메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 28, Issue 3, 1999, Pages 353-382

The social structure of liquidity: Flexibility, markets, and states

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0033419229     PISSN: 03042421     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1023/A:1006903103304     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (220)

References (51)
  • 1
    • 0003610739 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Harvard University Press
    • Liquidity also grants to market participants the "exit" option to express their unhappiness with a commodity. See Albert O. Hirschman, Exit, Voice and Loyally (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970).
    • (1970) Exit, Voice and Loyally
    • Hirschman, A.O.1
  • 3
    • 50249092941 scopus 로고
    • Economics and politics in the age of modern capitalism
    • Felix Gilbert, editor New York: Oxford University Press
    • The eighteenth-century British case involves an early modern state and market in their co-evolution. The American case involves a mature capitalist economy with a developed state. See Otto Hintze, "Economics and Politics in the Age of Modern Capitalism," in The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, Felix Gilbert, editor (New York: Oxford University Press, 1975), 424-452.
    • (1975) The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze , pp. 424-452
    • Hintze, O.1
  • 4
    • 0032333481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securitization: A new era in American finance
    • Leon T. Kendall and Michael J. Fishman, editors (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996)
    • Leon T. Kendall, "Securitization: A New Era in American Finance," in A Primer on Securitization, Leon T. Kendall and Michael J. Fishman, editors (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996), 5. An organized futures market: "...deals in a highly fungible good that is readily traded among strangers." Lester G. Telser and Harlow N. Higinbotham, "Organized Futures Markets: Costs and Benefits," Journal of Political Economy, 85 (1977): 969-1000, 997. Futures markets reduce and simplify the informational requirements of their members, facilitating trade and rendering futures contracts more liquid. Berle and Means put it thus: "... if property is to become a liquid ... it must become impersonal" Berle and Means, The Modern Corporation, 250. For a discussion of the more general issue of commensuration and cognition, see Wendy Nelson Espeland and Mitchell L. Stevens, "Commensuration as a Social Process," Annual Review of Sociology, 24 (1998): 313-343.
    • A Primer on Securitization , pp. 5
    • Kendall, L.T.1
  • 5
    • 0032333481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Organized futures markets: Costs and benefits
    • Leon T. Kendall, "Securitization: A New Era in American Finance," in A Primer on Securitization, Leon T. Kendall and Michael J. Fishman, editors (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996), 5. An organized futures market: "...deals in a highly fungible good that is readily traded among strangers." Lester G. Telser and Harlow N. Higinbotham, "Organized Futures Markets: Costs and Benefits," Journal of Political Economy, 85 (1977): 969-1000, 997. Futures markets reduce and simplify the informational requirements of their members, facilitating trade and rendering futures contracts more liquid. Berle and Means put it thus: "... if property is to become a liquid ... it must become impersonal" Berle and Means, The Modern Corporation, 250. For a discussion of the more general issue of commensuration and cognition, see Wendy Nelson Espeland and Mitchell L. Stevens, "Commensuration as a Social Process," Annual Review of Sociology, 24 (1998): 313-343.
    • (1977) Journal of Political Economy , vol.85 , pp. 969-1000
    • Telser, L.G.1    Higinbotham, H.N.2
  • 6
    • 0032333481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leon T. Kendall, "Securitization: A New Era in American Finance," in A Primer on Securitization, Leon T. Kendall and Michael J. Fishman, editors (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996), 5. An organized futures market: "...deals in a highly fungible good that is readily traded among strangers." Lester G. Telser and Harlow N. Higinbotham, "Organized Futures Markets: Costs and Benefits," Journal of Political Economy, 85 (1977): 969-1000, 997. Futures markets reduce and simplify the informational requirements of their members, facilitating trade and rendering futures contracts more liquid. Berle and Means put it thus: "... if property is to become a liquid ... it must become impersonal" Berle and Means, The Modern Corporation, 250. For a discussion of the more general issue of commensuration and cognition, see Wendy Nelson Espeland and Mitchell L. Stevens, "Commensuration as a Social Process," Annual Review of Sociology, 24 (1998): 313-343.
    • The Modern Corporation , pp. 250
    • Berle1    Means2
  • 7
    • 0032333481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commensuration as a social process
    • Leon T. Kendall, "Securitization: A New Era in American Finance," in A Primer on Securitization, Leon T. Kendall and Michael J. Fishman, editors (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996), 5. An organized futures market: "...deals in a highly fungible good that is readily traded among strangers." Lester G. Telser and Harlow N. Higinbotham, "Organized Futures Markets: Costs and Benefits," Journal of Political Economy, 85 (1977): 969-1000, 997. Futures markets reduce and simplify the informational requirements of their members, facilitating trade and rendering futures contracts more liquid. Berle and Means put it thus: "... if property is to become a liquid ... it must become impersonal" Berle and Means, The Modern Corporation, 250. For a discussion of the more general issue of commensuration and cognition, see Wendy Nelson Espeland and Mitchell L. Stevens, "Commensuration as a Social Process," Annual Review of Sociology, 24 (1998): 313-343.
    • (1998) Annual Review of Sociology , vol.24 , pp. 313-343
    • Espeland, W.N.1    Stevens, M.L.2
  • 8
    • 0003550589 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Although we emphasize here the effect of classification schemes on supply and demand (and thus market liquidity), sometimes causality goes the other way. See Charles W. Smith, Auctions: The Social Construction of Value (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989), 31.
    • (1989) Auctions: The Social Construction of Value , pp. 31
    • Smith, C.W.1
  • 9
    • 0038976256 scopus 로고
    • Financial intermediaries
    • John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, editors New York: Norton
    • James Tobin, "Financial Intermediaries," in The New Palgrave: Finance, John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, editors (New York: Norton, 1989), 42.
    • (1989) The New Palgrave: Finance , pp. 42
    • Tobin, J.1
  • 10
    • 0019940072 scopus 로고
    • Measurement cost and the organization of markets
    • Yoram Barzel, "Measurement Cost and the Organization of Markets," Journal of Law and Economics 25 (1982): 27-48.
    • (1982) Journal of Law and Economics , vol.25 , pp. 27-48
    • Barzel, Y.1
  • 11
    • 0004217542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Harvard University Press
    • Mitchel Y. Abolafia, Making Markets: Opportunism and Restraint on Wall Street (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1996), 24. Keynes put the matter thus: "...professional investment may be likened to those newspaper competitions in which the competitors have to pick out the six prettiest faces from a hundred photographs, the prize being awarded to the competitor whose choice most nearly corresponds to the average preferences of the competitors as a whole; so that each competitor has to pick, not the faces which he himself finds prettiest, but those which he thinks likeliest to catch the fancy of the other competitors, all of whom are looking at the problem from the same point of view." John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1964), 156.
    • (1996) Making Markets: Opportunism and Restraint on Wall Street , pp. 24
    • Abolafia, M.Y.1
  • 12
    • 0004064059 scopus 로고
    • New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich
    • Mitchel Y. Abolafia, Making Markets: Opportunism and Restraint on Wall Street (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1996), 24. Keynes put the matter thus: "...professional investment may be likened to those newspaper competitions in which the competitors have to pick out the six prettiest faces from a hundred photographs, the prize being awarded to the competitor whose choice most nearly corresponds to the average preferences of the competitors as a whole; so that each competitor has to pick, not the faces which he himself finds prettiest, but those which he thinks likeliest to catch the fancy of the other competitors, all of whom are looking at the problem from the same point of view." John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1964), 156.
    • (1964) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money , pp. 156
    • Keynes, J.M.1
  • 13
    • 0003487402 scopus 로고
    • Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books
    • Or, similarly, the determination of a transfer price in the absence of comparable market prices. See Robert C. Eccles, The Transfer Pricing Problem: A Theory for Practice (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1985).
    • (1985) The Transfer Pricing Problem: A Theory for Practice
    • Eccles, R.C.1
  • 15
    • 5544304781 scopus 로고
    • Why there are organized futures markets
    • Lester G. Telser, "Why There are Organized Futures Markets," Journal of Law and Economics 24 (1981): 1-22, and Telser and Higinbotham, "Organized Futures Markets," describe how organized futures exchanges create liquid markets.
    • (1981) Journal of Law and Economics , vol.24 , pp. 1-22
    • Telser, L.G.1
  • 16
    • 0040754612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • describe how organized futures exchanges create liquid markets
    • Lester G. Telser, "Why There are Organized Futures Markets," Journal of Law and Economics 24 (1981): 1-22, and Telser and Higinbotham, "Organized Futures Markets," describe how organized futures exchanges create liquid markets.
    • Organized Futures Markets
    • Telser1    Higinbotham2
  • 18
    • 85040899632 scopus 로고
    • New York: Norton
    • See William Cronon, Nature's Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West (New York: Norton, 1991), 116-120; Jonathan Lurie, The Chicago Board of Trade 1859-1905: The Dynamics of Self-Regulation (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1979). Sheehan describes in entertaining detail the lengths to which Green Giant goes to produce predictable, homogeneous, uniform green peas. Susan Sheehan, "Peas," The New Yorker, Sept. 17, (1973): 103-118.
    • (1991) Nature's Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West , pp. 116-120
    • Cronon, W.1
  • 19
    • 0004218350 scopus 로고
    • Urbana: University of Illinois Press
    • See William Cronon, Nature's Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West (New York: Norton, 1991), 116-120; Jonathan Lurie, The Chicago Board of Trade 1859-1905: The Dynamics of Self-Regulation (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1979). Sheehan describes in entertaining detail the lengths to which Green Giant goes to produce predictable, homogeneous, uniform green peas. Susan Sheehan, "Peas," The New Yorker, Sept. 17, (1973): 103-118.
    • (1979) The Chicago Board of Trade 1859-1905: The Dynamics of Self-regulation
    • Lurie, J.1
  • 20
    • 0038976243 scopus 로고
    • Peas
    • Sept. 17
    • See William Cronon, Nature's Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West (New York: Norton, 1991), 116-120; Jonathan Lurie, The Chicago Board of Trade 1859-1905: The Dynamics of Self-Regulation (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1979). Sheehan describes in entertaining detail the lengths to which Green Giant goes to produce predictable, homogeneous, uniform green peas. Susan Sheehan, "Peas," The New Yorker, Sept. 17, (1973): 103-118.
    • (1973) The New Yorker , pp. 103-118
    • Sheehan, S.1
  • 21
    • 0040754616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, the spread between market makers' buying and selling prices reflects liquidity. A high spread indicates low liquidity, and vice versa. See Telser, "Why There Are Organized Futures Markets," 17.
    • Why there are Organized Futures Markets , pp. 17
  • 22
    • 0003593911 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • For the details on how bills operated, see Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 5-7.
    • (1990) The Rise of Financial Capitalism , pp. 5-7
    • Neal, L.1
  • 24
    • 0038976245 scopus 로고
    • Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution
    • See U.S. Department of the Treasury, Government Sponsorship of the Federal National Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1996), 17; Anthony Downs, The Revolution in Real Estate (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1985), 239.
    • (1985) The Revolution in Real Estate , pp. 239
    • Downs, A.1
  • 25
    • 0031286982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The value of federal sponsorship: The case of freddie mac
    • James F. Gatti and Ronald W. Spahr, "The Value of Federal Sponsorship: The Case of Freddie Mac," Real Estate Economics 25 (1997): 453-485,453.
    • (1997) Real Estate Economics , vol.25 , pp. 453-485
    • Gatti, J.F.1    Spahr, R.W.2
  • 28
    • 0038976251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This does not imply that such stratifications of risk into junior and senior categories necessarily makes senior claims more liquid than junior ones. In the case of claims on a corporation, for example, shares (residual or junior claims) can be as liquid as bonds (senior claims). What matters is that both are relatively homogeneous classes of assets, with knowable risks.
  • 29
    • 84928218676 scopus 로고
    • Allocating information costs in a negotiated information order
    • Compare this to the "negotiated information order" in Carol A. Heimer, "Allocating Information Costs in a Negotiated Information Order," Administrative Science Quarterly 30 (1985): 395-417.
    • (1985) Administrative Science Quarterly , vol.30 , pp. 395-417
    • Heimer, C.A.1
  • 30
    • 85005305538 scopus 로고
    • The market for lemons: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism
    • George A. Akerlof, "The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism." Journal of Economics, 84(1970): 488-500.
    • (1970) Journal of Economics , vol.84 , pp. 488-500
    • Akerlof, G.A.1
  • 32
    • 0039569094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Underwriting such liquidity has increased homeownership and thus also provided political benefits to the government.
  • 34
    • 0004198592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A new liquid financial instrument, the collateralized mortgage obligation (CMO) solved this problem of prepayments: "Take a typical three-hundred-million-dollar CMO. It would be divided into three tranches, or slices of a hundred million dollars each. Investors in each tranche received interest payments. But the owners of the first tranche received all principal repayments, from all three hundred million dollars of mortgage bonds held in trust. Not until first tranche holders were entirely paid off did second tranche investors receive any prepayments. Not until both first and second tranche investors had been entirely paid off did the holder of a third tranche certificate receive prepayments.... Now at last, investors had a degree of certainty about the length of their loans. As a result of CMOs, there was a dramatic increase in the number of investors and volume of trading in the market." Lewis, Liar's Poker, 136-137.
    • Liar's Poker , pp. 136-137
    • Lewis1
  • 36
    • 0001109442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Learning and the creation of stock-market institutions: Evidence from the royal African and Hudson's Bay companies, 1670-1700
    • Ann Carlos, Jennifer Key, and Jill DuPree, "Learning and the Creation of Stock-Market Institutions: Evidence from the Royal African and Hudson's Bay Companies, 1670-1700," Journal of Economic History 58 (1998): 318-344, 332, 337.
    • (1998) Journal of Economic History , vol.58 , pp. 318-344
    • Carlos, A.1    Jennifer, K.2    DuPree, J.3
  • 37
    • 78751590105 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1766
    • Sir William Blackstone, Commentaries on the Laws of England, Vol. 2 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979 [1766]), 442; Bruce G. Carruthers, City of Capital: Politics and Markets in the English Financial Revolution (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996), 129-132.
    • (1979) Commentaries on the Laws of England , vol.2 , pp. 442
    • Blackstone, W.1
  • 44
    • 0003914156 scopus 로고
    • New York: W.W. Norton
    • Joseph Stiglitz, Economics (New York: W.W. Norton, 1993), 260.
    • (1993) Economics , pp. 260
    • Stiglitz, J.1
  • 47
    • 84953736822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • And, as Keynes pointed out, asset-owners cannot all be liquid at the same time. See General Theory, 155.
    • General Theory , pp. 155
  • 48
    • 0004207562 scopus 로고
    • Boston: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1907
    • Georg Simmel, The Philosophy of Money (Boston: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1978 [1907]), 131-203.
    • (1978) The Philosophy of Money , pp. 131-203
    • Simmel, G.1
  • 49
    • 0032348653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making things the same: Representation, tolerance and the end of the ancien régime in France
    • For some interesting work on the history and politics of standardization, metrology, and the creation of uniformity, see Ken Alder, "Making Things the Same: Representation, Tolerance and the End of the Ancien Régime in France," Social Studies of Science, 22 (1998): 499-545, and Bruce Curtis, "From the Moral Thermometer to Money: Metrological Reform in Pre-Confederation Canada," Social Studies of Science, 22 (1998): 547-570.
    • (1998) Social Studies of Science , vol.22 , pp. 499-545
    • Alder, K.1
  • 50
    • 0032355006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From the moral thermometer to money: Metrological reform in pre-confederation Canada
    • For some interesting work on the history and politics of standardization, metrology, and the creation of uniformity, see Ken Alder, "Making Things the Same: Representation, Tolerance and the End of the Ancien Régime in France," Social Studies of Science, 22 (1998): 499-545, and Bruce Curtis, "From the Moral Thermometer to Money: Metrological Reform in Pre-Confederation Canada," Social Studies of Science, 22 (1998): 547-570.
    • (1998) Social Studies of Science , vol.22 , pp. 547-570
    • Curtis, B.1
  • 51
    • 84936824322 scopus 로고
    • Accounting for rationality: Double-entry bookkeeping and the rhetoric of economic rationality
    • Bruce G. Carruthers and Wendy Nelson Espeland, "Accounting for Rationality: Double-Entry Bookkeeping and the Rhetoric of Economic Rationality," American Journal of Sociology, 97 (1991): 31-69.
    • (1991) American Journal of Sociology , vol.97 , pp. 31-69
    • Carruthers, B.G.1    Espeland, W.N.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.