메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 28, Issue 1, 2000, Pages 5-33

Between deregulation and social pacts: The responses of European economies to globalization

(1)  Regini, Marino a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0034387322     PISSN: 00323292     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1177/0032329200028001002     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (138)

References (94)
  • 1
    • 0029539323 scopus 로고
    • Economic opportunity, civil society and political liberty
    • Copenhagen, 11-12 March
    • See, for example, Ralf Dahrendorf, "Economic Opportunity, Civil Society and Political Liberty" (paper presented at UNRISD conference on "Rethinking Social Development," Copenhagen, 11-12 March 1995); Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism: Mapping Convergence and Diversity (London: Sage, 1997).
    • (1995) UNRISD Conference on Rethinking Social Development
    • Dahrendorf, R.1
  • 3
    • 85037753185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • From this point of view, the rhetoric of globalization is just as powerful as economic reality, in that it conveys the idea of a decisive challenge that the less competitive economies will be unable to meet and will therefore succumb.
  • 4
    • 85037784340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ranging from the standardizing consequences of industrialization through the instrumentalism of an affluent working class, predictions of the institutionalization of class conflict or indeed its "withering away," to the "end of ideology."
  • 5
    • 0039066445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The internationalization of industrial relations in Europe: Prospects and problems
    • Wolfgang Streeck, "The Internationalization of Industrial Relations in Europe: Prospects and Problems," Politics & Society 26, no. 4 (1998).
    • (1998) Politics & Society , vol.26 , Issue.4
    • Streeck, W.1
  • 6
    • 0003621387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bruxelles: ETUI
    • Giuseppe Fajertag and Philippe Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe (Bruxelles: ETUI, 1997); Philippe Pochet, "Les pactes sociaux en Europe dans les années 1990," Sociologie du Travail, no. 2 (1998).
    • (1997) Social Pacts in Europe
    • Fajertag, G.1    Pochet, P.2
  • 7
    • 0000659704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Les pactes sociaux en Europe dans les années 1990
    • Giuseppe Fajertag and Philippe Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe (Bruxelles: ETUI, 1997); Philippe Pochet, "Les pactes sociaux en Europe dans les années 1990," Sociologie du Travail, no. 2 (1998).
    • (1998) Sociologie du Travail , Issue.2
    • Pochet, P.1
  • 9
    • 85037755972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is not to underrate the importance of institutionalist approaches in economics (suffice it to mention the work of Douglas North and Oliver Williamson) and in sociology (especially the work of Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio). Nevertheless, it is mainly in political science that neoinstitutionalism has made a major contribution to the analysis of welfare systems, industrial relations, and the labor market - that is, the themes examined by this article.
  • 10
    • 0009978678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political science and the three new institutionalisms
    • For excellent reviews, see Peter Hall and Rosemary Taylor, "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms," Political Studies, no. 44 (1996); Guy Peters, "The New Institutionalism and Administrative Reform: Examining Alternative Models," Instituto Juan March Working Papers, no. 113 (1998).
    • (1996) Political Studies , Issue.44
    • Hall, P.1    Taylor, R.2
  • 11
  • 12
    • 0003463955 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Among the best known, mention should first be made of the models of interest intermediation that Philippe Schmitter has called respectively neocorporatist and pluralist and of the types of welfare systems classified by Richard Titmuss into institutional-redistributive, residual, and meritocratic-particularistic but then repeatedly redefined to give rise to the currently most widely accepted typology comprising the Scandinavian, Anglo-Saxon, and continental European models. See Gösta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990). Also, the organization of production - which labor economists and sociologists often only study as a consequence of technological change and managerial strategies - is viewed in this perspective as a choice closely conditioned by the institutional context. See Marc Maurice, Francois Sellier, and Jean-Jacques Silvestre, Politique d'éducation et organisation industrielle en France et en Allemande (Paris: PUF, 1982). This has given rise to the concept of "production regimes," which were simply distinguished between Fordist and post-Fordist in early studies, while the subsequent literature has developed more articulated typologies. See especially the work of David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Non-Coordinated Market Economies," in R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance (London: Macmillan, 1990) and "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, and J. Stephens, eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1998). Finally, the distinction between different "models of capitalism" - the Anglo-American and the Rhenish, to which the Japanese one is often added - covers to some extent all the aspects and institutional variables included in previous typologies. See Michel Albert, Capitalisme contre capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1991), for an early and rather crude formulation. More sophisticated analyses can be found in Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996); Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism
    • Esping-Andersen, G.1
  • 13
    • 0003653111 scopus 로고
    • Paris: PUF
    • Among the best known, mention should first be made of the models of interest intermediation that Philippe Schmitter has called respectively neocorporatist and pluralist and of the types of welfare systems classified by Richard Titmuss into institutional-redistributive, residual, and meritocratic-particularistic but then repeatedly redefined to give rise to the currently most widely accepted typology comprising the Scandinavian, Anglo-Saxon, and continental European models. See Gösta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990). Also, the organization of production - which labor economists and sociologists often only study as a consequence of technological change and managerial strategies - is viewed in this perspective as a choice closely conditioned by the institutional context. See Marc Maurice, Francois Sellier, and Jean-Jacques Silvestre, Politique d'éducation et organisation industrielle en France et en Allemande (Paris: PUF, 1982). This has given rise to the concept of "production regimes," which were simply distinguished between Fordist and post-Fordist in early studies, while the subsequent literature has developed more articulated typologies. See especially the work of David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Non-Coordinated Market Economies," in R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance (London: Macmillan, 1990) and "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, and J. Stephens, eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1998). Finally, the distinction between different "models of capitalism" - the Anglo-American and the Rhenish, to which the Japanese one is often added - covers to some extent all the aspects and institutional variables included in previous typologies. See Michel Albert, Capitalisme contre capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1991), for an early and rather crude formulation. More sophisticated analyses can be found in Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996); Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • (1982) Politique d'Éducation et Organisation Industrielle en France et en Allemande
    • Maurice, M.1    Sellier, F.2    Silvestre, J.-J.3
  • 14
    • 0002813673 scopus 로고
    • Reinterpreting corporatism and explaining unemployment: Coordinated and non-coordinated market economies
    • R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., London: Macmillan
    • Among the best known, mention should first be made of the models of interest intermediation that Philippe Schmitter has called respectively neocorporatist and pluralist and of the types of welfare systems classified by Richard Titmuss into institutional-redistributive, residual, and meritocratic-particularistic but then repeatedly redefined to give rise to the currently most widely accepted typology comprising the Scandinavian, Anglo-Saxon, and continental European models. See Gösta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990). Also, the organization of production - which labor economists and sociologists often only study as a consequence of technological change and managerial strategies - is viewed in this perspective as a choice closely conditioned by the institutional context. See Marc Maurice, Francois Sellier, and Jean-Jacques Silvestre, Politique d'éducation et organisation industrielle en France et en Allemande (Paris: PUF, 1982). This has given rise to the concept of "production regimes," which were simply distinguished between Fordist and post-Fordist in early studies, while the subsequent literature has developed more articulated typologies. See especially the work of David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Non-Coordinated Market Economies," in R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance (London: Macmillan, 1990) and "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, and J. Stephens, eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1998). Finally, the distinction between different "models of capitalism" - the Anglo-American and the Rhenish, to which the Japanese one is often added - covers to some extent all the aspects and institutional variables included in previous typologies. See Michel Albert, Capitalisme contre capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1991), for an early and rather crude formulation. More sophisticated analyses can be found in Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996); Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • (1990) Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance
    • Soskice, D.1
  • 15
    • 0003710981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Divergent production regimes: Coordinated and uncoordinated market economies in the 1980s and 1990s
    • Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press
    • Among the best known, mention should first be made of the models of interest intermediation that Philippe Schmitter has called respectively neocorporatist and pluralist and of the types of welfare systems classified by Richard Titmuss into institutional-redistributive, residual, and meritocratic-particularistic but then repeatedly redefined to give rise to the currently most widely accepted typology comprising the Scandinavian, Anglo-Saxon, and continental European models. See Gösta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990). Also, the organization of production - which labor economists and sociologists often only study as a consequence of technological change and managerial strategies - is viewed in this perspective as a choice closely conditioned by the institutional context. See Marc Maurice, Francois Sellier, and Jean-Jacques Silvestre, Politique d'éducation et organisation industrielle en France et en Allemande (Paris: PUF, 1982). This has given rise to the concept of "production regimes," which were simply distinguished between Fordist and post-Fordist in early studies, while the subsequent literature has developed more articulated typologies. See especially the work of David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Non-Coordinated Market Economies," in R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance (London: Macmillan, 1990) and "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, and J. Stephens, eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1998). Finally, the distinction between different "models of capitalism" - the Anglo-American and the Rhenish, to which the Japanese one is often added - covers to some extent all the aspects and institutional variables included in previous typologies. See Michel Albert, Capitalisme contre capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1991), for an early and rather crude formulation. More sophisticated analyses can be found in Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996); Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • (1998) Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism
    • Kitschelt, H.1    Lange, P.2    Marks, G.3    Stephens, J.4
  • 16
    • 0004208017 scopus 로고
    • Paris: Seuil
    • Among the best known, mention should first be made of the models of interest intermediation that Philippe Schmitter has called respectively neocorporatist and pluralist and of the types of welfare systems classified by Richard Titmuss into institutional-redistributive, residual, and meritocratic-particularistic but then repeatedly redefined to give rise to the currently most widely accepted typology comprising the Scandinavian, Anglo-Saxon, and continental European models. See Gösta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990). Also, the organization of production - which labor economists and sociologists often only study as a consequence of technological change and managerial strategies - is viewed in this perspective as a choice closely conditioned by the institutional context. See Marc Maurice, Francois Sellier, and Jean-Jacques Silvestre, Politique d'éducation et organisation industrielle en France et en Allemande (Paris: PUF, 1982). This has given rise to the concept of "production regimes," which were simply distinguished between Fordist and post-Fordist in early studies, while the subsequent literature has developed more articulated typologies. See especially the work of David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Non-Coordinated Market Economies," in R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance (London: Macmillan, 1990) and "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, and J. Stephens, eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1998). Finally, the distinction between different "models of capitalism" - the Anglo-American and the Rhenish, to which the Japanese one is often added - covers to some extent all the aspects and institutional variables included in previous typologies. See Michel Albert, Capitalisme contre capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1991), for an early and rather crude formulation. More sophisticated analyses can be found in Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996); Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • (1991) Capitalisme Contre Capitalisme
    • Albert, M.1
  • 17
    • 0003662290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press
    • Among the best known, mention should first be made of the models of interest intermediation that Philippe Schmitter has called respectively neocorporatist and pluralist and of the types of welfare systems classified by Richard Titmuss into institutional-redistributive, residual, and meritocratic-particularistic but then repeatedly redefined to give rise to the currently most widely accepted typology comprising the Scandinavian, Anglo-Saxon, and continental European models. See Gösta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990). Also, the organization of production - which labor economists and sociologists often only study as a consequence of technological change and managerial strategies - is viewed in this perspective as a choice closely conditioned by the institutional context. See Marc Maurice, Francois Sellier, and Jean-Jacques Silvestre, Politique d'éducation et organisation industrielle en France et en Allemande (Paris: PUF, 1982). This has given rise to the concept of "production regimes," which were simply distinguished between Fordist and post-Fordist in early studies, while the subsequent literature has developed more articulated typologies. See especially the work of David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Non-Coordinated Market Economies," in R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance (London: Macmillan, 1990) and "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, and J. Stephens, eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1998). Finally, the distinction between different "models of capitalism" - the Anglo-American and the Rhenish, to which the Japanese one is often added - covers to some extent all the aspects and institutional variables included in previous typologies. See Michel Albert, Capitalisme contre capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1991), for an early and rather crude formulation. More sophisticated analyses can be found in Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996); Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • (1996) National Diversity and Global Capitalism
    • Berger, S.1    Dore, R.2
  • 18
    • 0003596477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Among the best known, mention should first be made of the models of interest intermediation that Philippe Schmitter has called respectively neocorporatist and pluralist and of the types of welfare systems classified by Richard Titmuss into institutional-redistributive, residual, and meritocratic-particularistic but then repeatedly redefined to give rise to the currently most widely accepted typology comprising the Scandinavian, Anglo-Saxon, and continental European models. See Gösta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990). Also, the organization of production - which labor economists and sociologists often only study as a consequence of technological change and managerial strategies - is viewed in this perspective as a choice closely conditioned by the institutional context. See Marc Maurice, Francois Sellier, and Jean-Jacques Silvestre, Politique d'éducation et organisation industrielle en France et en Allemande (Paris: PUF, 1982). This has given rise to the concept of "production regimes," which were simply distinguished between Fordist and post-Fordist in early studies, while the subsequent literature has developed more articulated typologies. See especially the work of David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Non-Coordinated Market Economies," in R. Brunetta and C. Dell'Aringa, eds., Markets, Institutions and Corporations: Labour Relations and Economic Performance (London: Macmillan, 1990) and "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, and J. Stephens, eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1998). Finally, the distinction between different "models of capitalism" - the Anglo-American and the Rhenish, to which the Japanese one is often added - covers to some extent all the aspects and institutional variables included in previous typologies. See Michel Albert, Capitalisme contre capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1991), for an early and rather crude formulation. More sophisticated analyses can be found in Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996); Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • Political Economy of Modern Capitalism
    • Crouch1    Streeck2
  • 19
    • 0010593473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, forthcoming
    • The empirical analysis deals with ten countries (see appendix). The data and information used have been taken from a variety of sources. First, I have drawn on the results of a comparative study on eight European countries coordinated by myself for the European Commission, DGXII. These results are presented in Gösta Esping-Andersen and Marino Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets? (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, forthcoming). Comparative collections on recent trends in some of the areas considered, which have provided valuable information, are the volume edited by Fajertag and Pochet, Social Pacts in Europe, and especially the collection of country studies edited by Anthony Ferner and Richard Hyman, Changing Industrial Relations in Europe (Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1998). Further useful sources of comparative data are a research study recently commissioned by the FIAT industrial relations office on flexibility practices in various countries, the journal European Industrial Relations Review, and, for the past three years, the EIRO (European Industrial Relations Observatory) database coordinated by the European Foundation in Dublin. Of course, I have also drawn from the literature on individual countries, particularly those emblematic of ongoing trends or that have seen the most striking changes (United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Sweden, Germany, Italy).
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Esping-Andersen, G.1    Regini, M.2
  • 20
    • 0003621387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The empirical analysis deals with ten countries (see appendix). The data and information used have been taken from a variety of sources. First, I have drawn on the results of a comparative study on eight European countries coordinated by myself for the European Commission, DGXII. These results are presented in Gösta Esping-Andersen and Marino Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets? (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, forthcoming). Comparative collections on recent trends in some of the areas considered, which have provided valuable information, are the volume edited by Fajertag and Pochet, Social Pacts in Europe, and especially the collection of country studies edited by Anthony Ferner and Richard Hyman, Changing Industrial Relations in Europe (Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1998). Further useful sources of comparative data are a research study recently commissioned by the FIAT industrial relations office on flexibility practices in various countries, the journal European Industrial Relations Review, and, for the past three years, the EIRO (European Industrial Relations Observatory) database coordinated by the European Foundation in Dublin. Of course, I have also drawn from the literature on individual countries, particularly those emblematic of ongoing trends or that have seen the most striking changes (United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Sweden, Germany, Italy).
    • Social Pacts in Europe
    • Fajertag1    Pochet2
  • 21
    • 0004231190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford, UK: Blackwell
    • The empirical analysis deals with ten countries (see appendix). The data and information used have been taken from a variety of sources. First, I have drawn on the results of a comparative study on eight European countries coordinated by myself for the European Commission, DGXII. These results are presented in Gösta Esping-Andersen and Marino Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets? (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, forthcoming). Comparative collections on recent trends in some of the areas considered, which have provided valuable information, are the volume edited by Fajertag and Pochet, Social Pacts in Europe, and especially the collection of country studies edited by Anthony Ferner and Richard Hyman, Changing Industrial Relations in Europe (Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1998). Further useful sources of comparative data are a research study recently commissioned by the FIAT industrial relations office on flexibility practices in various countries, the journal European Industrial Relations Review, and, for the past three years, the EIRO (European Industrial Relations Observatory) database coordinated by the European Foundation in Dublin. Of course, I have also drawn from the literature on individual countries, particularly those emblematic of ongoing trends or that have seen the most striking changes (United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Sweden, Germany, Italy).
    • (1998) Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Ferner, A.1    Hyman, R.2
  • 22
    • 85037777430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some of these alternatives are relevant to areas other than the ones with which they are associated here: for instance, one can also discern tendencies toward rigidity or flexibility in the bargaining structure or toward centralization or decentralization in social security systems and so on. However, considering only the principal alternatives helps simplify what would otherwise be a too complex classificatory scheme.
  • 23
    • 0242599203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dutch miracle?
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • As in the Netherlands, see Cees Gorter, "The Dutch miracle?" in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Gorter, C.1
  • 24
    • 0002379756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why German employers cannot bring themselves to abandon the German model
    • T. Iversen, J. Pontusson, and D. Soskice, eds., Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press
    • As in Germany, see Kathleen Thelen, "Why German Employers Cannot Bring Themselves to Abandon the German Model," in T. Iversen, J. Pontusson, and D. Soskice, eds., Unions, Employers and Central Banks: Wage Bargaining and Macro-Economic Policy in an Integrating Europe (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1999).
    • (1999) Unions, Employers and Central Banks: Wage Bargaining and Macro-Economic Policy in an Integrating Europe
    • Thelen, K.1
  • 25
    • 85037758647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These difficulties in the construction of qualitative indicators are well known (an emblematic case being the "index of labor market rigidity" constructed by the OECD in 1994 and then radically revised). In order to handle them at least in part, I have used a large amount of information and assessment provided by national experts (see note 10) in allocating a country to one or the other alternative. The countries in parentheses in the tables are cases in which the pros and cons make their placement most problematic (Sweden) or in which major efforts at change have been made but with little success (Germany). However, the aim of this article is to show that the directions of change in each of the three areas may differ and that few countries have opted unequivocally for deregulation or concertation. This seems generally confirmed by the tables, despite the uncertainty and subjectivity that inevitably arise when classifying a particular country.
  • 26
    • 0242599203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gorter, "The Dutch Miracle?"; Anders Björklund, "Going Different Ways: Labor Market Policy in Denmark and Sweden," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; FIAT, "Flessibilità del lavoro: Confronto internazionale e spunti per la realtà italiana" (mimeo, 1998); Simon Deakin and Hannah Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath? Deregulation and Employment in Britain," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; George Taylor, "Labour Market Rigidities, Institutional Impediments and Managerial Constraints: Some Reflections on the Recent Experience of Macro-Political Bargaining in Ireland" (paper presented at SASE 8th International Conference, Geneva, July 1996).
    • The Dutch Miracle?
    • Gorter1
  • 27
    • 0011072463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Going different ways: Labor market policy in Denmark and Sweden
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • See Gorter, "The Dutch Miracle?"; Anders Björklund, "Going Different Ways: Labor Market Policy in Denmark and Sweden," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; FIAT, "Flessibilità del lavoro: Confronto internazionale e spunti per la realtà italiana" (mimeo, 1998); Simon Deakin and Hannah Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath? Deregulation and Employment in Britain," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; George Taylor, "Labour Market Rigidities, Institutional Impediments and Managerial Constraints: Some Reflections on the Recent Experience of Macro-Political Bargaining in Ireland" (paper presented at SASE 8th International Conference, Geneva, July 1996).
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Björklund, A.1
  • 28
    • 0040096807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • mimeo
    • See Gorter, "The Dutch Miracle?"; Anders Björklund, "Going Different Ways: Labor Market Policy in Denmark and Sweden," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; FIAT, "Flessibilità del lavoro: Confronto internazionale e spunti per la realtà italiana" (mimeo, 1998); Simon Deakin and Hannah Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath? Deregulation and Employment in Britain," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; George Taylor, "Labour Market Rigidities, Institutional Impediments and Managerial Constraints: Some Reflections on the Recent Experience of Macro-Political Bargaining in Ireland" (paper presented at SASE 8th International Conference, Geneva, July 1996).
    • (1998) Flessibilità del Lavoro: Confronto Internazionale e Spunti per la Realtà Italiana
  • 29
    • 0011142354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • River crossing or cold bath? Deregulation and employment in Britain
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • See Gorter, "The Dutch Miracle?"; Anders Björklund, "Going Different Ways: Labor Market Policy in Denmark and Sweden," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; FIAT, "Flessibilità del lavoro: Confronto internazionale e spunti per la realtà italiana" (mimeo, 1998); Simon Deakin and Hannah Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath? Deregulation and Employment in Britain," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; George Taylor, "Labour Market Rigidities, Institutional Impediments and Managerial Constraints: Some Reflections on the Recent Experience of Macro-Political Bargaining in Ireland" (paper presented at SASE 8th International Conference, Geneva, July 1996).
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Deakin, S.1    Reed, H.2
  • 30
    • 0040690301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Labour market rigidities, institutional impediments and managerial constraints: Some reflections on the recent experience of macro-political bargaining in Ireland
    • Geneva, July
    • See Gorter, "The Dutch Miracle?"; Anders Björklund, "Going Different Ways: Labor Market Policy in Denmark and Sweden," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; FIAT, "Flessibilità del lavoro: Confronto internazionale e spunti per la realtà italiana" (mimeo, 1998); Simon Deakin and Hannah Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath? Deregulation and Employment in Britain," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; George Taylor, "Labour Market Rigidities, Institutional Impediments and Managerial Constraints: Some Reflections on the Recent Experience of Macro-Political Bargaining in Ireland" (paper presented at SASE 8th International Conference, Geneva, July 1996).
    • (1996) SASE 8th International Conference
    • Taylor, G.1
  • 31
    • 0005708230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • (1998) Partial De-regulation: Fixed-term Contracts in Italy and Spain
    • Adam, P.1    Canziani, P.2
  • 32
    • 85057636069 scopus 로고
    • Crossing the river: A comparative perspective of Italian employment dynamics
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • (1995) Economic Policy , Issue.21
    • Bertola, G.1    Ichino, A.2
  • 33
    • 0041638138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • France: The deregulation that never existed
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Gautié, J.1    Malo, M.2    Toharia, L.3
  • 34
    • 0007014085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Spanish experiment: Pros and cons of the flexibility at the margin
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Toharia, L.1    Malo, M.2
  • 35
    • 0003209760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Norway: The revival of centralized concertation
    • Ferner and Hyman eds.
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Dølvik, J.E.1    Stokke, T.A.2
  • 36
    • 85037763085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Flessibilità del Lavoro
  • 37
    • 0007277603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Germany: A regulated flexibility
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Fuchs, S.1    Schettkat, R.2
  • 38
    • 16244418804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Italy: The long times of consensual re-regulation
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • See Paula Adam and Patrizia Canziani, "Partial De-regulation: Fixed-Term Contracts in Italy and Spain," Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Papers No. 386 (1998)-Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino, "Crossing the River: A Comparative Perspective of Italian Employment Dynamics," Economic Policy, no. 21 (1995); Jerôme Gautié Miguel Malo, and Luis Toharia, "France: The Deregulation That Never Existed," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Luis Toharia and Miguel Malo "The Spanish Experiment: Pros and Cons of the Flexibility at the Margin," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Jon Erik Dølvik and Torgier Aarvaag Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation," in Ferner and Hyman eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; FIAT, Flessibilità del lavoro; Susanne Fuchs and Ronald Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?; Manuela Samek, "Italy: The Long Times of Consensual Re-regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Samek, M.1
  • 39
    • 0038564722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The dilemmas of labor market regulation
    • Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds.
    • See Marino Regini, "The Dilemmas of Labor Market Regulation," in Esping-Andersen and Regini, eds., Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Why Deregulate Labour Markets?
    • Regini, M.1
  • 40
    • 0000010192 scopus 로고
    • The decentralization of collective bargaining
    • See Harry Katz, "The Decentralization of Collective Bargaining," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, no. 47 (1993).
    • (1993) Industrial and Labor Relations Review , Issue.47
    • Katz, H.1
  • 41
    • 0004231190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On developments in these countries, see the respective chapters in Ferner and Hyman eds Changing Industrial Relations in Europe. For a critique of the prevailing view of general decentralization, however, see Peter Lange, Michael Wallerstein, and Miriam Golden, "The End of Corporatism?" in S. Jacoby, ed., The Workers of Nations (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 1995).
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Ferner1    Hyman2
  • 42
    • 0003156331 scopus 로고
    • The end of corporatism?
    • S. Jacoby, ed., Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press
    • On developments in these countries, see the respective chapters in Ferner and Hyman eds Changing Industrial Relations in Europe. For a critique of the prevailing view of general decentralization, however, see Peter Lange, Michael Wallerstein, and Miriam Golden, "The End of Corporatism?" in S. Jacoby, ed., The Workers of Nations (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 1995).
    • (1995) The Workers of Nations
    • Lange, P.1    Wallerstein, M.2    Golden, M.3
  • 44
    • 0031286740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Still engaging in corporatism? Recent Italian experience in comparative perspective
    • Marino Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism? Recent Italian Experience in Comparative Perspective," European Journal of Industrial Relations 3, no. 3 (1997); Mimmo Carrieri Seconda Repubblica: Senza sindacati? Il futuro della concertazione in Italia (Roma: Ediesse, 1997); Serafino Negrelli, "Social Pacts and Flexibility: Towards a New Balance between Macro and Micro Industrial Relations: The Italian Experience," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • (1997) European Journal of Industrial Relations , vol.3 , Issue.3
    • Regini, M.1
  • 45
    • 0031286740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roma: Ediesse
    • Marino Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism? Recent Italian Experience in Comparative Perspective," European Journal of Industrial Relations 3, no. 3 (1997); Mimmo Carrieri Seconda Repubblica: Senza sindacati? Il futuro della concertazione in Italia (Roma: Ediesse, 1997); Serafino Negrelli, "Social Pacts and Flexibility: Towards a New Balance between Macro and Micro Industrial Relations: The Italian Experience," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • (1997) Seconda Repubblica: Senza Sindacati? Il Futuro Della Concertazione in Italia
    • Carrieri, M.1
  • 46
    • 0031286740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social pacts and flexibility: Towards a new balance between macro and micro industrial relations: The Italian experience
    • Fajertag and Pochet, eds.
    • Marino Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism? Recent Italian Experience in Comparative Perspective," European Journal of Industrial Relations 3, no. 3 (1997); Mimmo Carrieri Seconda Repubblica: Senza sindacati? Il futuro della concertazione in Italia (Roma: Ediesse, 1997); Serafino Negrelli, "Social Pacts and Flexibility: Towards a New Balance between Macro and Micro Industrial Relations: The Italian Experience," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • Social Pacts in Europe
    • Negrelli, S.1
  • 47
    • 21344437228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Power, flexibility, and the breakdown of centralized wage bargaining: The cases of Denmark and Sweden in comparative perspective
    • Torben Iversen, "Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bar" gaining: The Cases of Denmark and Sweden in Comparative Perspective," Comparative Politics, no. 4 (1996).
    • (1996) Comparative Politics , Issue.4
    • Iversen, T.1
  • 48
    • 0001883757 scopus 로고
    • Farewell to labour market associations? Organized versus disorganized decentralization as a map for industrial relations
    • C. Crouch and F. Traxler, eds., Aldershot, UK: Avebury
    • Franz Traxler "Farewell to Labour Market Associations? Organized versus Disorganized Decentralization as a Map for Industrial Relations," in C. Crouch and F. Traxler, eds., Organized Industrial Relations in Europe: What Future? (Aldershot, UK: Avebury, 1995).
    • (1995) Organized Industrial Relations in Europe: What Future?
    • Traxler, F.1
  • 50
    • 33847367772 scopus 로고
    • Ireland's experiment in social partnership, 1987-96
    • Fajertag and Pochet, eds.
    • On Ireland, see Rory O'Donnell and Colm O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Ferdinand Von Prondzynski, "Ireland: Corporatism Revived," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe. On Norway, see Jon Erik Dølvik and Andrew Martin "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters: The Divergent Fates of Social Pacts in Sweden and Norway," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Dølvik and Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation."
    • (1987) Social Pacts in Europe
    • O'Donnell, R.1    O'Reardon, C.2
  • 51
    • 0001834010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ireland: Corporatism revived
    • Ferner and Hyman, eds.
    • On Ireland, see Rory O'Donnell and Colm O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Ferdinand Von Prondzynski, "Ireland: Corporatism Revived," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe. On Norway, see Jon Erik Dølvik and Andrew Martin "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters: The Divergent Fates of Social Pacts in Sweden and Norway," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Dølvik and Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation."
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Von Prondzynski, F.1
  • 52
    • 0040546527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A spanner in the works and oil on troubled waters: The divergent fates of social pacts in Sweden and Norway
    • Fajertag and Pochet, eds.
    • On Ireland, see Rory O'Donnell and Colm O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Ferdinand Von Prondzynski, "Ireland: Corporatism Revived," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe. On Norway, see Jon Erik Dølvik and Andrew Martin "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters: The Divergent Fates of Social Pacts in Sweden and Norway," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Dølvik and Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation."
    • Social Pacts in Europe
    • Dølvik, J.E.1    Martin, A.2
  • 53
    • 0003209760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Ireland, see Rory O'Donnell and Colm O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Ferdinand Von Prondzynski, "Ireland: Corporatism Revived," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe. On Norway, see Jon Erik Dølvik and Andrew Martin "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters: The Divergent Fates of Social Pacts in Sweden and Norway," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Dølvik and Stokke, "Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation."
    • Norway: The Revival of Centralized Concertation
    • Dølvik1    Stokke2
  • 54
    • 0039674852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Italy, see Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism?"; Carrieri, Seconda Repubblica: Senza sindacati? On the Dutch case, see Jelle Visser and Anton Hemerijck, "A Dutch Miracle": Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); and Jelle Visser, "The Netherlands: The Return of Responsive Corporatism," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Still Engaging in Corporatism?
    • Regini1
  • 55
    • 80555124849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Italy, see Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism?"; Carrieri, Seconda Repubblica: Senza sindacati? On the Dutch case, see Jelle Visser and Anton Hemerijck, "A Dutch Miracle": Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); and Jelle Visser, "The Netherlands: The Return of Responsive Corporatism," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Seconda Repubblica: Senza Sindacati?
    • Carrieri1
  • 56
    • 0004103764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press
    • On Italy, see Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism?"; Carrieri, Seconda Repubblica: Senza sindacati? On the Dutch case, see Jelle Visser and Anton Hemerijck, "A Dutch Miracle": Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); and Jelle Visser, "The Netherlands: The Return of Responsive Corporatism," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • (1997) A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherland
    • Visser, J.1    Hemerijck, A.2
  • 57
    • 0002156316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Netherlands: The return of responsive corporatism
    • Ferner and Hyman, eds.
    • On Italy, see Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism?"; Carrieri, Seconda Repubblica: Senza sindacati? On the Dutch case, see Jelle Visser and Anton Hemerijck, "A Dutch Miracle": Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 1997); and Jelle Visser, "The Netherlands: The Return of Responsive Corporatism," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Visser, J.1
  • 58
    • 85037749888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Britain, see Deakin and Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath?"; on France, see Jeanine Goetschy, "France: The Limits of Reform," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; on Spain, see Miguel Martinez Lucio, "Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • River Crossing or Cold Bath?
    • Deakin1    Reed2
  • 59
    • 0002705362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • France: The limits of reform
    • Ferner and Hyman, eds.
    • On Britain, see Deakin and Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath?"; on France, see Jeanine Goetschy, "France: The Limits of Reform," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; on Spain, see Miguel Martinez Lucio, "Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Goetschy, J.1
  • 60
    • 0001357236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spain: Regulating employment and social fragmentation
    • Ferner and Hyman, eds.
    • On Britain, see Deakin and Reed, "River Crossing or Cold Bath?"; on France, see Jeanine Goetschy, "France: The Limits of Reform," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; on Spain, see Miguel Martinez Lucio, "Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Lucio, M.M.1
  • 61
    • 0040096806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Iversen, "Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining"; Jonas Pontusson and Peter Swenson, "Labor Markets, Production Strategies, and Wage Bargaining Institutions: The Swedish Employer Offensive in Comparative Perspective," Comparative Political Studies 29, no. 2 (1996); Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters"; Anders Kjellberg, "Sweden: Restoring the Model?" in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Steen Scheuer, "Denmark: A Less Regulated Model," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Jens Lind, "EMU and Collective Bargaining in Denmark," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining
    • Iversen1
  • 62
    • 0030548767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Labor markets, production strategies, and wage bargaining institutions: The Swedish employer offensive in comparative perspective
    • See Iversen, "Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining"; Jonas Pontusson and Peter Swenson, "Labor Markets, Production Strategies, and Wage Bargaining Institutions: The Swedish Employer Offensive in Comparative Perspective," Comparative Political Studies 29, no. 2 (1996); Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters"; Anders Kjellberg, "Sweden: Restoring the Model?" in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Steen Scheuer, "Denmark: A Less Regulated Model," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Jens Lind, "EMU and Collective Bargaining in Denmark," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • (1996) Comparative Political Studies , vol.29 , Issue.2
    • Pontusson, J.1    Swenson, P.2
  • 63
    • 85037751771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Iversen, "Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining"; Jonas Pontusson and Peter Swenson, "Labor Markets, Production Strategies, and Wage Bargaining Institutions: The Swedish Employer Offensive in Comparative Perspective," Comparative Political Studies 29, no. 2 (1996); Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters"; Anders Kjellberg, "Sweden: Restoring the Model?" in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Steen Scheuer, "Denmark: A Less Regulated Model," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Jens Lind, "EMU and Collective Bargaining in Denmark," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters
    • Dølvik1    Martin2
  • 64
    • 0002932643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sweden: Restoring the model?
    • Ferner and Hyman, eds.
    • See Iversen, "Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining"; Jonas Pontusson and Peter Swenson, "Labor Markets, Production Strategies, and Wage Bargaining Institutions: The Swedish Employer Offensive in Comparative Perspective," Comparative Political Studies 29, no. 2 (1996); Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters"; Anders Kjellberg, "Sweden: Restoring the Model?" in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Steen Scheuer, "Denmark: A Less Regulated Model," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Jens Lind, "EMU and Collective Bargaining in Denmark," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Kjellberg, A.1
  • 65
    • 0001540356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Denmark: A less regulated model
    • Ferner and Hyman, eds.
    • See Iversen, "Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining"; Jonas Pontusson and Peter Swenson, "Labor Markets, Production Strategies, and Wage Bargaining Institutions: The Swedish Employer Offensive in Comparative Perspective," Comparative Political Studies 29, no. 2 (1996); Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters"; Anders Kjellberg, "Sweden: Restoring the Model?" in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Steen Scheuer, "Denmark: A Less Regulated Model," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Jens Lind, "EMU and Collective Bargaining in Denmark," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Scheuer, S.1
  • 66
    • 85037759524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EMU and collective bargaining in Denmark
    • Fajertag and Pochet, eds.
    • See Iversen, "Power, Flexibility, and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining"; Jonas Pontusson and Peter Swenson, "Labor Markets, Production Strategies, and Wage Bargaining Institutions: The Swedish Employer Offensive in Comparative Perspective," Comparative Political Studies 29, no. 2 (1996); Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters"; Anders Kjellberg, "Sweden: Restoring the Model?" in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Steen Scheuer, "Denmark: A Less Regulated Model," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe; Jens Lind, "EMU and Collective Bargaining in Denmark," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • Social Pacts in Europe
    • Lind, J.1
  • 67
    • 0040690293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Thelen, "Why German Employers Cannot Bring Themselves to Abandon the German Model"; Reinhard Bispinck, "Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Otto Jacobi, Berndt Keller, and Walther Müller-Jentsch, "Germany: Facing New Challenges," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Why German Employers Cannot Bring Themselves to Abandon the German Model
    • Thelen1
  • 68
    • 0002756573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Germany: The chequered history of the alliance for jobs
    • Fajertag and Pochet, eds.
    • See Thelen, "Why German Employers Cannot Bring Themselves to Abandon the German Model"; Reinhard Bispinck, "Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Otto Jacobi, Berndt Keller, and Walther Müller-Jentsch, "Germany: Facing New Challenges," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Social Pacts in Europe
    • Bispinck, R.1
  • 69
    • 0002987836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Germany: Facing new challenges
    • Ferner and Hyman, eds.
    • See Thelen, "Why German Employers Cannot Bring Themselves to Abandon the German Model"; Reinhard Bispinck, "Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe; Otto Jacobi, Berndt Keller, and Walther Müller-Jentsch, "Germany: Facing New Challenges," in Ferner and Hyman, eds., Changing Industrial Relations in Europe.
    • Changing Industrial Relations in Europe
    • Jacobi, O.1    Keller, B.2    Müller-Jentsch, W.3
  • 72
    • 0039674852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Italian solution, see Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism? " On the pension reform in France, see Laurent Duclos and Olivier Mériaux, "Private Interest Governments under State Constraint: The Case of French 'paritarism'" (paper presented at SASE 10th International Conference, Vienna, 13-16 July 1998); on the protest movement against such reform, see Francois Piotet, "Les événements de décembre 1995, chroniques d'un conflit," Sociologie du Travail, no. 4 (1997).
    • Still Engaging in Corporatism?
    • Regini1
  • 73
    • 0039505075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private interest governments under state constraint: The case of French 'paritarism'
    • Vienna, 13-16 July
    • On the Italian solution, see Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism? " On the pension reform in France, see Laurent Duclos and Olivier Mériaux, "Private Interest Governments under State Constraint: The Case of French 'paritarism'" (paper presented at SASE 10th International Conference, Vienna, 13-16 July 1998); on the protest movement against such reform, see Francois Piotet, "Les événements de décembre 1995, chroniques d'un conflit," Sociologie du Travail, no. 4 (1997).
    • (1998) SASE 10th International Conference
    • Duclos, L.1    Mériaux, O.2
  • 74
    • 0039505078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Les événements de décembre 1995, chroniques d'un conflit
    • On the Italian solution, see Regini, "Still Engaging in Corporatism? " On the pension reform in France, see Laurent Duclos and Olivier Mériaux, "Private Interest Governments under State Constraint: The Case of French 'paritarism'" (paper presented at SASE 10th International Conference, Vienna, 13-16 July 1998); on the protest movement against such reform, see Francois Piotet, "Les événements de décembre 1995, chroniques d'un conflit," Sociologie du Travail, no. 4 (1997).
    • (1997) Sociologie du Travail , Issue.4
    • Piotet, F.1
  • 75
    • 0007277603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fuchs and Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility"; Bispinck, "Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs"; Anton Hemerijck, "Renegotiating the Dutch Welfare State" (paper presented at S ASE 10th International Conference, Vienna, 13-16 July 1998); Jan Peter van den Toren, "A 'Tripartite Consensus Economy' : The Dutch Variant of a Social Pact," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • Germany: A Regulated Flexibility
    • Fuchs1    Schettkat2
  • 76
    • 0002756573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fuchs and Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility"; Bispinck, "Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs"; Anton Hemerijck, "Renegotiating the Dutch Welfare State" (paper presented at S ASE 10th International Conference, Vienna, 13-16 July 1998); Jan Peter van den Toren, "A 'Tripartite Consensus Economy' : The Dutch Variant
    • Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs
    • Bispinck1
  • 77
    • 85037764078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Renegotiating the Dutch welfare state
    • Vienna, 13-16 July
    • See Fuchs and Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility"; Bispinck, "Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs"; Anton Hemerijck, "Renegotiating the Dutch Welfare State" (paper presented at S ASE 10th International Conference, Vienna, 13-16 July 1998); Jan Peter van den Toren, "A 'Tripartite Consensus Economy' : The Dutch Variant of a Social Pact," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • (1998) SASE 10th International Conference
    • Hemerijck, A.1
  • 78
    • 2042449959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A 'tripartite consensus economy' : The Dutch variant of a social pact
    • Fajertag and Pochet, eds.
    • See Fuchs and Schettkat, "Germany: A Regulated Flexibility"; Bispinck, "Germany: The Chequered History of the Alliance for Jobs"; Anton Hemerijck, "Renegotiating the Dutch Welfare State" (paper presented at S ASE 10th International Conference, Vienna, 13-16 July 1998); Jan Peter van den Toren, "A 'Tripartite Consensus Economy' : The Dutch Variant of a Social Pact," in Fajertag and Pochet, eds., Social Pacts in Europe.
    • Social Pacts in Europe
    • Van Den Toren, J.P.1
  • 79
    • 0001357236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Martinez Lucio, "Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation"; O'Donnell and O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96"; Björklund, "Going Different Ways"; Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters."
    • Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation
    • Lucio, M.1
  • 80
    • 33847367772 scopus 로고
    • See Martinez Lucio, "Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation"; O'Donnell and O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96"; Björklund, "Going Different Ways"; Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters."
    • (1987) Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96
    • O'Donnell1    O'Reardon2
  • 81
    • 4243854840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Martinez Lucio, "Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation"; O'Donnell and O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96"; Björklund, "Going Different Ways"; Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters."
    • Going Different Ways
    • Björklund1
  • 82
    • 85037751771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Martinez Lucio, "Spain: Regulating Employment and Social Fragmentation"; O'Donnell and O'Reardon, "Ireland's Experiment in Social Partnership, 1987-96"; Björklund, "Going Different Ways"; Dølvik and Martin, "A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters."
    • A Spanner in the Works and Oil on Troubled Waters
    • Dølvik1    Martin2
  • 84
    • 84937286888 scopus 로고
    • The crisis of government in Italy
    • Michele Salvati, "The Crisis of Government in Italy," New Left Review, no. 2/3 (1995).
    • (1995) New Left Review , Issue.2-3
    • Salvati, M.1
  • 86
    • 0002854017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social institutions and production structure: The Italian variety of capitalism in the 1980s
    • Crouch and Streeck, eds.
    • Marino Regini, "Social Institutions and Production Structure: The Italian Variety of Capitalism in the 1980s," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
    • Political Economy of Modern Capitalism
    • Regini, M.1
  • 87
    • 85037766512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, there are other variables of a more organizational character that can explain Confindustria's position, which differs from that of other employers' associations such as Confcommercio. The fragmentation of employer representation and its consequent loss of influence, in particular, may have induced Confindustria to step up its presence at the "concertation table" to regain legitimation among employers. However, its strongly positive stance has not changed even on the occasion of the social pact signed in December 1998, when it lost its oligopolistic position as a result of the new government's decision to involve the maximum possible number of actors in the negotiations.
  • 88
    • 0002404278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Globalisation, labour markets and welfare states: A future of competitive corporatism?
    • M. Rhodes and Y. Meny, eds., London: Macmillan
    • Martin Rhodes, "Globalisation, Labour Markets and Welfare States: A Future of Competitive Corporatism?" in M. Rhodes and Y. Meny, eds., The Future of European Welfare: A New Social Contract? (London: Macmillan, 1997).
    • (1997) The Future of European Welfare: A New Social Contract?
    • Rhodes, M.1
  • 89
    • 0039852216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Thelen, "Why German Employers"; Jacobi, Keller, and Müller-Jentsch, "Germany: Facing New Challenges."
    • Why German Employers
    • Thelen1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.