-
1
-
-
0000071673
-
The affinity between ownership forms and coordination mechanisms
-
The literature on restructuring property rights in transition economies is too vast and expands too quickly to review. For a rich flavor of this literature, see Janos Kornai, "The Affinity between Ownership Forms and Coordination Mechanisms," Journal of Economic Perspective 4, no. 3 (1990): 131-47; Kazimierz Poznanski, "Restructuring of Property Rights in Poland: A Study in Evolutionary Economics," East European Politics and Societies 7, no. 3 (1993): 395-421; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101, no. 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Weimer, ed., The Political Economy of Property Rights: Institutional Change and Credibility in the Reform of Centrally Planned Economies (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999).
-
(1990)
Journal of Economic Perspective
, vol.4
, Issue.3
, pp. 131-147
-
-
Kornai, J.1
-
2
-
-
21344492039
-
Restructuring of property rights in Poland: A study in evolutionary economics
-
The literature on restructuring property rights in transition economies is too vast and expands too quickly to review. For a rich flavor of this literature, see Janos Kornai, "The Affinity between Ownership Forms and Coordination Mechanisms," Journal of Economic Perspective 4, no. 3 (1990): 131-47; Kazimierz Poznanski, "Restructuring of Property Rights in Poland: A Study in Evolutionary Economics," East European Politics and Societies 7, no. 3 (1993): 395-421; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101, no. 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Weimer, ed., The Political Economy of Property Rights: Institutional Change and Credibility in the Reform of Centrally Planned Economies (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999).
-
(1993)
East European Politics and Societies
, vol.7
, Issue.3
, pp. 395-421
-
-
Poznanski, K.1
-
3
-
-
0030463090
-
Recombinant property in East European capitalism
-
The literature on restructuring property rights in transition economies is too vast and expands too quickly to review. For a rich flavor of this literature, see Janos Kornai, "The Affinity between Ownership Forms and Coordination Mechanisms," Journal of Economic Perspective 4, no. 3 (1990): 131-47; Kazimierz Poznanski, "Restructuring of Property Rights in Poland: A Study in Evolutionary Economics," East European Politics and Societies 7, no. 3 (1993): 395-421; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101, no. 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Weimer, ed., The Political Economy of Property Rights: Institutional Change and Credibility in the Reform of Centrally Planned Economies (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999).
-
(1996)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.101
, Issue.4
, pp. 993-1027
-
-
Stark, D.1
-
4
-
-
0004048646
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
The literature on restructuring property rights in transition economies is too vast and expands too quickly to review. For a rich flavor of this literature, see Janos Kornai, "The Affinity between Ownership Forms and Coordination Mechanisms," Journal of Economic Perspective 4, no. 3 (1990): 131-47; Kazimierz Poznanski, "Restructuring of Property Rights in Poland: A Study in Evolutionary Economics," East European Politics and Societies 7, no. 3 (1993): 395-421; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101, no. 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Weimer, ed., The Political Economy of Property Rights: Institutional Change and Credibility in the Reform of Centrally Planned Economies (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999).
-
(1997)
The Political Economy of Property Rights: Institutional Change and Credibility in the Reform of Centrally Planned Economies
-
-
Weimer, D.1
-
5
-
-
0003515764
-
-
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press
-
The literature on restructuring property rights in transition economies is too vast and expands too quickly to review. For a rich flavor of this literature, see Janos Kornai, "The Affinity between Ownership Forms and Coordination Mechanisms," Journal of Economic Perspective 4, no. 3 (1990): 131-47; Kazimierz Poznanski, "Restructuring of Property Rights in Poland: A Study in Evolutionary Economics," East European Politics and Societies 7, no. 3 (1993): 395-421; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101, no. 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Weimer, ed., The Political Economy of Property Rights: Institutional Change and Credibility in the Reform of Centrally Planned Economies (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999).
-
(1999)
Property Rights and Economic Reform in China
-
-
Oi, J.1
Walder, A.2
-
6
-
-
0003534837
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Yoram Barzel, Economic Analysis of Property Rights, 2d ed. (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990).
-
(1997)
Economic Analysis of Property Rights, 2d Ed.
-
-
Barzel, Y.1
-
7
-
-
0003540038
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Yoram Barzel, Economic Analysis of Property Rights, 2d ed. (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990).
-
(1990)
Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance
-
-
North, D.1
-
8
-
-
0003459520
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Douglass North and Robert Thomas, The Rise of the Western World (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1973); Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981); Nathan Rosenberg and L. E. Bridzell, How the West Got Rich (New York: Basic Books, 1986).
-
(1973)
The Rise of the Western World
-
-
North, D.1
Thomas, R.2
-
9
-
-
0003542293
-
-
New York: Norton
-
Douglass North and Robert Thomas, The Rise of the Western World (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1973); Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981); Nathan Rosenberg and L. E. Bridzell, How the West Got Rich (New York: Basic Books, 1986).
-
(1981)
Structure and Change in Economic History
-
-
North, D.1
-
10
-
-
0003622091
-
-
New York: Basic Books
-
Douglass North and Robert Thomas, The Rise of the Western World (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1973); Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981); Nathan Rosenberg and L. E. Bridzell, How the West Got Rich (New York: Basic Books, 1986).
-
(1986)
How the West Got Rich
-
-
Rosenberg, N.1
Bridzell, L.E.2
-
11
-
-
84935987730
-
The institutional framework and economic development
-
Gerald Scully, "The Institutional Framework and Economic Development," Journal of Political Economy 96, no. 3 (1988): 652-62; J. Torstensson, "Property Rights and Economic Growth," Kyklos 47, no. 2 (1994): 231-47; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Institutions and Economic Performance," Economics and Politics 7, no. 2 (1995): 207-27.
-
(1988)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.96
, Issue.3
, pp. 652-662
-
-
Scully, G.1
-
12
-
-
0028561171
-
Property rights and economic growth
-
Gerald Scully, "The Institutional Framework and Economic Development," Journal of Political Economy 96, no. 3 (1988): 652-62; J. Torstensson, "Property Rights and Economic Growth," Kyklos 47, no. 2 (1994): 231-47; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Institutions and Economic Performance," Economics and Politics 7, no. 2 (1995): 207-27.
-
(1994)
Kyklos
, vol.47
, Issue.2
, pp. 231-247
-
-
Torstensson, J.1
-
13
-
-
84984517112
-
Institutions and economic performance
-
Gerald Scully, "The Institutional Framework and Economic Development," Journal of Political Economy 96, no. 3 (1988): 652-62; J. Torstensson, "Property Rights and Economic Growth," Kyklos 47, no. 2 (1994): 231-47; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, "Institutions and Economic Performance," Economics and Politics 7, no. 2 (1995): 207-27.
-
(1995)
Economics and Politics
, vol.7
, Issue.2
, pp. 207-227
-
-
Knack, S.1
Keefer, P.2
-
15
-
-
0039198262
-
-
North, Institutions; Andrei Shleifer, "Establishing Property Rights," in M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic, eds., Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1995); Weimer, The Political.
-
Institutions
-
-
North1
-
16
-
-
0001903830
-
Establishing property rights
-
M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic, eds., Washington, DC: World Bank
-
North, Institutions; Andrei Shleifer, "Establishing Property Rights," in M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic, eds., Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1995); Weimer, The Political.
-
(1995)
Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics
-
-
Shleifer, A.1
-
17
-
-
84886085373
-
-
North, Institutions; Andrei Shleifer, "Establishing Property Rights," in M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic, eds., Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1995); Weimer, The Political.
-
The Political
-
-
Weimer1
-
20
-
-
0002179491
-
Corporation organization and local government property rights in China
-
V. Milor, ed., Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner
-
Even in public sectors there exist diverse routes to property rights reforms. Walder recognizes that privatization is one among many choices. See Andrew Walder, "Corporation Organization and Local Government Property Rights in China," in V. Milor, ed., Changing Political Economies: Privatization in Post-Communist and Reforming Communist States (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 1994); Oi and Walder, Property. Stark stresses the feature of path dependence in property rights reforms, challenging the unquestioned universal validity of privatization in transition economies. See Stark, "Recombinant."
-
(1994)
Changing Political Economies: Privatization in Post-Communist and Reforming Communist States
-
-
Walder, A.1
-
21
-
-
85037277561
-
-
Even in public sectors there exist diverse routes to property rights reforms. Walder recognizes that privatization is one among many choices. See Andrew Walder, "Corporation Organization and Local Government Property Rights in China," in V. Milor, ed., Changing Political Economies: Privatization in Post-Communist and Reforming Communist States (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 1994); Oi and Walder, Property. Stark stresses the feature of path dependence in property rights reforms, challenging the unquestioned universal validity of privatization in transition economies. See Stark, "Recombinant."
-
Property
-
-
Oi1
Walder2
-
22
-
-
85037285684
-
-
Even in public sectors there exist diverse routes to property rights reforms. Walder recognizes that privatization is one among many choices. See Andrew Walder, "Corporation Organization and Local Government Property Rights in China," in V. Milor, ed., Changing Political Economies: Privatization in Post-Communist and Reforming Communist States (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 1994); Oi and Walder, Property. Stark stresses the feature of path dependence in property rights reforms, challenging the unquestioned universal validity of privatization in transition economies. See Stark, "Recombinant."
-
Recombinant
-
-
Stark1
-
23
-
-
84929744029
-
Economics and the Russian transition
-
It is well-known that China's success in economic reforms is primarily due to the rise of new private sectors, particularly the township and village enterprises. Even in Russia and other transition economies, where privatization is the main reform strategy, new enterprises rather than privatized ones perform better. See Richard Ericson, "Economics and the Russian Transition," Slavic Review 57, no. 3 (1998): 609-25.
-
(1998)
Slavic Review
, vol.57
, Issue.3
, pp. 609-625
-
-
Ericson, R.1
-
24
-
-
27644496060
-
-
The booming literature is impressive on property rights transformation in Chinese reforms, see, for example, Walder, "Corporation"; David Li, "A Theory of Ambiguous Property Rights in Transition Economies: The Case of Chinese Non-State Sector," Journal of Comparative Economics 23, no. 1 (1996): 1-19; Martin Weizman and Chenggang Xu, "Chinese Township and Village Enterprises as Vaguely Defined Cooperatives," in John Romer, ed., Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare (New York: St. Martin's Press, International Economic Association, 1997); Jiahua Che and Yingyi Qian, "Insecure Property Rights and Government Ownership of Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no. 2 (1998): 467-96; Oi and Walder, Property. These studies, however, with the exception of Oi and Walder, only tangentially, if not at all, touch on the process of property rights transformation.
-
Corporation
-
-
Walder1
-
25
-
-
0030211236
-
A theory of ambiguous property rights in transition economies: The case of chinese non-state sector
-
The booming literature is impressive on property rights transformation in Chinese reforms, see, for example, Walder, "Corporation"; David Li, "A Theory of Ambiguous Property Rights in Transition Economies: The Case of Chinese Non-State Sector," Journal of Comparative Economics 23, no. 1 (1996): 1-19; Martin Weizman and Chenggang Xu, "Chinese Township and Village Enterprises as Vaguely Defined Cooperatives," in John Romer, ed., Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare (New York: St. Martin's Press, International Economic Association, 1997); Jiahua Che and Yingyi Qian, "Insecure Property Rights and Government Ownership of Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no. 2 (1998): 467-96; Oi and Walder, Property. These studies, however, with the exception of Oi and Walder, only tangentially, if not at all, touch on the process of property rights transformation.
-
(1996)
Journal of Comparative Economics
, vol.23
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-19
-
-
Li, D.1
-
26
-
-
0012570325
-
Chinese township and village enterprises as vaguely defined cooperatives
-
John Romer, ed., New York: St. Martin's Press, International Economic Association
-
The booming literature is impressive on property rights transformation in Chinese reforms, see, for example, Walder, "Corporation"; David Li, "A Theory of Ambiguous Property Rights in Transition Economies: The Case of Chinese Non-State Sector," Journal of Comparative Economics 23, no. 1 (1996): 1-19; Martin Weizman and Chenggang Xu, "Chinese Township and Village Enterprises as Vaguely Defined Cooperatives," in John Romer, ed., Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare (New York: St. Martin's Press, International Economic Association, 1997); Jiahua Che and Yingyi Qian, "Insecure Property Rights and Government Ownership of Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no. 2 (1998): 467-96; Oi and Walder, Property. These studies, however, with the exception of Oi and Walder, only tangentially, if not at all, touch on the process of property rights transformation.
-
(1997)
Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare
-
-
Weizman, M.1
Xu, C.2
-
27
-
-
0039403204
-
Insecure property rights and government ownership of firms
-
The booming literature is impressive on property rights transformation in Chinese reforms, see, for example, Walder, "Corporation"; David Li, "A Theory of Ambiguous Property Rights in Transition Economies: The Case of Chinese Non-State Sector," Journal of Comparative Economics 23, no. 1 (1996): 1-19; Martin Weizman and Chenggang Xu, "Chinese Township and Village Enterprises as Vaguely Defined Cooperatives," in John Romer, ed., Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare (New York: St. Martin's Press, International Economic Association, 1997); Jiahua Che and Yingyi Qian, "Insecure Property Rights and Government Ownership of Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no. 2 (1998): 467-96; Oi and Walder, Property. These studies, however, with the exception of Oi and Walder, only tangentially, if not at all, touch on the process of property rights transformation.
-
(1998)
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, vol.113
, Issue.2
, pp. 467-496
-
-
Che, J.1
Qian, Y.2
-
28
-
-
85037277561
-
-
The booming literature is impressive on property rights transformation in Chinese reforms, see, for example, Walder, "Corporation"; David Li, "A Theory of Ambiguous Property Rights in Transition Economies: The Case of Chinese Non-State Sector," Journal of Comparative Economics 23, no. 1 (1996): 1-19; Martin Weizman and Chenggang Xu, "Chinese Township and Village Enterprises as Vaguely Defined Cooperatives," in John Romer, ed., Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare (New York: St. Martin's Press, International Economic Association, 1997); Jiahua Che and Yingyi Qian, "Insecure Property Rights and Government Ownership of Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no. 2 (1998): 467-96; Oi and Walder, Property. These studies, however, with the exception of Oi and Walder, only tangentially, if not at all, touch on the process of property rights transformation.
-
Property
-
-
Oi1
Walder2
-
29
-
-
0014413249
-
The tragedy of the commons
-
Garrett Hardin, "The Tragedy of the Commons," Science 162, (1969): 1243-48. For two classic studies of open access fisheries, see H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery," Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 2 (1954): 124-42; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Nonexclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics 13, no. 1 (1970): 49-70. Scholars have recently begun to differentiate between "open access" and "common property." See Elinor Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Daniel Bromley, Environment and the Economy (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991). According to Baland and Platteau, open access and common property are essentially different in so far as, in a common property, the community has the right to exclude nonmembers from the use of the resource. Under common property, the right of exclusion is assigned to a well-defined group. Under open access, a right of inclusion is granted to anyone who wants to use the resource. See Jean-Marie Baland and Jean Platteau, Halting Degradation of Natural Resource (New York: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 1996), 29 . In the light of this distinction, this study is actually concerned with open access resources rather than common property resources, though we continue to use the traditional metaphor, "the tragedy of the commons."
-
(1969)
Science
, vol.162
, pp. 1243-1248
-
-
Hardin, G.1
-
30
-
-
0014413249
-
The economic theory of a common property resource: The fishery
-
Garrett Hardin, "The Tragedy of the Commons," Science 162, (1969): 1243-48. For two classic studies of open access fisheries, see H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery," Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 2 (1954): 124-42; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Nonexclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics 13, no. 1 (1970): 49-70. Scholars have recently begun to differentiate between "open access" and "common property." See Elinor Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Daniel Bromley, Environment and the Economy (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991). According to Baland and Platteau, open access and common property are essentially different in so far as, in a common property, the community has the right to exclude nonmembers from the use of the resource. Under common property, the right of exclusion is assigned to a well-defined group. Under open access, a right of inclusion is granted to anyone who wants to use the resource. See Jean-Marie Baland and Jean Platteau, Halting Degradation of Natural Resource (New York: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 1996), 29 . In the light of this distinction, this study is actually concerned with open access resources rather than common property resources, though we continue to use the traditional metaphor, "the tragedy of the commons."
-
(1954)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.62
, Issue.2
, pp. 124-142
-
-
Gordon, H.S.1
-
31
-
-
0014413249
-
The structure of a contract and the theory of nonexclusive resource
-
Garrett Hardin, "The Tragedy of the Commons," Science 162, (1969): 1243-48. For two classic studies of open access fisheries, see H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery," Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 2 (1954): 124-42; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Nonexclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics 13, no. 1 (1970): 49-70. Scholars have recently begun to differentiate between "open access" and "common property." See Elinor Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Daniel Bromley, Environment and the Economy (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991). According to Baland and Platteau, open access and common property are essentially different in so far as, in a common property, the community has the right to exclude nonmembers from the use of the resource. Under common property, the right of exclusion is assigned to a well-defined group. Under open access, a right of inclusion is granted to anyone who wants to use the resource. See Jean-Marie Baland and Jean Platteau, Halting Degradation of Natural Resource (New York: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 1996), 29 . In the light of this distinction, this study is actually concerned with open access resources rather than common property resources, though we continue to use the traditional metaphor, "the tragedy of the commons."
-
(1970)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.13
, Issue.1
, pp. 49-70
-
-
Cheung, S.N.S.1
-
32
-
-
85040890266
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Garrett Hardin, "The Tragedy of the Commons," Science 162, (1969): 1243-48. For two classic studies of open access fisheries, see H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery," Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 2 (1954): 124-42; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Nonexclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics 13, no. 1 (1970): 49-70. Scholars have recently begun to differentiate between "open access" and "common property." See Elinor Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Daniel Bromley, Environment and the Economy (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991). According to Baland and Platteau, open access and common property are essentially different in so far as, in a common property, the community has the right to exclude nonmembers from the use of the resource. Under common property, the right of exclusion is assigned to a well-defined group. Under open access, a right of inclusion is granted to anyone who wants to use the resource. See Jean-Marie Baland and Jean Platteau, Halting Degradation of Natural Resource (New York: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 1996), 29 . In the light of this distinction, this study is actually concerned with open access resources rather than common property resources, though we continue to use the traditional metaphor, "the tragedy of the commons."
-
(1990)
Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action
-
-
Ostrom, E.1
-
33
-
-
0014413249
-
-
Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell
-
Garrett Hardin, "The Tragedy of the Commons," Science 162, (1969): 1243-48. For two classic studies of open access fisheries, see H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery," Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 2 (1954): 124-42; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Nonexclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics 13, no. 1 (1970): 49-70. Scholars have recently begun to differentiate between "open access" and "common property." See Elinor Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Daniel Bromley, Environment and the Economy (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991). According to Baland and Platteau, open access and common property are essentially different in so far as, in a common property, the community has the right to exclude nonmembers from the use of the resource. Under common property, the right of exclusion is assigned to a well-defined group. Under open access, a right of inclusion is granted to anyone who wants to use the resource. See Jean-Marie Baland and Jean Platteau, Halting Degradation of Natural Resource (New York: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 1996), 29 . In the light of this distinction, this study is actually concerned with open access resources rather than common property resources, though we continue to use the traditional metaphor, "the tragedy of the commons."
-
(1991)
Environment and the Economy
-
-
Bromley, D.1
-
34
-
-
0014413249
-
-
New York: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations
-
Garrett Hardin, "The Tragedy of the Commons," Science 162, (1969): 1243-48. For two classic studies of open access fisheries, see H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery," Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 2 (1954): 124-42; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Nonexclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics 13, no. 1 (1970): 49-70. Scholars have recently begun to differentiate between "open access" and "common property." See Elinor Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Daniel Bromley, Environment and the Economy (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991). According to Baland and Platteau, open access and common property are essentially different in so far as, in a common property, the community has the right to exclude nonmembers from the use of the resource. Under common property, the right of exclusion is assigned to a well-defined group. Under open access, a right of inclusion is granted to anyone who wants to use the resource. See Jean-Marie Baland and Jean Platteau, Halting Degradation of Natural Resource (New York: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 1996), 29 . In the light of this distinction, this study is actually concerned with open access resources rather than common property resources, though we continue to use the traditional metaphor, "the tragedy of the commons."
-
(1996)
Halting Degradation of Natural Resource
, pp. 29
-
-
Baland, J.-M.1
Platteau, J.2
-
35
-
-
85037273994
-
-
We are interested in changes of practical or economic property rights, not legal rights. In this case, legal rules have hardly changed. For the distinction between practical and legal rights, see Barzel, Economic, 3.
-
Economic
, pp. 3
-
-
Barzel1
-
36
-
-
0001625177
-
The new institutional economics
-
Ronald Coase, "The New Institutional Economics," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 140, no. 1 (1984): 229-31; Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); North, Institutions; Erik Furubotn and Rudolf Richter, Institutions and Economic Theory (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997).
-
(1984)
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
, vol.140
, Issue.1
, pp. 229-231
-
-
Coase, R.1
-
37
-
-
0003788290
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Ronald Coase, "The New Institutional Economics," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 140, no. 1 (1984): 229-31; Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); North, Institutions; Erik Furubotn and Rudolf Richter, Institutions and Economic Theory (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997).
-
(1990)
Economic Behavior and Institutions
-
-
Eggertsson, T.1
-
38
-
-
0039198262
-
-
Ronald Coase, "The New Institutional Economics," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 140, no. 1 (1984): 229-31; Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); North, Institutions; Erik Furubotn and Rudolf Richter, Institutions and Economic Theory (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997).
-
Institutions
-
-
North1
-
39
-
-
0003495878
-
-
Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
-
Ronald Coase, "The New Institutional Economics," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 140, no. 1 (1984): 229-31; Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); North, Institutions; Erik Furubotn and Rudolf Richter, Institutions and Economic Theory (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997).
-
(1997)
Institutions and Economic Theory
-
-
Furubotn, E.1
Richter, R.2
-
42
-
-
85037277760
-
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 247-77; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 104-14. Classical writings on property rights include Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44; Armen Alchian, "Some Economics of Property Rights," IL Politico 30, (1965): 916-29; Harold Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347-59; North, Structure; Barzel, Economic.
-
Economic
, pp. 247-277
-
-
Eggertsson1
-
43
-
-
85037261502
-
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 247-77; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 104-14. Classical writings on property rights include Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44; Armen Alchian, "Some Economics of Property Rights," IL Politico 30, (1965): 916-29; Harold Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347-59; North, Structure; Barzel, Economic.
-
Institutions
, pp. 104-114
-
-
Furubotn1
Richter2
-
44
-
-
0002071502
-
The problem of social cost
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 247-77; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 104-14. Classical writings on property rights include Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44; Armen Alchian, "Some Economics of Property Rights," IL Politico 30, (1965): 916-29; Harold Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347-59; North, Structure; Barzel, Economic.
-
(1960)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.3
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-44
-
-
Coase, R.1
-
45
-
-
0001332619
-
Some economics of property rights
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 247-77; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 104-14. Classical writings on property rights include Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44; Armen Alchian, "Some Economics of Property Rights," IL Politico 30, (1965): 916-29; Harold Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347-59; North, Structure; Barzel, Economic.
-
(1965)
IL Politico
, vol.30
, pp. 916-929
-
-
Alchian, A.1
-
46
-
-
0001394870
-
Toward a theory of property rights
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 247-77; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 104-14. Classical writings on property rights include Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44; Armen Alchian, "Some Economics of Property Rights," IL Politico 30, (1965): 916-29; Harold Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347-59; North, Structure; Barzel, Economic.
-
(1967)
American Economic Review
, vol.57
, Issue.2
, pp. 347-359
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
-
47
-
-
84876620930
-
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 247-77; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 104-14. Classical writings on property rights include Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44; Armen Alchian, "Some Economics of Property Rights," IL Politico 30, (1965): 916-29; Harold Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347-59; North, Structure; Barzel, Economic.
-
Structure
-
-
North1
-
48
-
-
85037273994
-
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 247-77; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 104-14. Classical writings on property rights include Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44; Armen Alchian, "Some Economics of Property Rights," IL Politico 30, (1965): 916-29; Harold Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347-59; North, Structure; Barzel, Economic.
-
Economic
-
-
Barzel1
-
49
-
-
85037270185
-
-
Demsetz, "Toward"; North and Thomas, The Rise.
-
Toward
-
-
Demsetz1
-
51
-
-
0002320855
-
Distributional issues in contracting for property rights
-
Gary Libecap, "Distributional Issues in Contracting for Property Rights," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 145, no. 1 (1989): 6-24; Gary Libecap, Contracting for Property Rights (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jack Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992).
-
(1989)
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
, vol.145
, Issue.1
, pp. 6-24
-
-
Libecap, G.1
-
52
-
-
0003647049
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Gary Libecap, "Distributional Issues in Contracting for Property Rights," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 145, no. 1 (1989): 6-24; Gary Libecap, Contracting for Property Rights (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jack Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992).
-
(1989)
Contracting for Property Rights
-
-
Libecap, G.1
-
53
-
-
0004224103
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Gary Libecap, "Distributional Issues in Contracting for Property Rights," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 145, no. 1 (1989): 6-24; Gary Libecap, Contracting for Property Rights (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jack Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992).
-
(1992)
Institutions and Social Conflict
-
-
Knight, J.1
-
57
-
-
84958358489
-
-
North and Thomas, The Rise; Lance Davis and Douglass North, Institutional Change and American Economic Growth (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1971); Terry Anderson and P. J. Hill, "The Evolution of Property Rights: A Study of the American West," Journal of Law and Economics 18, no. 1 (1975): 163-79.
-
The Rise
-
-
North1
Thomas2
-
58
-
-
0003813846
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
North and Thomas, The Rise; Lance Davis and Douglass North, Institutional Change and American Economic Growth (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1971); Terry Anderson and P. J. Hill, "The Evolution of Property Rights: A Study of the American West," Journal of Law and Economics 18, no. 1 (1975): 163-79.
-
(1971)
Institutional Change and American Economic Growth
-
-
Davis, L.1
North, D.2
-
59
-
-
84917275342
-
The evolution of property rights: A study of the American West
-
North and Thomas, The Rise; Lance Davis and Douglass North, Institutional Change and American Economic Growth (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1971); Terry Anderson and P. J. Hill, "The Evolution of Property Rights: A Study of the American West," Journal of Law and Economics 18, no. 1 (1975): 163-79.
-
(1975)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.18
, Issue.1
, pp. 163-179
-
-
Anderson, T.1
Hill, P.J.2
-
60
-
-
85037277760
-
-
Eggertsson, Economic, 250; Furubotn and Richter, Institutions, 108.
-
Economic
, pp. 250
-
-
Eggertsson1
-
65
-
-
0040477843
-
The new
-
Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
This emphasis on actors in new institutional economics is attributable to Coase. See Coase, "The New" and The Firm, the Market, and the Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988). Rational choice sociologists have traditionally stressed action and agency. See, for example, George Homans, "Bring Men Back in," American Sociological Review 29, no. 6 (1964): 809-18; Michael Hechter, ed., The Microfoundations of Macrosociology (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983); James Coleman, "Social Theory, Social Research, and a Theory of Action," American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 6 (1986): 1309-35.
-
(1988)
The Firm, the Market, and the Law
-
-
Coase1
-
66
-
-
84977051366
-
Bring men back
-
This emphasis on actors in new institutional economics is attributable to Coase. See Coase, "The New" and The Firm, the Market, and the Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988). Rational choice sociologists have traditionally stressed action and agency. See, for example, George Homans, "Bring Men Back in," American Sociological Review 29, no. 6 (1964): 809-18; Michael Hechter, ed., The Microfoundations of Macrosociology (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983); James Coleman, "Social Theory, Social Research, and a Theory of Action," American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 6 (1986): 1309-35.
-
(1964)
American Sociological Review
, vol.29
, Issue.6
, pp. 809-818
-
-
Homans, G.1
-
67
-
-
0041127494
-
-
Philadelphia: Temple University Press
-
This emphasis on actors in new institutional economics is attributable to Coase. See Coase, "The New" and The Firm, the Market, and the Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988). Rational choice sociologists have traditionally stressed action and agency. See, for example, George Homans, "Bring Men Back in," American Sociological Review 29, no. 6 (1964): 809-18; Michael Hechter, ed., The Microfoundations of Macrosociology (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983); James Coleman, "Social Theory, Social Research, and a Theory of Action," American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 6 (1986): 1309-35.
-
(1983)
The Microfoundations of Macrosociology
-
-
Hechter, M.1
-
68
-
-
84936628467
-
Social theory, social research, and a theory of action
-
This emphasis on actors in new institutional economics is attributable to Coase. See Coase, "The New" and The Firm, the Market, and the Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988). Rational choice sociologists have traditionally stressed action and agency. See, for example, George Homans, "Bring Men Back in," American Sociological Review 29, no. 6 (1964): 809-18; Michael Hechter, ed., The Microfoundations of Macrosociology (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983); James Coleman, "Social Theory, Social Research, and a Theory of Action," American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 6 (1986): 1309-35.
-
(1986)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.91
, Issue.6
, pp. 1309-1335
-
-
Coleman, J.1
-
71
-
-
84935412452
-
The pointless of Pareto
-
Guido Calabresi, "The Pointless of Pareto," Yale Law Review 100, no. 2 (1991): 1211-37; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Transaction Costs Paradigm," Economic Inquiry 36, no. 4 (1998): 514-21.
-
(1991)
Yale Law Review
, vol.100
, Issue.2
, pp. 1211-1237
-
-
Calabresi, G.1
-
72
-
-
0032243865
-
The transaction costs paradigm
-
Guido Calabresi, "The Pointless of Pareto," Yale Law Review 100, no. 2 (1991): 1211-37; Steven N. S. Cheung, "The Transaction Costs Paradigm," Economic Inquiry 36, no. 4 (1998): 514-21.
-
(1998)
Economic Inquiry
, vol.36
, Issue.4
, pp. 514-521
-
-
Cheung, S.N.S.1
-
77
-
-
0040914237
-
Transaction costs and the structure of the market
-
Ning Wang, "Transaction Costs and the Structure of the Market," American Journal of Economics and Sociology 58, no. 4 (1999): 783-805.
-
(1999)
American Journal of Economics and Sociology
, vol.58
, Issue.4
, pp. 783-805
-
-
Wang, N.1
-
78
-
-
0004083437
-
-
New York: Basic Books
-
See Clifford Geertz, The Interpretation of Cultures (New York: Basic Books, 1973). But Popper proposed a different view on subjectivity in social sciences. See Karl Popper, "The Logic of Social Sciences," in Theodor Adorno, ed., Positivist Dispute in German Sociology (New York: Harper, 1976).
-
(1973)
The Interpretation of Cultures
-
-
Geertz, C.1
-
79
-
-
0006715543
-
The logic of social sciences
-
Theodor Adorno, ed., New York: Harper
-
See Clifford Geertz, The Interpretation of Cultures (New York: Basic Books, 1973). But Popper proposed a different view on subjectivity in social sciences. See Karl Popper, "The Logic of Social Sciences," in Theodor Adorno, ed., Positivist Dispute in German Sociology (New York: Harper, 1976).
-
(1976)
Positivist Dispute in German Sociology
-
-
Popper, K.1
-
80
-
-
85037276632
-
-
note
-
Two factors discouraged peasants on the south side to continue fishing in the lake. First, close to Jingzhou, they had much more alternative opportunities. Second, since the Longlake Fishing Farm (LLFF) was located on the same side, these peasants could be quite effectively deterred from fishing in the lake.
-
-
-
-
84
-
-
84904233793
-
-
Ostrom, Governing; Bromley, Environment; Baland and Platteau, Halting.
-
Governing
-
-
Ostrom1
-
85
-
-
57349187717
-
-
Ostrom, Governing; Bromley, Environment; Baland and Platteau, Halting.
-
Environment
-
-
Bromley1
-
88
-
-
84953202904
-
Peasant household individualism
-
William Parish, ed., Armonk, NY: Sharpe
-
Victor Nee, "Peasant Household Individualism," in William Parish, ed., Chinese Rural Development: The Great Transformation (Armonk, NY: Sharpe, 1985), 164-90.
-
(1985)
Chinese Rural Development: The Great Transformation
, pp. 164-190
-
-
Victor, N.1
-
89
-
-
85037278089
-
-
note
-
Best bundles of durable goods are represented by the so-called three big items and three new big items. In this region, the bicycle, radio, and watch constituted the "three big items" in the 1970s and early 1980s. They were later gradually replaced by the "three new big items": the electrical fan, TV, and sewing machine. These consumer goods once commanded the most popularity among rural households.
-
-
-
-
90
-
-
85037286824
-
-
note
-
One may counterargue that the change of consumption pattern is a mere consequence of the increase of income. However, no one can deny that the change of consumption pattern has a recursive effect, that is, generating more demand for cash. Moreover, it is contagious. The change of consumption pattern in one group has demonstrating or rippling effects and stimulates others to follow the suit. As a result, the change of preference put dramatic pressures on fisheries, a main source of cash income for peasants.
-
-
-
-
92
-
-
85037273994
-
-
Anderson and Hill, "The Evolution"; Barzel, Economic.
-
Economic
-
-
Barzel1
-
97
-
-
85037284987
-
-
note
-
During interviews, private fishermen revealed that their side had three death records and various cases of physical abuse. While LLFF officials refused to talk about this issue, private fishermen acknowledged that they also fought back hard against LLFF patrolmen.
-
-
-
-
98
-
-
0011566070
-
-
New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
-
This strategy reminds us of the "weapon of the weak." When political channels are severely blocked and private individuals cannot articulate their interests and complaints, they usually resort to feigned ignorance, false compliance, verbal threats, mass defiance, and theft to mitigate or deny formal institution. See James Scott, Everyday Forms of Resistance (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1985).
-
(1985)
Everyday Forms of Resistance
-
-
Scott, J.1
-
99
-
-
0000934061
-
Threshold models of collective action
-
Mark Granovetter, "Threshold Models of Collective Action," American Journal of Sociology 83, no. 6 (1978): 1420-43.
-
(1978)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.83
, Issue.6
, pp. 1420-1443
-
-
Granovetter, M.1
-
100
-
-
0002360579
-
The experience of creating institutions: The framing of the United States constitution
-
Jack Knight and Itai Sened, eds., Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
-
William Riker, "The Experience of Creating Institutions: The Framing of the United States Constitution," in Jack Knight and Itai Sened, eds., Explaining Social Institutions (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1995), 121-44.
-
(1995)
Explaining Social Institutions
, pp. 121-144
-
-
Riker, W.1
-
101
-
-
0004078652
-
-
Boston: Beacon Press
-
Karl Popper, The Poverty of Historicism (Boston: Beacon Press, 1957); Fredick Hayek, "The Results of Human Action but Not of Human Design," in F. A. Hayek, Studies in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967).
-
(1957)
The Poverty of Historicism
-
-
Popper, K.1
-
102
-
-
0003315587
-
The results of human action but not of human design
-
F. A. Hayek, Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
Karl Popper, The Poverty of Historicism (Boston: Beacon Press, 1957); Fredick Hayek, "The Results of Human Action but Not of Human Design," in F. A. Hayek, Studies in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967).
-
(1967)
Studies in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics
-
-
Hayek, F.1
-
103
-
-
0001239049
-
The unanticipated consequences of purposive social action
-
Robert Merton, "The Unanticipated Consequences of Purposive Social Action," American Sociological Review 1, no. 6 (1936): 894-904; Raymond Boudon, The Unintended Consequences of Social Action (New York: Macmillan, 1982).
-
(1936)
American Sociological Review
, vol.1
, Issue.6
, pp. 894-904
-
-
Merton, R.1
-
104
-
-
85007143670
-
-
New York: Macmillan
-
Robert Merton, "The Unanticipated Consequences of Purposive Social Action," American Sociological Review 1, no. 6 (1936): 894-904; Raymond Boudon, The Unintended Consequences of Social Action (New York: Macmillan, 1982).
-
(1982)
The Unintended Consequences of Social Action
-
-
Boudon, R.1
-
105
-
-
85037280904
-
-
note
-
Unfortunately, we do not have quantitative data to illustrate this trend. During interviews, LLFF officials were uncomfortable to talk about their employees' uncivil treatment of caught fishermen. Yet fishermen's resentful accounts clearly indicate that LLFF patrolmen took advantage of the disintegration of gang groups and took harsh measures to punish caught fishermen. They [LLFF patrolmen] enjoyed patrolling very much, intercepting us in the lake, taking away our catch and nets. When they [LLFF patrolmen] caught us [fishermen] in the lake, they would take away everything they could, fish, nets, and boats. And they brought us to their private house of detention, and then ask our families to pay fines before releasing us. Our family members had nothing to do but to pay the fines as soon as possible. Otherwise they would beat us.
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
85037260211
-
-
note
-
Though I do not have data to show how many peasant fishermen shifted to pond fishery, the percentage was very high. All but one of the twenty-four fishermen informants had engaged in pond fishery. Since the fixed supply of ponds usually could not meet the demand, peasants took their turn to rent ponds. This practice not only made peasants who were currently in pond fishery respect secure property rights but also warned those who were waiting to rent ponds not to behave short sightedly.
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
85037274292
-
-
note
-
It is true that in the early 1980s, LLFF could not recoup its costs, as LLFF officials acknowledged in interviews.
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
84977406211
-
Soft budget constraints
-
This is known as the "soft budget constraint," a built-in feature of state-owned enterprises in the socialist economy. See Janos Kornai, "Soft Budget Constraints," Kyklos 39, no. 1 (1986): 3-30.
-
(1986)
Kyklos
, vol.39
, Issue.1
, pp. 3-30
-
-
Kornai, J.1
-
109
-
-
84936628245
-
-
Berkeley: University of California Press
-
As Emile Durkheim put it, A social fact is to be recognized by the power of external coercion which it exercises or is capable of exercising over individuals, and the presence of this power may be recognized in its turn either by the existence of some specific sanction or by the resistance offered against every individual effort that tends to violate it. In Michael Hechter, The Principles of Group Solidarity (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987), 15. For a recent articulation, see Jean Ensminger and Jack Knight, "Changing Social Norms: Common Property, Bridewealth, and Clan Exogamy," Current Anthropology 38, no. 1 (1997): 1-24.
-
(1987)
The Principles of Group Solidarity
, pp. 15
-
-
Hechter, M.1
-
110
-
-
0002468330
-
Changing social norms: Common property, bridewealth, and clan exogamy
-
As Emile Durkheim put it, A social fact is to be recognized by the power of external coercion which it exercises or is capable of exercising over individuals, and the presence of this power may be recognized in its turn either by the existence of some specific sanction or by the resistance offered against every individual effort that tends to violate it. In Michael Hechter, The Principles of Group Solidarity (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987), 15. For a recent articulation, see Jean Ensminger and Jack Knight, "Changing Social Norms: Common Property, Bridewealth, and Clan Exogamy," Current Anthropology 38, no. 1 (1997): 1-24.
-
(1997)
Current Anthropology
, vol.38
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-24
-
-
Ensminger, J.1
Knight, J.2
-
111
-
-
85037284201
-
-
note
-
Another factor also played a role. It is not unexpected that most of these remaining fishermen were recalcitrant in character. In the past, they led the combat against LLFF and gained recognition from fellow fishermen. However, after the gang groups were disbanded, they became increasingly violent and threatening even toward their former fellows. For example, they occasionally turned to their former fellow fishermen's fishing ponds when opportunities allowed. As a result, fishermen who engaged in pond fishery even became cooperative with LLFF officials to get rid of these "tough guys."
-
-
-
-
112
-
-
0002007615
-
Ideology
-
David Sills, ed., New York: Macmillan and Free Press
-
Edward Shils, "Ideology," in David Sills, ed., International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, vol. 7 (New York: Macmillan and Free Press, 1968), 66-76. For a recent exposition of ideology, particularly its role in economics, see Arthur Denzau and Douglass North, "Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions," Kyklos 47, no. 1 (1994): 3-31.
-
(1968)
International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences
, vol.7
, pp. 66-76
-
-
Shils, E.1
-
113
-
-
84980243564
-
Shared mental models: Ideologies and institutions
-
Edward Shils, "Ideology," in David Sills, ed., International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, vol. 7 (New York: Macmillan and Free Press, 1968), 66-76. For a recent exposition of ideology, particularly its role in economics, see Arthur Denzau and Douglass North, "Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions," Kyklos 47, no. 1 (1994): 3-31.
-
(1994)
Kyklos
, vol.47
, Issue.1
, pp. 3-31
-
-
Denzau, A.1
North, D.2
-
114
-
-
0039316670
-
-
the Coase Lecture delivered at the Law School of the University of Chicago, 24 November
-
For a general exposition of the relation between social norm and social meaning, see Cass Sunstein, "Social Norms and Social Roles" (the Coase Lecture delivered at the Law School of the University of Chicago, 24 November 1995); Lawrence Lessig, "The Regulations of Social Meaning," The University of Chicago Law Review 62, no. 2 (1995): 943-1045.
-
(1995)
Social norms and social roles
-
-
Sunstein, C.1
-
115
-
-
33750159669
-
The regulations of social meaning
-
For a general exposition of the relation between social norm and social meaning, see Cass Sunstein, "Social Norms and Social Roles" (the Coase Lecture delivered at the Law School of the University of Chicago, 24 November 1995); Lawrence Lessig, "The Regulations of Social Meaning," The University of Chicago Law Review 62, no. 2 (1995): 943-1045.
-
(1995)
The University of Chicago Law Review
, vol.62
, Issue.2
, pp. 943-1045
-
-
Lessig, L.1
-
117
-
-
0004197365
-
-
New York: Norton
-
Kenneth Arrow, The Limits of Organization (New York: Norton, 1974), 72; Margaret Levi, Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988).
-
(1974)
The Limits of Organization
, pp. 72
-
-
Arrow, K.1
-
118
-
-
84936628583
-
-
Berkeley: University of California Press
-
Kenneth Arrow, The Limits of Organization (New York: Norton, 1974), 72; Margaret Levi, Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988).
-
(1988)
Of Rule and Revenue
-
-
Levi, M.1
-
119
-
-
0039842814
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
One may be quick to point out that the "sour grapes" mechanism, as exposed by Elster, was at work here. See Jon Elster, Sour Grapes (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983). That is, after their access to fisheries was denied due to LLFF's increased enforcement efforts, fishermen chose to play down and even deny their desire for fisheries, thus reducing the conflict between the reality and their desire. Two considerations direct me away from such an explanation, however. First, if the "sour grapes" were indeed the working mechanism, we would expect fishermen who had gone through such a psychological self-denial to stop fishing in the lake. But they were unlikely to take actions to denounce other fishermen's continuous fishing in the lake. Second and more important, if fishermen changed to deny their desire for fishing in the lake in the face of LLFF's increased enforcement efforts, they would likely to return to the lake after LLFF reduces its patrol efforts. For a critique of Elster's argument, see Tore Sandeven, "Autonomy, Adaptation, and Rationality - A Critical Discussion of Jon Elster's Concept of 'Sour Grapes,'" Philosophy of Social Sciences 29, no. 1 (1999): 3-31.
-
(1983)
Sour Grapes
-
-
Elster, J.1
-
120
-
-
0039842814
-
Autonomy, adaptation, and rationality - A critical discussion of Jon Elster's concept of 'sour grapes,'
-
One may be quick to point out that the "sour grapes" mechanism, as exposed by Elster, was at work here. See Jon Elster, Sour Grapes (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983). That is, after their access to fisheries was denied due to LLFF's increased enforcement efforts, fishermen chose to play down and even deny their desire for fisheries, thus reducing the conflict between the reality and their desire. Two considerations direct me away from such an explanation, however. First, if the "sour grapes" were indeed the working mechanism, we would expect fishermen who had gone through such a psychological self-denial to stop fishing in the lake. But they were unlikely to take actions to denounce other fishermen's continuous fishing in the lake. Second and more important, if fishermen changed to deny their desire for fishing in the lake in the face of LLFF's increased enforcement efforts, they would likely to return to the lake after LLFF reduces its patrol efforts. For a critique of Elster's argument, see Tore Sandeven, "Autonomy, Adaptation, and Rationality - A Critical Discussion of Jon Elster's Concept of 'Sour Grapes,'" Philosophy of Social Sciences 29, no. 1 (1999): 3-31.
-
(1999)
Philosophy of Social Sciences
, vol.29
, Issue.1
, pp. 3-31
-
-
Sandeven, T.1
-
121
-
-
85037259761
-
-
Elster, Nuts; Bunge, "Mechanism"; Hedstrom and Swedberg, Social.
-
Nuts
-
-
Elster1
-
122
-
-
85037284952
-
-
Elster, Nuts; Bunge, "Mechanism"; Hedstrom and Swedberg, Social.
-
Mechanism
-
-
Bunge1
-
126
-
-
0001806314
-
Five propositions about institutional change
-
Jack Knight and Itai Sened, eds., Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
-
Douglass North, "Five Propositions about Institutional Change," in Jack Knight and Itai Sened, eds., Explaining Social Institutions (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1995), 15-26.
-
(1995)
Explaining Social Institutions
, pp. 15-26
-
-
North, D.1
-
128
-
-
0002666119
-
Social norms and economic theory
-
Social scientists are all too familiar with the entrenched tension between homo economicus and homo sociologicus. See, for example, Jon Elster, "Social Norms and Economic Theory," Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, no. 4 (1989): 99-117. In this everlasting debate, social norms and interests are two competing forces driving human behavior.
-
(1989)
Journal of Economic Perspectives
, vol.3
, Issue.4
, pp. 99-117
-
-
Elster, J.1
-
130
-
-
0002623151
-
Can neoclassical economics underpin the reform of centrally planned economies?
-
Peter Murrell, "Can Neoclassical Economics Underpin the Reform of Centrally Planned Economies?" Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 4 (1991): 59-76.
-
(1991)
Journal of Economic Perspectives
, vol.5
, Issue.4
, pp. 59-76
-
-
Murrell, P.1
-
131
-
-
0001789772
-
Co-existing organizational forms in Hungary's emerging mixed economy
-
Victor Nee and David Stark, eds., Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press
-
David Stark, "Co-existing Organizational Forms in Hungary's Emerging Mixed Economy," in Victor Nee and David Stark, eds., Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1989), 137-68; Stark, "Recombinant."
-
(1989)
Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism
, pp. 137-168
-
-
Stark, D.1
-
132
-
-
85037285684
-
-
David Stark, "Co-existing Organizational Forms in Hungary's Emerging Mixed Economy," in Victor Nee and David Stark, eds., Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1989), 137-68; Stark, "Recombinant."
-
Recombinant
-
-
Stark1
-
134
-
-
84936824245
-
Organizational dynamics of market transition: Hybrid forms, property rights, and mixed economy in China
-
Victor Nee, "Organizational Dynamics of Market Transition: Hybrid Forms, Property Rights, and Mixed Economy in China," Administrative Science Quarterly 37, no. 1 (1992): 1-27; Walder, "Corporation" ; Lin, "Local"; Oi and Walder, Property.
-
(1992)
Administrative Science Quarterly
, vol.37
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-27
-
-
Victor, N.1
-
135
-
-
27644496060
-
-
Victor Nee, "Organizational Dynamics of Market Transition: Hybrid Forms, Property Rights, and Mixed Economy in China," Administrative Science Quarterly 37, no. 1 (1992): 1-27; Walder, "Corporation" ; Lin, "Local"; Oi and Walder, Property.
-
Corporation
-
-
Walder1
-
136
-
-
85037261359
-
-
Victor Nee, "Organizational Dynamics of Market Transition: Hybrid Forms, Property Rights, and Mixed Economy in China," Administrative Science Quarterly 37, no. 1 (1992): 1-27; Walder, "Corporation" ; Lin, "Local"; Oi and Walder, Property.
-
Local
-
-
Lin1
-
137
-
-
85037277561
-
-
Victor Nee, "Organizational Dynamics of Market Transition: Hybrid Forms, Property Rights, and Mixed Economy in China," Administrative Science Quarterly 37, no. 1 (1992): 1-27; Walder, "Corporation" ; Lin, "Local"; Oi and Walder, Property.
-
Property
-
-
Oi1
Walder2
-
138
-
-
85048063294
-
-
Weitzman and Xu, "Chinese"; Li, "A Theory"; Che and Qian, "Insecure."
-
Chinese
-
-
Weitzman1
Xu2
-
139
-
-
85037277276
-
-
Weitzman and Xu, "Chinese"; Li, "A Theory"; Che and Qian, "Insecure."
-
A Theory
-
-
Li1
-
140
-
-
85037286202
-
-
Weitzman and Xu, "Chinese"; Li, "A Theory"; Che and Qian, "Insecure."
-
Insecure
-
-
Che1
Qian2
-
141
-
-
0242645648
-
Local market socialism: Local corporatism in action in rural China
-
Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action in Rural China," Theory and Society 24, no. 2 (1995): 301-54; Stark, "Recombinant."
-
(1995)
Theory and Society
, vol.24
, Issue.2
, pp. 301-354
-
-
Nan, L.1
-
142
-
-
0242645648
-
-
Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action in Rural China," Theory and Society 24, no. 2 (1995): 301-54; Stark, "Recombinant."
-
Recombinant
-
-
Stark1
-
143
-
-
0003793633
-
-
New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
-
Daniel Kelliher, Peasant Power in China (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1992); Kate Xiao Zhou, How the Farmers Changed China: Power of the People (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1996).
-
(1992)
Peasant Power in China
-
-
Kelliher, D.1
|