claiming, in the chapter on Bourdieu (Chapter 4) that his views have been "abandoned" (p. 63) and that there has been "exclusion from the 'mature' social capital literature" (p. 55); but later he concedes that "Bourdieu's concerns are being restored to the literature, usually unwittingly ... [in] an accumulation of case studies..." (p. 97) and that "the evolving literature is effectively based upon bringing Bourdieu back in...." It is clear that there have been and continues to be an important politico-ideological divide and a dispute among exponents of social capital - what major concept in the social sciences is not subject to such contestation' Fine is premature, to say the least, in his certainty that social capital theory is the exclusive property of a methodological individualist, "rational choice" approach, which excludes issues of power and conflict from its purview. Those most concerned to clarify and develop social capital theory since Coleman and Bourdieu, such as Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards (see note 8). S. Szreter, "Social Capital, the Economy and Education in Historical Perspective," Chapter 3 in Baron, Field, and Schuller, editors, Social Capital, 56-77, and others, have been progressively and explicitly (not unwittingly) exploring the critical agenda of Bourdieu, through "linking social capital" and examination of the state, power, class, and inequality. Meanwhile, the most careful and properly contextualized empirical studies, such as those of Bebbington, have been addressing similar issues: Anthony Bebbington, "Capitals and Capabilities: A Framework for Analyzing Peasant Viability, Rural Livelihoods and Poverty," World Development 27 (1999): 2021-2044; A. Bebbington and Thomas Perrault, "Social Capital, Development and Access to Resources in Highland Ecuador," Economic Geography 75 (1999): 395-418. See also the important collection of empirical studies, in the special section of World Development (1996), introduced and edited by Peter Evans, cited in note 12; and S. Saegert, J. Thompson, M. Warren, editors, Social Capital and Poor Communities (N.Y.: Russell Sage Foundation, 2001).
    • (2001) Social Capital Versus Social Theory. Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium
    • Fine, B.1
  • 48
    • 0003213313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital, the economy and education in historical perspective
    • Chapter 3 in Baron, Field, and Schuller, editors
    • The extensive critique of social capital theory, published by Ben Fine, Social Capital Versus Social Theory. Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium (London: Routledge 2001), has accused it of evading these issues. It is true that certain social capital exponents, including notably Robert Putnam, have tended to fight shy of these issues. Fine, however, would like to advance the much stronger argument that social capital theory, per se, is intrinsically incapable of addressing these key questions. Such an attempt at summary execution depends on a highly selective reading, both of its historiographical origins and of the most important currents in the theoretical debate. It is symptomatic of Fine's selectivity that he spends a lot of time (Chapter 3) in critique of an author who perfectly suits his allegation, Gary Becker, but whose work on social capital plays almost no role in the current debate and is hardly ever cited. Fine gives Becker an equivalent space allocation to Pierre Bourdieu, who, by contrast, is certainly one of the two key early theorists (along with James S. Coleman) of the concept, whose influence is property considered as such in all serious examinations of the early development of social capital theory (such as the frequently cited reviews by Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards - see note 8, above). This is awkward for Fine, given Bourdieu's impeccable credentials as one of his generation's foremost critical sociologists, who is certainly centrally interested in issues of power, conflict, inequality, and the state. Consequently Fine's text is slippery and internally self-contradictory on Bourdieu's role in social capital theory, claiming, in the chapter on Bourdieu (Chapter 4) that his views have been "abandoned" (p. 63) and that there has been "exclusion from the 'mature' social capital literature" (p. 55); but later he concedes that "Bourdieu's concerns are being restored to the literature, usually unwittingly ... [in] an accumulation of case studies..." (p. 97) and that "the evolving literature is effectively based upon bringing Bourdieu back in...." It is clear that there have been and continues to be an important politico-ideological divide and a dispute among exponents of social capital - what major concept in the social sciences is not subject to such contestation' Fine is premature, to say the least, in his certainty that social capital theory is the exclusive property of a methodological individualist, "rational choice" approach, which excludes issues of power and conflict from its purview. Those most concerned to clarify and develop social capital theory since Coleman and Bourdieu, such as Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards (see note 8). S. Szreter, "Social Capital, the Economy and Education in Historical Perspective," Chapter 3 in Baron, Field, and Schuller, editors, Social Capital, 56-77, and others, have been progressively and explicitly (not unwittingly) exploring the critical agenda of Bourdieu, through "linking social capital" and examination of the state, power, class, and inequality. Meanwhile, the most careful and properly contextualized empirical studies, such as those of Bebbington, have been addressing similar issues: Anthony Bebbington, "Capitals and Capabilities: A Framework for Analyzing Peasant Viability, Rural Livelihoods and Poverty," World Development 27 (1999): 2021-2044; A. Bebbington and Thomas Perrault, "Social Capital, Development and Access to Resources in Highland Ecuador," Economic Geography 75 (1999): 395-418. See also the important collection of empirical studies, in the special section of World Development (1996), introduced and edited by Peter Evans, cited in note 12; and S. Saegert, J. Thompson, M. Warren, editors, Social Capital and Poor Communities (N.Y.: Russell Sage Foundation, 2001).
    • Social Capital , pp. 56-77
    • Szreter, S.1
  • 49
    • 0033407166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Capitals and capabilities: A framework for analyzing peasant viability, rural livelihoods and poverty
    • The extensive critique of social capital theory, published by Ben Fine, Social Capital Versus Social Theory. Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium (London: Routledge 2001), has accused it of evading these issues. It is true that certain social capital exponents, including notably Robert Putnam, have tended to fight shy of these issues. Fine, however, would like to advance the much stronger argument that social capital theory, per se, is intrinsically incapable of addressing these key questions. Such an attempt at summary execution depends on a highly selective reading, both of its historiographical origins and of the most important currents in the theoretical debate. It is symptomatic of Fine's selectivity that he spends a lot of time (Chapter 3) in critique of an author who perfectly suits his allegation, Gary Becker, but whose work on social capital plays almost no role in the current debate and is hardly ever cited. Fine gives Becker an equivalent space allocation to Pierre Bourdieu, who, by contrast, is certainly one of the two key early theorists (along with James S. Coleman) of the concept, whose influence is property considered as such in all serious examinations of the early development of social capital theory (such as the frequently cited reviews by Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards - see note 8, above). This is awkward for Fine, given Bourdieu's impeccable credentials as one of his generation's foremost critical sociologists, who is certainly centrally interested in issues of power, conflict, inequality, and the state. Consequently Fine's text is slippery and internally self-contradictory on Bourdieu's role in social capital theory, claiming, in the chapter on Bourdieu (Chapter 4) that his views have been "abandoned" (p. 63) and that there has been "exclusion from the 'mature' social capital literature" (p. 55); but later he concedes that "Bourdieu's concerns are being restored to the literature, usually unwittingly ... [in] an accumulation of case studies..." (p. 97) and that "the evolving literature is effectively based upon bringing Bourdieu back in...." It is clear that there have been and continues to be an important politico-ideological divide and a dispute among exponents of social capital - what major concept in the social sciences is not subject to such contestation' Fine is premature, to say the least, in his certainty that social capital theory is the exclusive property of a methodological individualist, "rational choice" approach, which excludes issues of power and conflict from its purview. Those most concerned to clarify and develop social capital theory since Coleman and Bourdieu, such as Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards (see note 8). S. Szreter, "Social Capital, the Economy and Education in Historical Perspective," Chapter 3 in Baron, Field, and Schuller, editors, Social Capital, 56-77, and others, have been progressively and explicitly (not unwittingly) exploring the critical agenda of Bourdieu, through "linking social capital" and examination of the state, power, class, and inequality. Meanwhile, the most careful and properly contextualized empirical studies, such as those of Bebbington, have been addressing similar issues: Anthony Bebbington, "Capitals and Capabilities: A Framework for Analyzing Peasant Viability, Rural Livelihoods and Poverty," World Development 27 (1999): 2021-2044; A. Bebbington and Thomas Perrault, "Social Capital, Development and Access to Resources in Highland Ecuador," Economic Geography 75 (1999): 395-418. See also the important collection of empirical studies, in the special section of World Development (1996), introduced and edited by Peter Evans, cited in note 12; and S. Saegert, J. Thompson, M. Warren, editors, Social Capital and Poor Communities (N.Y.: Russell Sage Foundation, 2001).
    • (1999) World Development , vol.27 , pp. 2021-2044
    • Bebbington, A.1
  • 50
    • 0033492839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital, development and access to resources in highland Ecuador
    • The extensive critique of social capital theory, published by Ben Fine, Social Capital Versus Social Theory. Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium (London: Routledge 2001), has accused it of evading these issues. It is true that certain social capital exponents, including notably Robert Putnam, have tended to fight shy of these issues. Fine, however, would like to advance the much stronger argument that social capital theory, per se, is intrinsically incapable of addressing these key questions. Such an attempt at summary execution depends on a highly selective reading, both of its historiographical origins and of the most important currents in the theoretical debate. It is symptomatic of Fine's selectivity that he spends a lot of time (Chapter 3) in critique of an author who perfectly suits his allegation, Gary Becker, but whose work on social capital plays almost no role in the current debate and is hardly ever cited. Fine gives Becker an equivalent space allocation to Pierre Bourdieu, who, by contrast, is certainly one of the two key early theorists (along with James S. Coleman) of the concept, whose influence is property considered as such in all serious examinations of the early development of social capital theory (such as the frequently cited reviews by Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards - see note 8, above). This is awkward for Fine, given Bourdieu's impeccable credentials as one of his generation's foremost critical sociologists, who is certainly centrally interested in issues of power, conflict, inequality, and the state. Consequently Fine's text is slippery and internally self-contradictory on Bourdieu's role in social capital theory, claiming, in the chapter on Bourdieu (Chapter 4) that his views have been "abandoned" (p. 63) and that there has been "exclusion from the 'mature' social capital literature" (p. 55); but later he concedes that "Bourdieu's concerns are being restored to the literature, usually unwittingly ... [in] an accumulation of case studies..." (p. 97) and that "the evolving literature is effectively based upon bringing Bourdieu back in...." It is clear that there have been and continues to be an important politico-ideological divide and a dispute among exponents of social capital - what major concept in the social sciences is not subject to such contestation' Fine is premature, to say the least, in his certainty that social capital theory is the exclusive property of a methodological individualist, "rational choice" approach, which excludes issues of power and conflict from its purview. Those most concerned to clarify and develop social capital theory since Coleman and Bourdieu, such as Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards (see note 8). S. Szreter, "Social Capital, the Economy and Education in Historical Perspective," Chapter 3 in Baron, Field, and Schuller, editors, Social Capital, 56-77, and others, have been progressively and explicitly (not unwittingly) exploring the critical agenda of Bourdieu, through "linking social capital" and examination of the state, power, class, and inequality. Meanwhile, the most careful and properly contextualized empirical studies, such as those of Bebbington, have been addressing similar issues: Anthony Bebbington, "Capitals and Capabilities: A Framework for Analyzing Peasant Viability, Rural Livelihoods and Poverty," World Development 27 (1999): 2021-2044; A. Bebbington and Thomas Perrault, "Social Capital, Development and Access to Resources in Highland Ecuador," Economic Geography 75 (1999): 395-418. See also the important collection of empirical studies, in the special section of World Development (1996), introduced and edited by Peter Evans, cited in note 12; and S. Saegert, J. Thompson, M. Warren, editors, Social Capital and Poor Communities (N.Y.: Russell Sage Foundation, 2001).
    • (1999) Economic Geography , vol.75 , pp. 395-418
    • Bebbington, A.1    Perrault, T.2
  • 51
    • 84881927605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The extensive critique of social capital theory, published by Ben Fine, Social Capital Versus Social Theory. Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium (London: Routledge 2001), has accused it of evading these issues. It is true that certain social capital exponents, including notably Robert Putnam, have tended to fight shy of these issues. Fine, however, would like to advance the much stronger argument that social capital theory, per se, is intrinsically incapable of addressing these key questions. Such an attempt at summary execution depends on a highly selective reading, both of its historiographical origins and of the most important currents in the theoretical debate. It is symptomatic of Fine's selectivity that he spends a lot of time (Chapter 3) in critique of an author who perfectly suits his allegation, Gary Becker, but whose work on social capital plays almost no role in the current debate and is hardly ever cited. Fine gives Becker an equivalent space allocation to Pierre Bourdieu, who, by contrast, is certainly one of the two
    • (1996) World Development
    • Evans, P.1
  • 52
    • 0009754964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.Y.: Russell Sage Foundation
    • The extensive critique of social capital theory, published by Ben Fine, Social Capital Versus Social Theory. Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium (London: Routledge 2001), has accused it of evading these issues. It is true that certain social capital exponents, including notably Robert Putnam, have tended to fight shy of these issues. Fine, however, would like to advance the much stronger argument that social capital theory, per se, is intrinsically incapable of addressing these key questions. Such an attempt at summary execution depends on a highly selective reading, both of its historiographical origins and of the most important currents in the theoretical debate. It is symptomatic of Fine's selectivity that he spends a lot of time (Chapter 3) in critique of an author who perfectly suits his allegation, Gary Becker, but whose work on social capital plays almost no role in the current debate and is hardly ever cited. Fine gives Becker an equivalent space allocation to Pierre Bourdieu, who, by contrast, is certainly one of the two key early theorists (along with James S. Coleman) of the concept, whose influence is property considered as such in all serious examinations of the early development of social capital theory (such as the frequently cited reviews by Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards - see note 8, above). This is awkward for Fine, given Bourdieu's impeccable credentials as one of his generation's foremost critical sociologists, who is certainly centrally interested in issues of power, conflict, inequality, and the state. Consequently Fine's text is slippery and internally self-contradictory on Bourdieu's role in social capital theory, claiming, in the chapter on Bourdieu (Chapter 4) that his views have been "abandoned" (p. 63) and that there has been "exclusion from the 'mature' social capital literature" (p. 55); but later he concedes that "Bourdieu's concerns are being restored to the literature, usually unwittingly ... [in] an accumulation of case studies..." (p. 97) and that "the evolving literature is effectively based upon bringing Bourdieu back in...." It is clear that there have been and continues to be an important politico-ideological divide and a dispute among exponents of social capital - what major concept in the social sciences is not subject to such contestation' Fine is premature, to say the least, in his certainty that social capital theory is the exclusive property of a methodological individualist, "rational choice" approach, which excludes issues of power and conflict from its purview. Those most concerned to clarify and develop social capital theory since Coleman and Bourdieu, such as Portes, Woolcock, Foley, and Edwards (see note 8). S. Szreter, "Social Capital, the Economy and Education in Historical Perspective," Chapter 3 in Baron, Field, and Schuller, editors, Social Capital, 56-77, and others, have been progressively and explicitly (not unwittingly) exploring the critical agenda of Bourdieu, through "linking social capital" and examination of the state, power, class, and inequality. Meanwhile, the most careful and properly contextualized empirical studies, such as those of Bebbington, have been addressing similar issues: Anthony Bebbington, "Capitals and Capabilities: A Framework for Analyzing Peasant Viability, Rural Livelihoods and Poverty," World Development 27 (1999): 2021-2044; A. Bebbington and Thomas Perrault, "Social Capital, Development and Access to Resources in Highland Ecuador," Economic Geography 75 (1999): 395-418. See also the important collection of empirical studies, in the special section of World Development (1996), introduced and edited by Peter Evans, cited in note 12; and S. Saegert, J. Thompson, M. Warren, editors, Social Capital and Poor Communities (N.Y.: Russell Sage Foundation, 2001).
    • (2001) Social Capital and Poor Communities
    • Saegert, S.1    Thompson, J.2    Warren, M.3
  • 53
    • 84937334140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital and political fantasy: Robert Putnam's bowling alone
    • Carl Boggs, "Social Capital and Political Fantasy: Robert Putnam's Bowling Alone," Theory and Society 30/2 (2001): 281-297, citing Putnam, Bowling Alone, 338.
    • (2001) Theory and Society , vol.30 , Issue.2 , pp. 281-297
    • Boggs, C.1
  • 54
    • 0004272517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carl Boggs, "Social Capital and Political Fantasy: Robert Putnam's Bowling Alone," Theory and Society 30/2 (2001): 281-297, citing Putnam, Bowling Alone, 338.
    • Bowling Alone , pp. 338
    • Putnam1
  • 56
    • 0003408239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Guilford
    • C. Boggs, The End of Politics: Corporate Power and the Decline of the Public Sphere (New York: Guilford, 2000); George Monbiot, Captive state. The Corporate Takeover of Britain (Macmillan, 2000); Naomi Klein, No Logo (Flamingo, 2000); Noreena Hertz, The Silent Takeover. Global Capitalism and the Death of Democracy (Heinemann, 2001).
    • (2000) The End of Politics: Corporate Power and the Decline of the Public Sphere
    • Boggs, C.1
  • 57
    • 0003738597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Macmillan
    • C. Boggs, The End of Politics: Corporate Power and the Decline of the Public Sphere (New York: Guilford, 2000); George Monbiot, Captive state. The Corporate Takeover of Britain (Macmillan, 2000); Naomi Klein, No Logo (Flamingo, 2000); Noreena Hertz, The Silent Takeover. Global Capitalism and the Death of Democracy (Heinemann, 2001).
    • (2000) Captive State. The Corporate Takeover of Britain
    • Monbiot, G.1
  • 58
    • 0004065037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Flamingo
    • C. Boggs, The End of Politics: Corporate Power and the Decline of the Public Sphere (New York: Guilford, 2000); George Monbiot, Captive state. The Corporate Takeover of Britain (Macmillan, 2000); Naomi Klein, No Logo (Flamingo, 2000); Noreena Hertz, The Silent Takeover. Global Capitalism and the Death of Democracy (Heinemann, 2001).
    • (2000) No Logo
    • Klein, N.1
  • 59
    • 0003608324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heinemann
    • C. Boggs, The End of Politics: Corporate Power and the Decline of the Public Sphere (New York: Guilford, 2000); George Monbiot, Captive state. The Corporate Takeover of Britain (Macmillan, 2000); Naomi Klein, No Logo (Flamingo, 2000); Noreena Hertz, The Silent Takeover. Global Capitalism and the Death of Democracy (Heinemann, 2001).
    • (2001) The Silent Takeover. Global Capitalism and the Death of Democracy
    • Hertz, N.1
  • 60
    • 0141801847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boggs, "Social Capital," 286-287. T. Skocpol and M. Fiorina, editors, Civic Engagement in American Democracy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1999), ch. 1, 16.
    • Social Capital , pp. 286-287
    • Boggs1
  • 61
    • 0003709010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press), ch. 1
    • Boggs, "Social Capital," 286-287. T. Skocpol and M. Fiorina, editors, Civic Engagement in American Democracy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1999), ch. 1, 16.
    • (1999) Civic Engagement in American Democracy , pp. 16
    • Skocpol, T.1    Fiorina, M.2
  • 62
    • 0003843287 scopus 로고
    • (New York: Oxford University Press), 6-7 and Chapter 15, on the unusually physically isolated patterns of residential living in the United States
    • See Kenneth T. Jackson, Crabgrass Frontier. The Suburbanization of the United States (New York: Oxford University Press, 1985), 6-7 and Chapter 15, on the unusually physically isolated patterns of residential living in the United States.
    • (1985) Crabgrass Frontier. The Suburbanization of the United States
    • Jackson, K.T.1
  • 63
    • 0003935833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Haven, Conn.: Yale U. Press
    • Cynthia M. Duncan, Worlds Apart: Why Poverty Persists in Rural America (New Haven, Conn.: Yale U. Press, 1999). For a historically-informed study of categories of officially-sanctioned racial disability in the United States and Brazil at the elementary level of enumeration and registration in the census, see Melissa Nobles, Shades of Citizenship. Race and the Census in Modern Politics (Stanford: Stanford U. Press, 2000); and more generally, see Richard Sennet and Jonathan Cobb, The Hidden Injuries of Class (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1972).
    • (1999) Worlds Apart: Why Poverty Persists in Rural America
    • Duncan, C.M.1
  • 64
    • 84937335353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stanford: Stanford U. Press
    • Cynthia M. Duncan, Worlds Apart: Why Poverty Persists in Rural America (New Haven, Conn.: Yale U. Press, 1999). For a historically-informed study of categories of officially-sanctioned racial disability in the United States and Brazil at the elementary level of enumeration and registration in the census, see Melissa Nobles, Shades of Citizenship. Race and the Census in Modern Politics (Stanford: Stanford U. Press, 2000); and more generally, see Richard Sennet and Jonathan Cobb, The Hidden Injuries of Class (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1972).
    • (2000) Shades of Citizenship. Race and the Census in Modern Politics
    • Nobles, M.1
  • 65
    • 0003514746 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press
    • Cynthia M. Duncan, Worlds Apart: Why Poverty Persists in Rural America (New Haven, Conn.: Yale U. Press, 1999). For a historically-informed study of categories of officially-sanctioned racial disability in the United States and Brazil at the elementary level of enumeration and registration in the census, see Melissa Nobles, Shades of Citizenship. Race and the Census in Modern Politics (Stanford: Stanford U. Press, 2000); and more generally, see Richard Sennet and Jonathan Cobb, The Hidden Injuries of Class (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1972).
    • (1972) The Hidden Injuries of Class
    • Sennet, R.1    Cobb, J.2
  • 66
    • 0141467020 scopus 로고
    • (Cambridge: Polity Press; first published), see Appendix, esp.
    • Jürgen Habermas, Knowledge and Human Interests (Cambridge: Polity Press 1987; first published 1968), see Appendix, esp. p. 314.
    • (1968) Knowledge and Human Interests , pp. 314
    • Habermas, J.1
  • 68
    • 84974040603 scopus 로고
    • British trade unions and popular political economy 1860-1880
    • Eugenio Biagini, "British Trade Unions and Popular Political Economy 1860-1880," Historical Journal 30 (1987): 811-840.
    • (1987) Historical Journal , vol.30 , pp. 811-840
    • Biagini, E.1
  • 69
    • 0004347703 scopus 로고
    • Beckenham: Croom Helm
    • Roger Davidson, Whitehall and the Labor Problem in Late-Victorian and Edwardian Britain. A Study in Official Statistics and Social Control (Beckenham: Croom Helm, 1985); Rodney Lowe, Adjusting to Democracy. The Role of the Ministry of Labor in British Politics 1916 39 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986); Alastair Reid, Social Classes and Social Relations in Britain, 1850-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1992), Chapters 4-5. The classic study remains H. A Clegg, Alan Fox, and A. F. Thompson, A History of British Trade Unions since 1889. Vol. I 1889-1910 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1964).
    • (1985) Whitehall and the Labor Problem in Late-Victorian and Edwardian Britain. A Study in Official Statistics and Social Control
    • Davidson, R.1
  • 70
    • 84928448736 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • Roger Davidson, Whitehall and the Labor Problem in Late-Victorian and Edwardian Britain. A Study in Official Statistics and Social Control (Beckenham: Croom Helm, 1985); Rodney Lowe, Adjusting to Democracy. The Role of the Ministry of Labor in British Politics 1916 39 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986); Alastair Reid, Social Classes and Social Relations in Britain, 1850-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1992), Chapters 4-5. The classic study remains H. A Clegg, Alan Fox, and A. F. Thompson, A History of British Trade Unions since 1889. Vol. I 1889-1910 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1964).
    • (1986) Adjusting to Democracy. The Role of the Ministry of Labor in British Politics 1916-39
    • Lowe, R.1
  • 71
    • 0040692309 scopus 로고
    • (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press), Chapters 4-5
    • Roger Davidson, Whitehall and the Labor Problem in Late-Victorian and Edwardian Britain. A Study in Official Statistics and Social Control (Beckenham: Croom Helm, 1985); Rodney Lowe, Adjusting to Democracy. The Role of the Ministry of Labor in British Politics 1916 39 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986); Alastair Reid, Social Classes and Social Relations in Britain, 1850-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1992), Chapters 4-5. The classic study remains H. A Clegg, Alan Fox, and A. F. Thompson, A History of British Trade Unions since 1889. Vol. I 1889-1910 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1964).
    • (1992) Social Classes and Social Relations in Britain, 1850-1914
    • Reid, A.1
  • 72
    • 0003860441 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • Roger Davidson, Whitehall and the Labor Problem in Late-Victorian and Edwardian Britain. A Study in Official Statistics and Social Control (Beckenham: Croom Helm, 1985); Rodney Lowe, Adjusting to Democracy. The Role of the Ministry of Labor in British Politics 1916 39 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986); Alastair Reid, Social Classes and Social Relations in Britain, 1850-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1992), Chapters 4-5. The classic study remains H. A Clegg, Alan Fox, and A. F. Thompson, A History of British Trade Unions since 1889. Vol. I 1889-1910 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1964).
    • (1964) A History of British Trade Unions Since 1889. Vol. I 1889-1910 , vol.1
    • Clegg, H.A.1    Fox, A.2    Thompson, A.F.3
  • 73
    • 0003505928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago: U. of Chicago Press
    • With millennial timing, Robert Fogel has recently argued that religious awakenings are, indeed, the United States' motor force for social movements of this kind: Robert Fogel, The Fourth Great Awakening and the Future of Egalitarianism (Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 2000).
    • (2000) The Fourth Great Awakening and the Future of Egalitarianism
    • Fogel, R.1
  • 74
    • 0004130519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for an accessible summary statement of his work to date
    • See Amartya Sen, Development as Freedom (1999) for an accessible summary statement of his work to date.
    • (1999) Development as Freedom
    • Sen, A.1
  • 78
    • 0003442918 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic Books
    • Note, however, that there were also distinct limits to the scope of cross-class political imagination, trust and ingenuity shown in U.S. society at this time, as can be appreciated by comparing the gains made by the working classes in the United States with those made in Britain. There, the combination of relatively well-organized workers, with union membership already reaching over 40 percent of the labor force by the first decade of the twentieth century, along with significant middle-class ideological and political support from both the Fabian Socialists and the collectivist "New Liberals," resulted in the passing of the important 1908 national pensions and 1911 national insurance acts. The latter was in the teeth of the same kind of opposition from a coalition of both the middle-class insurance industry and the working-class provident institutions (led in the United States by Samuel Gompers, President of the A.F.L.) along with the medical profession, which were the set of oppositional forces that sank the American Progressives' attempts to organize a similar federal system of social security in the United States during the same period, 1910-1917. See Paul Starr, The Social Transformation of American Medicine (New York: Basic Books, 1982), 235-257. This also points to the importance of the rather different history and political complexion of the more modest American trade-union movement, which did not begin to follow the strategy of working-class inclusion, signalled in 1889 in Britain with the formation of the all-grades New Unions, until the formation of the Congress of Industrial Organizations (C.I.O) after 1935. On American trade-unionism, see David Montgomery, The Fall of the House of Labor. The Workplace, the State and American Labor Activism, 1865-1925 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1987); Frances Piven and Richard Cloward, Poor People's Movements. Why they Succeed, How they Fail (New York: Pantheon, 1977), Chapter 3.
    • (1982) The Social Transformation of American Medicine , pp. 235-257
    • Starr, P.1
  • 79
    • 0003885726 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press
    • Note, however, that there were also distinct limits to the scope of cross-class political imagination, trust and ingenuity shown in U.S. society at this time, as can be appreciated by comparing the gains made by the working classes in the United States with those made in Britain. There, the combination of relatively well-organized workers, with union membership already reaching over 40 percent of the labor force by the first decade of the twentieth century, along with significant middle-class ideological and political support from both the Fabian Socialists and the collectivist "New Liberals," resulted in the passing of the important 1908 national pensions and 1911 national insurance acts. The latter was in the teeth of the same kind of opposition from a coalition of both the middle-class insurance industry and the working-class provident institutions (led in the United States by Samuel Gompers, President of the A.F.L.) along with the medical profession, which were the set of oppositional forces that sank the American Progressives' attempts to organize a similar federal system of social security in the United States during the same period, 1910-1917. See Paul Starr, The Social Transformation of American Medicine (New York: Basic Books, 1982), 235-257. This also points to the importance of the rather different history and political complexion of the more modest American trade-union movement, which did not begin to follow the strategy of working-class inclusion, signalled in 1889 in Britain with the formation of the all-grades New Unions, until the formation of the Congress of Industrial Organizations (C.I.O) after 1935. On American trade-unionism, see David Montgomery, The Fall of the House of Labor. The Workplace, the State and American Labor Activism, 1865-1925 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1987); Frances Piven and Richard Cloward, Poor People's Movements. Why they Succeed, How they Fail (New York: Pantheon, 1977), Chapter 3.
    • (1987) The Fall of the House of Labor. The Workplace, the State and American Labor Activism, 1865-1925
    • Montgomery, D.1
  • 80
    • 0003761335 scopus 로고
    • (New York: Pantheon), Chapter 3
    • Note, however, that there were also distinct limits to the scope of cross-class political imagination, trust and ingenuity shown in U.S. society at this time, as can be appreciated by comparing the gains made by the working classes in the United States with those made in Britain. There, the combination of relatively well-organized workers, with union membership already reaching over 40 percent of the labor force by the first decade of the twentieth century, along with significant middle-class ideological and political support from both the Fabian Socialists and the collectivist "New Liberals," resulted in the passing of the important 1908 national pensions and 1911 national insurance acts. The latter was in the teeth of the same kind of opposition from a coalition of both the middle-class insurance industry and the working-class provident institutions (led in the United States by Samuel Gompers, President of the A.F.L.) along with the medical profession, which were the set of oppositional forces that sank the American Progressives' attempts to organize a similar federal system of social security in the United States during the same period, 1910-1917. See Paul Starr, The Social Transformation of American Medicine (New York: Basic Books, 1982), 235-257. This also points to the importance of the rather different history and political complexion of the more modest American trade-union movement, which did not begin to follow the strategy of working-class inclusion, signalled in 1889 in Britain with the formation of the all-grades New Unions, until the formation of the Congress of Industrial Organizations (C.I.O) after 1935. On American trade-unionism, see David Montgomery, The Fall of the House of Labor. The Workplace, the State and American Labor Activism, 1865-1925 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1987); Frances Piven and Richard Cloward, Poor People's Movements. Why they Succeed, How they Fail (New York: Pantheon, 1977), Chapter 3.
    • (1977) Poor People's Movements. Why They Succeed, How They Fail
    • Piven, F.1    Cloward, R.2
  • 81
    • 0003598816 scopus 로고
    • New York: Alfred A. Knopf
    • Richard Hosfstadter, The Age of Reform: From Bryan to F.D.R. (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1985); and see S. Brint and C. Levy, "Professions and civic engagement," ch. 5 in Skocpol and Fiorina, Civic Engagement, 163-210.
    • (1985) The Age of Reform: From Bryan to F.D.R.
    • Hosfstadter, R.1
  • 82
    • 0008034414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professions and civic engagement
    • ch. 5 in Skocpol and Fiorina
    • Richard Hosfstadter, The Age of Reform: From Bryan to F.D.R. (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1985); and see S. Brint and C. Levy, "Professions and civic engagement," ch. 5 in Skocpol and Fiorina, Civic Engagement, 163-210.
    • Civic Engagement , pp. 163-210
    • Brint, S.1    Levy, C.2
  • 84
    • 0009318070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Berkeley and Los Angeles: U. of California Press), Chapter 5
    • The theory of cultural bias holds that at any and all times the adversarial discourses within a liberal democracy will reflect a continuous flux of debate among four or five types of justificatory argument and their respective constituencies, comprising the opposed values of fatalism, autonomy, competitive individualism, egalitarianism, and hierarchy. On the theory of cultural bias, see Mary Douglas and Steven Ney, Missing Persons. A Critique of Personhood in the Social Sciences (Berkeley and Los Angeles: U. of California Press, 1998), Chapter 5. The original formulation of the theory was: Richard Ellis, Michael Thompson, and Aaron Wildavsky, Cultural Theory (Boulder, Col.: Westview Press).
    • (1998) Missing Persons. A Critique of Personhood in the Social Sciences
    • Douglas, M.1    Ney, S.2
  • 85
    • 84872767676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boulder, Col.: Westview Press
    • The theory of cultural bias holds that at any and all times the adversarial discourses within a liberal democracy will reflect a continuous flux of debate among four or five types of justificatory argument and their respective constituencies, comprising the opposed values of fatalism, autonomy, competitive individualism, egalitarianism, and hierarchy. On the theory of cultural bias, see Mary Douglas and Steven Ney, Missing Persons. A Critique of Personhood in the Social Sciences (Berkeley and Los Angeles: U. of California Press, 1998), Chapter 5. The original formulation of the theory was: Richard Ellis, Michael Thompson, and Aaron Wildavsky, Cultural Theory (Boulder, Col.: Westview Press).
    • Cultural Theory
    • Ellis, R.1    Thompson, M.2    Wildavsky, A.3
  • 86
    • 0004341025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • narrative account shows: Starr
    • From a comparative perspective, the obvious omission in this list of "state" achievements is the failure to establish a universalist, federally-funded national health service after World War II. Instead, a very comprehensive and generous program was established for Veterans and their families but not for the populace in general. In accounting for this difference it is perhaps relevant to note that America was the only major belligerent in the Second World War not to experience the devastation of a home front - on the contrary the war years of full employment were a period of great prosperity for business and the blue collar class, while the proportion of its male population who saw active service was significantly lower than the principal European nations involved. There was at the end of the war in the United States, correspondingly, much less of a sense that the populace as a whole had universally suffered in common and faced a life-threatening test together. It was this sense of national delivery, which provided the moral justification for the revolutionary and expensive act of collective expiation, which the establishment of the National Health Service in Britain by its first majority Labor government undoubtedly symbolized. By contrast, in the United States, no such collective symbolic capital could be mustered to overcome the opposition of the usual vested interests of the medical profession and the private insurance industry, as Paul Starr's narrative account shows: Starr, The Social Transformation, 280-289. Instead in the United States there was more of a sense that one large section of the nation owed a moral debt to another smaller part - the veterans - a debt that could be satisfied with a scheme specific to them.
    • The Social Transformation , pp. 280-289
    • Starr, P.1
  • 88
    • 0141801845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The evolving scope of government
    • Chapter 1 in Nye et al.
    • A telling observation made by Ernest R. May, "The Evolving Scope of Government," Chapter 1 in Nye et al., Why People, 45.
    • Why People , pp. 45
    • May, E.R.1
  • 89
    • 0141690213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is not, of course, intended to suggest that this shift was in any way monolithic nor that the positive public endorsement for the strong state was uniform throughout the later period. There were inevitably many local and individual variations of opinion, along with side eddies in the nation's changing mood, as the helpful theory of cultural bias makes clear. A particularly serious example of this was the menacing character, which agencies of the federal government assumed during the notorious episode of McCarthyism in the 1950s. But despite this and the alienation of the intellectual left, the general disposition of the populace toward the state remained, on balance, relatively positive through to the late 1960s.
  • 91
    • 0003617560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chapter 6
    • Wiebe, The Search for Order, Chapter 6, and pp. 166-176; and see the discussion of the local election battles, which Jane Addams of Hull House fought against the Chicago "boss," Johnny Powers, in the 1890s: Mary L. M. Bryan and Allen F. Davis, editors, 100 Years at Hull House (Bloomington: Indiana U. Press, 1990), 53-57. For more on one central aspect of this movement, see Barbara G. Rosenkrantz, Public Health and the State. Changing Views in Massachusetts, 1842-1936 (Cambridge: Harvard U. Press, 1972), esp. Chapters 3-4; John Duffy, The Sanitarians. A history of American Public Health (Urbana: U. of Illinois Press, 1990), Chapters 10-12.
    • The Search for Order , pp. 166-176
    • Wiebe1
  • 92
    • 0003749528 scopus 로고
    • Bloomington: Indiana U. Press
    • Wiebe, The Search for Order, Chapter 6, and pp. 166-176; and see the discussion of the local election battles, which Jane Addams of Hull House fought against the Chicago "boss," Johnny Powers, in the 1890s: Mary L. M. Bryan and Allen F. Davis, editors, 100 Years at Hull House (Bloomington: Indiana U. Press, 1990), 53-57. For more on one central aspect of this movement, see Barbara G. Rosenkrantz, Public Health and the State. Changing Views in Massachusetts, 1842-1936 (Cambridge: Harvard U. Press, 1972), esp. Chapters 3-4; John Duffy, The Sanitarians. A history of American Public Health (Urbana: U. of Illinois Press, 1990), Chapters 10-12.
    • (1990) 100 Years at Hull House , pp. 53-57
    • Bryan, M.L.M.1    Davis, A.F.2
  • 93
    • 0003918642 scopus 로고
    • (Cambridge: Harvard U. Press), esp. Chapters 3-4
    • Wiebe, The Search for Order, Chapter 6, and pp. 166-176; and see the discussion of the local election battles, which Jane Addams of Hull House fought against the Chicago "boss," Johnny Powers, in the 1890s: Mary L. M. Bryan and Allen F. Davis, editors, 100 Years at Hull House (Bloomington: Indiana U. Press, 1990), 53-57. For more on one central aspect of this movement, see Barbara G. Rosenkrantz, Public Health and the State. Changing Views in Massachusetts, 1842-1936 (Cambridge: Harvard U. Press, 1972), esp. Chapters 3-4; John Duffy, The Sanitarians. A history of American Public Health (Urbana: U. of Illinois Press, 1990), Chapters 10-12.
    • (1972) Public Health and the State. Changing Views in Massachusetts, 1842-1936
    • Rosenkrantz, B.G.1
  • 94
    • 0003936780 scopus 로고
    • (Urbana: U. of Illinois Press), Chapters 10-12
    • Wiebe, The Search for Order, Chapter 6, and pp. 166-176; and see the discussion of the local election battles, which Jane Addams of Hull House fought against the Chicago "boss," Johnny Powers, in the 1890s: Mary L. M. Bryan and Allen F. Davis, editors, 100 Years at Hull House (Bloomington: Indiana U. Press, 1990), 53-57. For more on one central aspect of this movement, see Barbara G. Rosenkrantz, Public Health and the State. Changing Views in Massachusetts, 1842-1936 (Cambridge: Harvard U. Press, 1972), esp. Chapters 3-4; John Duffy, The Sanitarians. A history of American Public Health (Urbana: U. of Illinois Press, 1990), Chapters 10-12.
    • (1990) The Sanitarians. A History of American Public Health
    • Duffy, J.1
  • 96
    • 0002440345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Americans became civic
    • Theda Skocpol and Morris Fiorina, editors, (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institute)
    • Theda Skocpol, with M. Ganz, Z. Munson, B. Camp, M. Sewers, and J. Oser, "How Americans Became Civic," in Theda Skocpol and Morris Fiorina, editors, Civic Engagement in American Democracy (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institute, 1999), 27-80.
    • (1999) Civic Engagement in American Democracy , pp. 27-80
    • Skocpol, T.1    Ganz, M.2    Munson, Z.3    Camp, B.4    Sewers, M.5    Oser, J.6
  • 97
    • 0003858824 scopus 로고
    • London: Institute of Economic Affairs
    • For examples of such right-wing analysis, see, for instance, D. Green, Re-inventing Civil Society. (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1994); D. Green, Community Without Politics (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1995).
    • (1994) Re-inventing Civil Society
    • Green, D.1
  • 98
    • 0004238982 scopus 로고
    • London: Institute of Economic Affairs
    • For examples of such right-wing analysis, see, for instance, D. Green, Re-inventing Civil Society. (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1994); D. Green, Community Without Politics (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1995).
    • (1995) Community Without Politics
    • Green, D.1
  • 99
    • 0141467022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See above, note 12
    • See above, note 12.
  • 100
    • 0003491150 scopus 로고
    • (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press), esp. ch. 3
    • Michael Mann, The Sources of Social Power. II. The rise of classes and nation-states, 1760-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1993), esp. ch. 3. Kenneth H. F. Dyson, The State Tradition in Western Europe: A Study of an Idea and Institution (Oxford: Robertson, 1980); Harold Perkin, The Rise of Professional Society. England Since 1880 (London: Routledge, 1989); Rolf Torstendahl and Michael Burrage, editors, The Formation of Professions. Knowledge, State and Strategy (London: Sage, 1990).
    • (1993) The Sources of Social Power. II. The Rise of Classes and Nation-states, 1760-1914
    • Mann, M.1
  • 101
    • 0003419855 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Robertson
    • Michael Mann, The Sources of Social Power. II. The rise of classes and nation-states, 1760-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1993), esp. ch. 3. Kenneth H. F. Dyson, The State Tradition in Western Europe: A Study of an Idea and Institution (Oxford: Robertson, 1980); Harold Perkin, The Rise of Professional Society. England Since 1880 (London: Routledge, 1989); Rolf Torstendahl and Michael Burrage, editors, The Formation of Professions. Knowledge, State and Strategy (London: Sage, 1990).
    • (1980) The State Tradition in Western Europe: A Study of an Idea and Institution
    • Dyson, K.H.F.1
  • 102
    • 84909033830 scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge
    • Michael Mann, The Sources of Social Power. II. The rise of classes and nation-states, 1760-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1993), esp. ch. 3. Kenneth H. F. Dyson, The State Tradition in Western Europe: A Study of an Idea and Institution (Oxford: Robertson, 1980); Harold Perkin, The Rise of Professional Society. England Since 1880 (London: Routledge, 1989); Rolf Torstendahl and Michael Burrage, editors, The Formation of Professions. Knowledge, State and Strategy (London: Sage, 1990).
    • (1989) The Rise of Professional Society. England Since 1880
    • Perkin, H.1
  • 103
    • 0040992570 scopus 로고
    • London: Sage
    • Michael Mann, The Sources of Social Power. II. The rise of classes and nation-states, 1760-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1993), esp. ch. 3. Kenneth H. F. Dyson, The State Tradition in Western Europe: A Study of an Idea and Institution (Oxford: Robertson, 1980); Harold Perkin, The Rise of Professional Society. England Since 1880 (London: Routledge, 1989); Rolf Torstendahl and Michael Burrage, editors, The Formation of Professions. Knowledge, State and Strategy (London: Sage, 1990).
    • (1990) The Formation of Professions. Knowledge, State and Strategy
  • 105
    • 0013351156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accounts of social capital: The mixed health effects of personal communities and voluntary groups
    • Chapter 8 in David Leon and Gill Walt, editors, (Oxford: Oxford U. Press)
    • Stephen J. Kunitz, "Accounts of Social Capital: The Mixed Health Effects of Personal Communities and Voluntary Groups," Chapter 8 in David Leon and Gill Walt, editors, Poverty, Inequality and Health. An International Perspective (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2001), 162-163.
    • (2001) Poverty, Inequality and Health. An International Perspective , pp. 162-163
    • Kunitz, S.J.1
  • 107
    • 0141578634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oscar Handlin and Mary Flug Handlin, Commonwealth. A Study of the Role of Government in the American Economy: Massachusetts, 1774-1861 (Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press, revised edition 1969, first published 1947); and for a recent survey of this work, see May "The Evolving," 29-36.
    • The Evolving , pp. 29-36
    • May1
  • 108
    • 0040803787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • preface to the first edition
    • Handlin and Handlin, Commonwealth, p. xvi (preface to the first edition).
    • Commonwealth
    • Handlin1    Handlin2
  • 110
    • 0141801842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. Hopkins Press
    • By 1860 municipalities had debts of $200 million to fund their activities, 3 times the federal debt: M. Melosi, The Sanitary City (J. Hopkins Press, 2000), 78. See also, Eric H. Monkkonen, The Local State: Public Money and American Cities (Stanford: Stanford U. Press, 1995).
    • (2000) The Sanitary City , pp. 78
    • Melosi, M.1
  • 111
    • 0003562404 scopus 로고
    • Stanford: Stanford U. Press
    • By 1860 municipalities had debts of $200 million to fund their activities, 3 times the federal debt: M. Melosi, The Sanitary City (J. Hopkins Press, 2000), 78. See also, Eric H. Monkkonen, The Local State: Public Money and American Cities (Stanford: Stanford U. Press, 1995).
    • (1995) The Local State: Public Money and American Cities
    • Monkkonen, E.H.1
  • 112
    • 0141690210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Samuel P. Huntington, "Americans and Their Government," p. 1, address to Visions of Governance for the twenty-first century conference, Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, 1996, cited in Gary Orren, "Fall from Grace: The Public's Loss of Faith in Government," Chapter 3 in Nye et al., Why People, 88-89.
    • Americans and Their Government , pp. 1
    • Huntington, S.P.1
  • 113
    • 0141801843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bretton Woods, New Hampshire
    • Samuel P. Huntington, "Americans and Their Government," p. 1, address to Visions of Governance for the twenty-first century conference, Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, 1996, cited in Gary Orren, "Fall from Grace: The Public's Loss of Faith in Government," Chapter 3 in Nye et al., Why People, 88-89.
    • (1996) Visions of Governance for the Twenty-First Century Conference
  • 114
    • 0141467023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fall from grace: The public's loss of faith in government
    • Chapter 3 in Nye et al.
    • Samuel P. Huntington, "Americans and Their Government," p. 1, address to Visions of Governance for the twenty-first century conference, Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, 1996, cited in Gary Orren, "Fall from Grace: The Public's Loss of Faith in Government," Chapter 3 in Nye et al., Why People, 88-89.
    • Why People , pp. 88-89
    • Orren, G.1
  • 115
    • 0141690212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The fact that this may have been accompanied also by an ambiguous popular attitude toward so much government, at times manifesting itself in great distrust, is entirely plausible, but this is an altogether different, and more subtle emphasis from the blunt view articulated in the citation from Huntington. This point about ambiguity and the continual possibility of alternatives would be the sort of interpretative viewpoint that the theory of cultural bias would - justifiably - insist upon (see note 33).
  • 116
    • 0003900237 scopus 로고
    • London: Tavistock
    • The most influential representative of the antagonistic position toward the liberal state within the post-structuralist and post-modernist stream has been Michel Foucault. See his initial contribution, Michel Foucault, The Order of Things. An Archeology of the Human Sciences (London: Tavistock, 1970); and, for a more ambivalent view of the state, see his later reflections, Michel Foucault, "Governmentality," (trans. R. Pasquino), in Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon, and Peter Miller, editors, The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality, with Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault (Hemel Hempstead: Harvester, 1991), 87-104. For an accessible overview of the whole field, see David Lyon, Postmodernity (Buckingham: Open U. Press, second edition 1999).
    • (1970) The Order of Things. An Archeology of the Human Sciences
    • Foucault, M.1
  • 117
    • 0001844449 scopus 로고
    • Governmentality
    • (trans. R. Pasquino), Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon, and Peter Miller, editors, (Hemel Hempstead: Harvester
    • The most influential representative of the antagonistic position toward the liberal state within the post-structuralist and post-modernist stream has been Michel Foucault. See his initial contribution, Michel Foucault, The Order of Things. An Archeology of the Human Sciences (London: Tavistock, 1970); and, for a more ambivalent view of the state, see his later reflections, Michel Foucault, "Governmentality," (trans. R. Pasquino), in Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon, and Peter Miller, editors, The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality, with Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault (Hemel Hempstead: Harvester, 1991), 87-104. For an accessible overview of the whole field, see David Lyon, Postmodernity (Buckingham: Open U. Press, second edition 1999).
    • (1991) The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality, with Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault , pp. 87-104
    • Foucault, M.1
  • 118
    • 0004172965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Buckingham: Open U. Press, second edition
    • The most influential representative of the antagonistic position toward the liberal state within the post-structuralist and post-modernist stream has been Michel Foucault. See his initial contribution, Michel Foucault, The Order of Things. An Archeology of the Human Sciences (London: Tavistock, 1970); and, for a more ambivalent view of the state, see his later reflections, Michel Foucault, "Governmentality," (trans. R. Pasquino), in Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon, and Peter Miller, editors, The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality, with Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault (Hemel Hempstead: Harvester, 1991), 87-104. For an accessible overview of the whole field, see David Lyon, Postmodernity (Buckingham: Open U. Press, second edition 1999).
    • (1999) Postmodernity
    • Lyon, D.1
  • 119
    • 0141801844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although it is arguable that New Zealand went in for this approach more deeply than any other western liberal democracy, coming to it rather late in the 1990s, but also it has pulled away, in repulsion from its consequences, most rapidly - in less than a decade.
  • 120
    • 0141467024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ch. 1
    • Skocpol and Fiorina, Civic Engagement, ch. 1, acknowledges that new forms of association seem more inward-looking, as does R. Wuthnow, "Mobilizing civic engagement," ch. 9, in the same volume.
    • Civic Engagement
    • Skocpol1    Fiorina2
  • 121
    • 0041086987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ch. 9, in the same volume
    • Skocpol and Fiorina, Civic Engagement, ch. 1, acknowledges that new forms of association seem more inward-looking, as does R. Wuthnow, "Mobilizing civic engagement," ch. 9, in the same volume.
    • Mobilizing Civic Engagement
    • Wuthnow, R.1
  • 122
    • 0001372820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic progress and the idea of social capital
    • Partha Dasgupta and Ismail Serageldin, editors, (Washington, D.C.: The World Bank)
    • For examples of an eminent economist's attempts to work with these problems, see Partha Dasgupta, "Economic Progress and the Idea of Social Capital," in Partha Dasgupta and Ismail Serageldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 2000); Partha Dasgupta, Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2001).
    • (2000) Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective
    • Dasgupta, P.1
  • 123
    • 0003954193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Oxford U. Press
    • For examples of an eminent economist's attempts to work with these problems, see Partha Dasgupta, "Economic Progress and the Idea of Social Capital," in Partha Dasgupta and Ismail Serageldin, editors, Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective (Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 2000); Partha Dasgupta, Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment (Oxford: Oxford U. Press, 2001).
    • (2001) Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment
    • Dasgupta, P.1
  • 127
    • 0032283968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From clientelism to cooperation: Local government, participatory policy, and civic organizing in Porto Alegre, Brazil
    • Rebecca Abers, "From Clientelism to Cooperation: Local Government, Participatory Policy, and Civic Organizing in Porto Alegre, Brazil," Politics and Society 26 (1998): 511-537. With thanks to Emilio Luque for alerting me to Abers' article.
    • (1998) Politics and Society , vol.26 , pp. 511-537
    • Abers, R.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.