-
1
-
-
6744275478
-
When Competitive Advantage Is Neither
-
21 April
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "When Competitive Advantage Is Neither," Wall Street Journal, 21 April 1997a, p. 22.
-
(1997)
Wall Street Journal
, pp. 22
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
3
-
-
0030621889
-
Value Innovation: The Strategic Logic of High Growth
-
January-February
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Value Innovation: The Strategic Logic of High Growth," Harvard Business Review, volume 75, January-February 1997c, pp. 102-112.
-
(1997)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.75
, pp. 102-112
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
6
-
-
6744269868
-
-
Kim and Mauborgne (1997c)
-
Kim and Mauborgne (1997c).
-
-
-
-
7
-
-
84989023371
-
Strategic Management and Economics
-
Winter
-
R.P. Rumelt, D. Sehendel, and D. J. Teece, "Strategic Management and Economics," Strategic Management Journal, volume 12, Winter 1991, pp. 5-29.
-
(1991)
Strategic Management Journal
, vol.12
, pp. 5-29
-
-
Rumelt, R.P.1
Sehendel, D.2
Teece, D.J.3
-
8
-
-
84989040103
-
Why Do Firms Differ, and How Does it Matter?
-
Winter
-
R.R. Nelson, "Why Do Firms Differ, and How Does it Matter?" Strategic Management Journal, volume 12, Winter 1991, pp. 61-74.
-
(1991)
Strategic Management Journal
, vol.12
, pp. 61-74
-
-
Nelson, R.R.1
-
9
-
-
0032619380
-
Creating New Market Space
-
January-February
-
For a discussion on the importance and patterns of creating new markets, see W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Creating New Market Space," Harvard Business Review, volume 77, January-February 1999, pp. 83-93: also see: G. Hamel and C.K. Prahalad, Competing for the Future (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994).
-
(1999)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.77
, pp. 83-93
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
10
-
-
0032619380
-
-
Boston: Harvard Business School Press
-
For a discussion on the importance and patterns of creating new markets, see W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Creating New Market Space," Harvard Business Review, volume 77, January-February 1999, pp. 83-93: also see: G. Hamel and C.K. Prahalad, Competing for the Future (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994).
-
(1994)
Competing for the Future
-
-
Hamel, G.1
Prahalad, C.K.2
-
11
-
-
6744269008
-
Value Knowledge or Pay the Price
-
29 January
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Value Knowledge or Pay the Price," Wall Street Journal Europe, 29 January 1998a, p. 6; and TA. Stewart, Intellectual Capital (New York: Currency/Doubleday. 1997).
-
(1998)
Wall Street Journal Europe
, pp. 6
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
12
-
-
0004104111
-
-
New York: Currency/Doubleday
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Value Knowledge or Pay the Price," Wall Street Journal Europe, 29 January 1998a, p. 6; and TA. Stewart, Intellectual Capital (New York: Currency/Doubleday. 1997).
-
(1997)
Intellectual Capital
-
-
Stewart, T.A.1
-
13
-
-
85018651986
-
Endogenous Technological Change
-
October
-
P. Romer, "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political Economy, volume 98, October 1990, pp. S71-S102; P.M. Romer, "The Origins of Endogenous Growth," Journal of Economic Perspectives, volume 8, Winter 1994, pp. 3- 22; and G.M. Grossman and E. Helpman, Innovation and Growth (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1995).
-
(1990)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.98
-
-
Romer, P.1
-
14
-
-
85018651986
-
The Origins of Endogenous Growth
-
Winter
-
P. Romer, "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political Economy, volume 98, October 1990, pp. S71-S102; P.M. Romer, "The Origins of Endogenous Growth," Journal of Economic Perspectives, volume 8, Winter 1994, pp. 3- 22; and G.M. Grossman and E. Helpman, Innovation and Growth (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1995).
-
(1994)
Journal of Economic Perspectives
, vol.8
, pp. 3-22
-
-
Romer, P.M.1
-
15
-
-
85018651986
-
-
Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press
-
P. Romer, "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political Economy, volume 98, October 1990, pp. S71-S102; P.M. Romer, "The Origins of Endogenous Growth," Journal of Economic Perspectives, volume 8, Winter 1994, pp. 3- 22; and G.M. Grossman and E. Helpman, Innovation and Growth (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1995).
-
(1995)
Innovation and Growth
-
-
Grossman, G.M.1
Helpman, E.2
-
16
-
-
0000512905
-
Differentiation Versus Low Cost or Differentiation and Low Cost
-
July
-
C.W L. Hill, "Differentiation Versus Low Cost or Differentiation and Low Cost," Academy of Management Review, volume 13, July 1988, pp. 401-412. Hill argues that low cost and differentiation do not have to be an either-or choice.
-
(1988)
Academy of Management Review
, vol.13
, pp. 401-412
-
-
Hill, C.W.L.1
-
17
-
-
0031498046
-
Technology Brokening and Innovation in a Product Development Firm
-
December
-
For the most recent research on this, see: A. Hargadon and R. Sutton. "Technology Brokening and Innovation in a Product Development Firm," Administrative Science Quarterly, volume 42, December 1997, pp. 716-749.
-
(1997)
Administrative Science Quarterly
, vol.42
, pp. 716-749
-
-
Hargadon, A.1
Sutton, R.2
-
18
-
-
0003584083
-
-
New York: Free Press
-
For an excellent discussion on this, see. E.M. Rogers, Diffusion of Innovations (New York: Free Press, 1995).
-
(1995)
Diffusion of Innovations
-
-
Rogers, E.M.1
-
19
-
-
6744273863
-
-
For more discussion on this, see: Kim and Mauborgne (1999)
-
For more discussion on this, see: Kim and Mauborgne (1999).
-
-
-
-
20
-
-
0003971613
-
-
Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press
-
For a discussion of "creative destruction," see: J.A. Schumpeter. The Theory of Economic Development (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1934).
-
(1934)
The Theory of Economic Development
-
-
Schumpeter, J.A.1
-
21
-
-
0030188444
-
Increasing Returns and the New World of Business
-
1934; 1990; July-August
-
For discussion of the importance of innovators' monopoly profits, see: Schumpeter (1934); Romer (1990); and W.B. Arthur, "Increasing Returns and the New World of Business," Harvard Business Review, volume 74, July-August 1996, pp. 100-109.
-
(1996)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.74
, pp. 100-109
-
-
Schumpeter1
Romer2
Arthur, W.B.3
-
22
-
-
84936526527
-
Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth
-
October and Arthur (1996)
-
R Romer, "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth," Journal of Political Economy, volume 94, October 1986, pp. 1002-1037; and Arthur (1996).
-
(1986)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.94
, pp. 1002-1037
-
-
Romer, R.1
-
23
-
-
0000584479
-
Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Inventions
-
R.R. Nelson, ed., Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, and Romer (1990)
-
K.J. Arrow, "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Inventions," in R.R. Nelson, ed., The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1962), pp. 609-626; and Romer (1990). It is worth noting that both Arrow and Romer limited their discussions of nonrival and nonexcludable goods to technological innovations as is the tradition of economics. When the concept of innovation is redefined as value innovation, which is more relevant at the microeconomic firm level, the importance of the nonrival and nonexcludable notion is even more striking. This is because technological innovation often has a greater excludable component due to the possibility and relative ease of obtaining patent protection.
-
(1962)
The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity
, pp. 609-626
-
-
Arrow, K.J.1
-
24
-
-
0031230342
-
Needed: A New System of Intellectual Property Rights
-
September-October
-
For a brrliiant discussion of this issue, see: L.C. Thurow, "Needed: A New System of Intellectual Property Rights," Harvard Business Review, volume 75, September-October 1997, pp. 94-103.
-
(1997)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.75
, pp. 94-103
-
-
Thurow, L.C.1
-
25
-
-
6744273386
-
-
note
-
The extent to which the idea behind a value innovation is nonexcludable affects the strategic price set by the value innovator. As we have argued, while innovative ideas and processes are usually nonexcludable or only partially so, some value innovators have patentable ideas that are excludable for a given time. In these cases, value innovators may be inclined to price their product the same or higher than rivals' products and services. However, recognizing the powerful economies of scale, learning, and increasing returns that come with high volumes of knowledge-intensive goods, the strategic price will still be set from the outset with an aim to capture the mass of buyers. In the United Kingdom, Dyson Appliances, for example, created a value innovation in vacuum cleaners with its launch of the Dyson Dual Cyclone, which eliminated vacuum cleaner bags and the hassle of replacing bags for the life of the vacuum. In doing so, Dyson also increased the suction power of its vacuum cleaner dramatically over the industry average. Given the radically superior value of its product and the fact that its value innovation was patentable. Dyson strategically set its price relatively high while still capturing the mass of buyers. Although the vaccum cleaner was priced higher than the competition, it was a leap in value and within the economic reach of the mass of buyers. In this instance, Dyson did not use the conventional monopolist's practice of restricting supply by establishing a high price.
-
-
-
-
26
-
-
6744253993
-
A Corporate Future Built with New Blocks
-
29 March Section 3
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "A Corporate Future Built with New Blocks," New York Times, 29 March 1998b, Section 3, p. 14.
-
(1998)
New York Times
, pp. 14
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
27
-
-
84989056644
-
Towards a Dynamic Theory of Strategy
-
Winter
-
For thought-provoking discussions on the implications of a focus on a company's current capabilities, see: M.E. Porter, "Towards a Dynamic Theory of Strategy," Strategic Management Journal, volume 12, Winter 1991, pp. 95-117; and M.L Tushman and P. Anderson, "Technological Discontinuities and Organizational Environments," Administrative Science Quarterly, volume 31, September 1986, pp. 439-465.
-
(1991)
Strategic Management Journal
, vol.12
, pp. 95-117
-
-
Porter, M.E.1
-
28
-
-
84989056644
-
Technological Discontinuities and Organizational Environments
-
September
-
For thought-provoking discussions on the implications of a focus on a company's current capabilities, see: M.E. Porter, "Towards a Dynamic Theory of Strategy," Strategic Management Journal, volume 12, Winter 1991, pp. 95-117; and M.L Tushman and P. Anderson, "Technological Discontinuities and Organizational Environments," Administrative Science Quarterly, volume 31, September 1986, pp. 439-465.
-
(1986)
Administrative Science Quarterly
, vol.31
, pp. 439-465
-
-
Tushman, M.L.1
Anderson, P.2
-
29
-
-
0002466427
-
Disruptive Technologies: Catching the Wave
-
January-February
-
That a focus on current customers can be detrimental to a firm's long-run viability is also discussed in: J.L. Bower and CM. Christensen, "Disruptive Technologies: Catching the Wave," Harvard Business Review, volume 73, January-February 1995, pp. 43-53.
-
(1995)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.73
, pp. 43-53
-
-
Bower, J.L.1
Christensen, C.M.2
-
30
-
-
6744269484
-
-
For a more thorough discussion on this, see: Kim and Mauborgne (1997c)
-
For a more thorough discussion on this, see: Kim and Mauborgne (1997c).
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
0003130475
-
When a Thousand Flowers Bloom: Structural, Collective, and Social Conditions for Innovation in Organizations
-
P.S. Myers, ed., Boston: Butterworth-Heinemann
-
The critical importance of top management setting clear expectations is highlighted in the works of Kanter and Amabile. See: R.M. Kanter, "When a Thousand Flowers Bloom: Structural, Collective, and Social Conditions for Innovation in Organizations," in P.S. Myers, ed., Knowledge Management and Organization Design (Boston: Butterworth-Heinemann, 1996), pp. 169-211; and T.M. Amabile, "A Model of Creativity and Innovation in Organizations," in Research in Organizational Behavior (Greenwich, Connecticut JAI Press, 1988), pp. 123-167.
-
(1996)
Knowledge Management and Organization Design
, pp. 169-211
-
-
Kanter, R.M.1
-
32
-
-
0001462036
-
A Model of Creativity and Innovation in Organizations
-
Greenwich, Connecticut JAI Press
-
The critical importance of top management setting clear expectations is highlighted in the works of Kanter and Amabile. See: R.M. Kanter, "When a Thousand Flowers Bloom: Structural, Collective, and Social Conditions for Innovation in Organizations," in P.S. Myers, ed., Knowledge Management and Organization Design (Boston: Butterworth-Heinemann, 1996), pp. 169-211; and T.M. Amabile, "A Model of Creativity and Innovation in Organizations," in Research in Organizational Behavior (Greenwich, Connecticut JAI Press, 1988), pp. 123-167.
-
(1988)
Research in Organizational Behavior
, pp. 123-167
-
-
Amabile, T.M.1
-
33
-
-
6744235156
-
-
note
-
This is consistent with the work of Amabile (1988), who argues that the most important elements of motivating innovation are concise and compelling articulation of the value of innovation, orientation away from the status quo, and activating an offensive leadership strategy aimed at the future, rather than simply trying to protect an organization's past.
-
-
-
-
34
-
-
6744274687
-
-
note
-
Kanter (1996) also argues for the importance of smaller units organized around common business objectives as a catalyst for innovative thinking in organizations.
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
0032161358
-
How to Kill Creativity
-
September-October
-
The important work on creativity conducted by Amabile clearly establishes the importance of autonomy in achieving strategic goals to foster creativity. See: T.M. Amabile, "How to Kill Creativity," Harvard Business Review, volume 76, September-October 1998, pp. 76-87.
-
(1998)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.76
, pp. 76-87
-
-
Amabile, T.M.1
-
36
-
-
6744274274
-
-
The need for diversity or cross-disciplinary contact to spark innovation is also well articulated in the excellent works of: Kanter (1996); and Amabile (1998)
-
The need for diversity or cross-disciplinary contact to spark innovation is also well articulated in the excellent works of: Kanter (1996); and Amabile (1998).
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
0004150769
-
-
San Francisco: Chandler Publishing Company
-
The roots of our distinction between voluntary and compulsory cooperation originate with: P. Blau and W.R. Scott, Formal Organizations (San Francisco: Chandler Publishing Company, 1962); and O.E. Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies (New York; Free Press, 1975).
-
(1962)
Formal Organizations
-
-
Blau, P.1
Scott, W.R.2
-
38
-
-
0004293745
-
-
New York; Free Press
-
The roots of our distinction between voluntary and compulsory cooperation originate with: P. Blau and W.R. Scott, Formal Organizations (San Francisco: Chandler Publishing Company, 1962); and O.E. Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies (New York; Free Press, 1975).
-
(1975)
Markets and Hierarchies
-
-
Williamson, O.E.1
-
39
-
-
6744253591
-
Building Trust
-
9 January
-
Kim and Mauborgne (1998a); and W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Building Trust," Financial Times, 9 January 1998e, p. 25.
-
(1998)
Financial Times
, pp. 25
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
40
-
-
0031180478
-
Fair Process: Managing in the Knowledge Economy
-
July-August
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Fair Process: Managing in the Knowledge Economy," Harvard Business Review, volume 75, July-August 1997, pp. 65-75; W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Procedural Justice, Strategic Decision Making and the Knowledge Economy," Strategic Management Journal, volume 19, April 1998, pp. 323-338; and W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "A Procedural Justice Model of Strategic Decision Making: Strategy Content Implications," Organization Science, volume 19, January-February 1995, pp. 44-61.
-
(1997)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.75
, pp. 65-75
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
41
-
-
0000558763
-
Procedural Justice, Strategic Decision Making and the Knowledge Economy
-
April
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Fair Process: Managing in the Knowledge Economy," Harvard Business Review, volume 75, July-August 1997, pp. 65-75; W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Procedural Justice, Strategic Decision Making and the Knowledge Economy," Strategic Management Journal, volume 19, April 1998, pp. 323-338; and W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "A Procedural Justice Model of Strategic Decision Making: Strategy Content Implications," Organization Science, volume 19, January-February 1995, pp. 44-61.
-
(1998)
Strategic Management Journal
, vol.19
, pp. 323-338
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
42
-
-
0011539753
-
A Procedural Justice Model of Strategic Decision Making: Strategy Content Implications
-
January-February
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Fair Process: Managing in the Knowledge Economy," Harvard Business Review, volume 75, July-August 1997, pp. 65-75; W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Procedural Justice, Strategic Decision Making and the Knowledge Economy," Strategic Management Journal, volume 19, April 1998, pp. 323-338; and W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "A Procedural Justice Model of Strategic Decision Making: Strategy Content Implications," Organization Science, volume 19, January-February 1995, pp. 44-61.
-
(1995)
Organization Science
, vol.19
, pp. 44-61
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
43
-
-
1542778220
-
Procedural Justice and Managers' In-role and Extra-role Behavior
-
April
-
W.C. Kim and R. Mauborgne, "Procedural Justice and Managers' In-role and Extra-role Behavior," Management Science, volume 42, April 1996, pp. 499-515.
-
(1996)
Management Science
, vol.42
, pp. 499-515
-
-
Kim, W.C.1
Mauborgne, R.2
-
44
-
-
0003189799
-
What Is Strategy
-
November-December
-
For an excellent discussion of how strategy differs from operational improvements, see: M.E. Porter, "What Is Strategy" Harvard Business Review, volume 74, November-December 1996, pp. 61-78.
-
(1996)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.74
, pp. 61-78
-
-
Porter, M.E.1
|