메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 66, Issue 3, 1998, Pages 567-611

Making sense of State Oil Co. v. Khan: Vertical maximum price fixing under a rule of reason

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0032343346     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (7)

References (137)
  • 1
    • 18944394661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 118 S. Ct. 275 (1997)
    • 118 S. Ct. 275 (1997).
  • 2
    • 18944399728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 282 (citing Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986)). 3 390 U.S. 145 (1968.)
    • Id. at 282 (citing Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986)). 3 390 U.S. 145 (1968.)
  • 3
    • 18944369320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 153
    • Id. at 153.
  • 4
    • 18944389327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911)
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911).
  • 5
    • 18044363408 scopus 로고
    • The Seven Myths of Vertical Price Fixing: The Politics and Economics of a Century-Long Debate
    • Warren S. Grimes, The Seven Myths of Vertical Price Fixing: The Politics and Economics of a Century-Long Debate, 21 SW. U. L. REV. 1285, 1287-93 (1992).
    • (1992) Sw. U. L. Rev. , vol.21 , pp. 1285
    • Grimes, W.S.1
  • 6
    • 18944374055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 340 U.S. 211 (1951)
    • 340 U.S. 211 (1951).
  • 7
    • 84865906945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This aspect of the Kiefer-Stewart holding presumably would not suvive after Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752 (1984) (holding that a conspiracy under § 1 of the Sherman Act cannot be found between a corporation and its wholly owned subsidiary)
    • This aspect of the Kiefer-Stewart holding presumably would not suvive after Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752 (1984) (holding that a conspiracy under § 1 of the Sherman Act cannot be found between a corporation and its wholly owned subsidiary).
  • 8
    • 18944365836 scopus 로고
    • Comment, the Per Se Illegality of Price-Fixing - Sans Power, Purpose, or Effect
    • The background underlying Kiefer-Stewart is described in James A. Rahl, Comment, The Per Se Illegality of Price-Fixing - Sans Power, Purpose, or Effect, 19 U. CHI. L. REV. 837, 838-39 (1952). See also Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, 182 F.2d 228, 230-32 (7th Cir. 1950).
    • (1952) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.19 , pp. 837
    • Rahl, J.A.1
  • 9
    • 18944388609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kiefer-Stewart, 340 U.S. at 213
    • Kiefer-Stewart, 340 U.S. at 213.
  • 10
    • 18944381992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In his dissent in Albrecht, Justice Harlan read Kiefer-Stewart as a decision premised on a horizontal conspiracy between two liquor producers, ignoring the circumstance that they were commonly owned. Albrecht, 390 U.S. at 156, 164-65. Although correct on its face, this reading does not provide a basis for a credible economic analysis of the maximum resale prices imposed in Kiefer-Stewart. Because the facts demonstrate no horizontally generated market power at the producer or distributor level, a genuine economic analysis must assume the vertical nature of the price restraints.
  • 11
    • 18944369082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kiefer-Stewart, 340 U.S. at 214. According to one source, the minimum prices were also likely to operate as maximum prices because wholesalers could not distinguish their offerings from rivals' offerings, with the result that retailers would quickly switch to another supplier if a particular wholesaler's prices were out of line. Rahl, supra note 9, at 838-39.
  • 12
    • 18944380109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 388 U.S. 365 (1967)
    • 388 U.S. 365 (1967).
  • 13
    • 18944400688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Albrecht, 390 U.S. at 152-53
    • Albrecht, 390 U.S. at 152-53.
  • 14
    • 18944365170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 153
    • Id. at 153.
  • 15
    • 18944375425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 159
    • Id. at 159.
  • 16
    • 18944391126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Justice Stewart's dissent in Albrecht described the plaintiff distributor as "the only person who could sell for home delivery the city's only daily morning newspaper," and hence as "a monopolist widlin his own territory." Id. at 168.
  • 17
    • 18944371628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977)
    • Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977).
  • 18
    • 11544352070 scopus 로고
    • Maximum Resale Price Fixing Moves Toward the Rule of Reason
    • Among those who took this position were Roger Blair & Gordon Lang, Albrecht After ARCO, Maximum Resale Price Fixing Moves Toward the Rule of Reason, 44 VAND. L. REV. 1007 (1991); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 17 (3d ed. 1990); 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 1635 at 295 (1989); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886, 887-90 (1980); ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 281-82 (1978).
    • (1991) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 1007
    • Blair, R.1    Lang, G.2
  • 19
    • 0003728403 scopus 로고
    • 3d ed. 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 1635 at 295 (1989);
    • Among those who took this position were Roger Blair & Gordon Lang, Albrecht After ARCO, Maximum Resale Price Fixing Moves Toward the Rule of Reason, 44 VAND. L. REV. 1007 (1991); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 17 (3d ed. 1990); 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 1635 at 295 (1989); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886, 887-90 (1980); ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 281-82 (1978).
    • (1990) Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance , pp. 17
    • Scherer, F.M.1    Ross, D.2
  • 20
    • 0039894683 scopus 로고
    • Maximum Price Fixing
    • Among those who took this position were Roger Blair & Gordon Lang, Albrecht After ARCO, Maximum Resale Price Fixing Moves Toward the Rule of Reason, 44 VAND. L. REV. 1007 (1991); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 17 (3d ed. 1990); 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 1635 at 295 (1989); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886, 887-90 (1980); ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 281-82 (1978).
    • (1980) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 886
    • Easterbrook, F.1
  • 21
    • 0004004432 scopus 로고
    • Among those who took this position were Roger Blair & Gordon Lang, Albrecht After ARCO, Maximum Resale Price Fixing Moves Toward the Rule of Reason, 44 VAND. L. REV. 1007 (1991); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 17 (3d ed. 1990); 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 1635 at 295 (1989); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886, 887-90 (1980); ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 281-82 (1978).
    • (1978) The Antitrust Paradox , pp. 281-282
    • Bork, R.1
  • 22
    • 0003913144 scopus 로고
    • LAWRENCE SULLIVAN, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW OF ANTITRUST 391 (1977). Other defenders of Albrecht include Mark Roszkowski, Vertical Maximum Price Fixing: In Defense of Albrecht, 23 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 209 (1992); Recent Case: Khan v. State Oil Co., 110 HARV. L. REV. 523 (1996).
    • (1977) Handbook of the Law of Antitrust , pp. 391
    • Sullivan, L.1
  • 23
    • 18944386499 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Maximum Price Fixing: In Defense of Albrecht
    • LAWRENCE SULLIVAN, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW OF ANTITRUST 391 (1977). Other defenders of Albrecht include Mark Roszkowski, Vertical Maximum Price Fixing: In Defense of Albrecht, 23 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 209 (1992); Recent Case: Khan v. State Oil Co., 110 HARV. L. REV. 523 (1996).
    • (1992) Loy. U. Chi. L.J. , vol.23 , pp. 209
    • Roszkowski, M.1
  • 24
    • 18944377675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent Case: Khan v. State Oil Co
    • LAWRENCE SULLIVAN, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW OF ANTITRUST 391 (1977). Other defenders of Albrecht include Mark Roszkowski, Vertical Maximum Price Fixing: In Defense of Albrecht, 23 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 209 (1992); Recent Case: Khan v. State Oil Co., 110 HARV. L. REV. 523 (1996).
    • (1996) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.110 , pp. 523
  • 25
    • 18944376879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 495 U.S. 328 (1990)
    • 495 U.S. 328 (1990).
  • 26
    • 18944361931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 335 n.5
    • Id. at 335 n.5.
  • 27
    • 18944379596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 118 S. Ct. at 278
    • 118 S. Ct. at 278.
  • 28
    • 18944402895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 93 F.3d 1358 (7th Cir. 1996)
    • 93 F.3d 1358 (7th Cir. 1996).
  • 29
    • 18944388110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 136
    • Id. at 136.
  • 30
    • 18944379145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roundtable Conference with Enforcement Officials
    • Roundtable Conference with Enforcement Officials, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 929, 952 (1997).
    • (1997) Antitrust L.J. , vol.65 , pp. 929
  • 31
    • 18944367778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Amicus Brief for the United States and the Federal Trade Commission 25 (1997) ("Since Albrecht, we are aware of no case in which either the Commission or the United States has committed enforcement resources to proceeding against a party on the ground of purely vertical maximum price fixing.").
  • 32
    • 18944408007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Court refers to the per se rule against vertical maximum price fixing as "Albrecht's per se rule." 118 S. Ct. at 283.
  • 33
    • 85076747725 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Control with Bilateral Contracts
    • The government brief cites without discussion two economic studies said to explore circumstances in-which vertical maximum price fixing might be anticompetitive, but offers no explanation or support for these studies. Amicus Brief at 25 n.13 (citing Daniel P. O'Brien & Greg Shaffer, Vertical Control with Bilateral Contracts, 23 RAND J. ECON. 299 (1992); Martin K. Perry & David Besanko, Resale Price Maintenance and Manufacturer Competition for Exclusive Dealerships, 39 J. INDUS. ECON. 517 (1991)).
    • (1992) Rand J. Econ. , vol.23 , pp. 299
    • O'Brien, D.P.1    Shaffer, G.2
  • 34
    • 0040410105 scopus 로고
    • Resale Price Maintenance and Manufacturer Competition for Exclusive Dealerships
    • The government brief cites without discussion two economic studies said to explore circumstances in-which vertical maximum price fixing might be anticompetitive, but offers no explanation or support for these studies. Amicus Brief at 25 n.13 (citing Daniel P. O'Brien & Greg Shaffer, Vertical Control with Bilateral Contracts, 23 RAND J. ECON. 299 (1992); Martin K. Perry & David Besanko, Resale Price Maintenance and Manufacturer Competition for Exclusive Dealerships, 39 J. INDUS. ECON. 517 (1991)).
    • (1991) J. Indus. Econ. , vol.39 , pp. 517
    • Perry, M.K.1    Besanko, D.2
  • 35
    • 18944379381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 118 S. Ct. at 283. The Court goes on to state: "Neither the parties nor any of the amici curiae have called our attention to any cases in which enforcement efforts have been directed solely against the conduct encompassed by Albrecht's per se rule." Id. Presumably, the reference to "enforcement efforts" was meant to exclude private claims, of which there have been a substantial number. See infra note 31.
  • 36
    • 18944407761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In addition to vertical maximum price-fixing cases reaching the Supreme Court (Khan and ARCO), a number of post-Albrecht private claims were decided by courts of appeal. See, e.g., Acquaire v. Canada Dry Bottling Co., 24 F.3d 401 (2d Cir. 1994); Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke, Aktiengesellschaft, 19 F.3d 745 (1st Cir. 1994); Nordwest Publications, Inc. v. Crumb, 752 F.2d 473 (9th Cir. 1985); Jack Walters & Sons Corp. v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d 698 (7th Cir. 1984); Blanton v. Mobil Oil Corp., 721 F.2d 1207 (9th Cir. 1983); Auburn News Co. v. Providence Journal Co., 659 F.2d 273 (1st Cir. 1981); Yentsch v. Texaco, Inc., 630 F.2d 46 (2d Cir. 1980); Arnott v. American Oil Co., 609 F.2d 873 (8th Cir. 1979); Knutson v. Daily Review, Inc., 548 F.2d 795 (9th Cir. 1976); Bowen v. New York News, Inc., 522 F.2d 1242 (2d Cir. 1975); Blankenship v. Hearst Corp., 519 F.2d 418 (9th Cir. 1975); Greene v. General Foods Corp., 517 F.2d 635 (5th Cir. 1975); Milsen Co. v. Southland Corp., 454 F.2d 363 (7th Cir. 1971). There has already been at least one circuit court decision since the Supreme Court decided Khan. Mularkey v. Holsum Bakery, 1998-1 Trade Gas. (CCH) ¶ 72,183 (9th Cir. 1998).
  • 37
    • 18944375657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 118 S. Ct. at 283
    • 118 S. Ct. at 283.
  • 38
    • 11544316721 scopus 로고
    • Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust: A Snug Fit
    • Blair & Lang, supra note 19, at 1034
    • Id. at 282 (citing John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1, 60 (1995)); Blair & Lang, supra note 19, at 1034.
    • (1995) Antitrust Bull. , vol.40 , pp. 1
    • Lopatka, J.E.1
  • 39
    • 18944402997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Supreme Court restated this argument in ARCO: "When a manufacturer provides a dealer an exclusive area within which to distribute a product, the manufacturer's decision to fix a maximum resale price may actually protect consumers against exploitation by the dealer acting as a local monopolist." 495 U.S. at 343 n.13.
  • 40
    • 84865906938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Among those who made the argument were PHILUP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1636a, at 395 (1989)
    • Among those who made the argument were PHILUP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1636a, at 395 (1989).
  • 41
    • 18944403986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 118 S. Ct. at 283
    • 118 S. Ct. at 283.
  • 42
    • 18944404213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In 1995 less than 10% of all branded gasoline stations in Illinois were Union stations. Amicus Brief of the Service Station Dealers of America 15 (noting that in 1995 only 380 of 4038 branded service stations in Illinois were Union stations). See Recent Case, supra note 20, at 528 (concluding that Khan "probably had interbrand if not intrabrand competition . . . [and] would not have been capable of price gouging.").
  • 43
    • 18944373819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 118 S. Ct. at 282 (quoting Judge Posner's opinion, 93 F.3d at 1362)
    • 118 S. Ct. at 282 (quoting Judge Posner's opinion, 93 F.3d at 1362).
  • 44
    • 18944394660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 93 F.3d at 1362
    • 93 F.3d at 1362.
  • 45
    • 21444446636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When Do Franchisors Have Market Power? Antitrust Remedies for Franchisor Opportunism
    • See the discussion of franchisor encroachment in Warren S. Grimes, When Do Franchisors Have Market Power? Antitrust Remedies for Franchisor Opportunism, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 105, 136-41 (1996) [hereinafter Franchisor Market Power]. In response to franchisee protests of unfair exploitation, the Iowa Legislature in 1992 passed a statute that would provide franchisees specified territorial protection. Franchisors successfully challenged certain applications of that law as violating the retroactivity provisions of the federal and state constitutions. McDonald's Corp. v. Nelson, 822 F. Supp. 597 (S.D. Iowa 1993), aff'd sub nom. Holiday Inns Franchising, Inc. v. Branstad, 29 F.3d 383 (8th Cir. 1994). The territorial protections were modified in 1995 amendments, but remain in effect. The 1992 statute and the 1995 amendments are described in Dennis E. Wieczorek, The Iowa Franchise Law: 1995 Amendments and Some Proposals for 1996, 15 FRANCHISE L.J. 43 (1995).
    • (1996) Antitrust L.J. , vol.65 , pp. 105
    • Grimes, W.S.1
  • 46
    • 21444446636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Iowa Franchise Law: 1995 Amendments and Some Proposals for 1996
    • See the discussion of franchisor encroachment in Warren S. Grimes, When Do Franchisors Have Market Power? Antitrust Remedies for Franchisor Opportunism, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 105, 136-41 (1996) [hereinafter Franchisor Market Power]. In response to franchisee protests of unfair exploitation, the Iowa Legislature in 1992 passed a statute that would provide franchisees specified territorial protection. Franchisors successfully challenged certain applications of that law as violating the retroactivity provisions of the federal and state constitutions. McDonald's Corp. v. Nelson, 822 F. Supp. 597 (S.D. Iowa 1993), aff'd sub nom. Holiday Inns Franchising, Inc. v. Branstad, 29 F.3d 383 (8th Cir. 1994). The territorial protections were modified in 1995 amendments, but remain in effect. The 1992 statute and the 1995 amendments are described in Dennis E. Wieczorek, The Iowa Franchise Law: 1995 Amendments and Some Proposals for 1996, 15 FRANCHISE L.J. 43 (1995).
    • (1995) Franchise L.J. , vol.15 , pp. 43
    • Wieczorek, D.E.1
  • 47
    • 18944405608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332, 344 (1982)
    • Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332, 344 (1982).
  • 48
    • 18944402893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 372 U.S. 253 (1963)
    • 372 U.S. 253 (1963).
  • 49
    • 18944394878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Indeed, apparentiy concerned that it could not prevail under a rule of reason, the defendant in White Motor negotiated a setdement with the Department of Justice after the Supreme Court's decision.
  • 50
    • 18944400930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 285. On remand, Mr. Khan apparently was discouraged by the Supreme Court's opinion and did not pursue his vertical maximum price-fixing claim, instead arguing that the defendant's actions constituted minimum price fixing. This argument also failed, and the court of appeals ordered the district court to dismiss. Khan v. State Oil Co., 143 F.3d 362 (7th Cir. 1998).
  • 51
    • 18944405860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 283
    • Id. at 283.
  • 52
    • 18944399961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lewiston, N.Y., Info Press
    • 1995 FRANCHISE ANNUAL H5 (Lewiston, N.Y., Info Press).
    • Franchise Annual , vol.1995
  • 53
    • 18944387387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The one apparent exception is the soft drink holders, who, although often franchisees, filed an amicus brief in support of abrogating the per se rule. But the alignment of soft drink bottlers is not an anomaly. Soft drink bottiers have been accused of imposing maximum resale prices on soft drink dealers. See Acquaire v. Canada Dry Bottling Co. of N.Y., Inc., 24 F.3d 401 (2d Cir. 1994).
  • 54
    • 18944405400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Blanton v. Mobil Oil Corp., 721 F.2d 1207 (9th Cir. 1983); Milsen Co. v. Southland Corp., 454 F.2d 363 (7th Cir. 1971)
    • E.g., Blanton v. Mobil Oil Corp., 721 F.2d 1207 (9th Cir. 1983); Milsen Co. v. Southland Corp., 454 F.2d 363 (7th Cir. 1971).
  • 55
    • 84875128652 scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Antitrust Cases
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, 94 HARV. L. REV. 937, 939 (1981).
    • (1981) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 937
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 56
    • 18944398728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In re Brand Name Prescription Drugs Antitrust Litig., 123 F.3d 599, 603 (7th Cir. 1997), cert. denied, 118 S. Ct. 1178 (1998) (market power or monopoly power is "the power to raise price above cost without losing so many sales as to make the price rise unsustainable"); Valley Liquors, Inc. v. Renfield Importers, Ltd., 678 F.2d 742, 745 (7th Cir. 1982) (market power is "the power to raise price significantly above the competitive level without losing all of one's business.")
  • 57
    • 0039195660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Aftermarkets
    • Among the critics of an inelastic demand definition are Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Aftermarkets, 17 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 143 (1996); Thomas C. Arthur, The Costly Quest for Perfect Competition: Kodak and Nonstructural Market Power, 69 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1 (1994). I discuss the power-over-price definition of market power and the criticisms of that definition in Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 112-23.
    • (1996) Managerial & Decision Econ. , vol.17 , pp. 143
    • Klein, B.1
  • 58
    • 0012101834 scopus 로고
    • The Costly Quest for Perfect Competition: Kodak and Nonstructural Market Power
    • Among the critics of an inelastic demand definition are Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Aftermarkets, 17 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 143 (1996); Thomas C. Arthur, The Costly Quest for Perfect Competition: Kodak and Nonstructural Market Power, 69 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1 (1994). I discuss the power-over-price definition of market power and the criticisms of that definition in Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 112-23.
    • (1994) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.69 , pp. 1
    • Arthur, T.C.1
  • 59
    • 18944369081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 113 n.29 (listing various theorists who accept power-over-price as a definition of market power)
    • Id. at 113 n.29 (listing various theorists who accept power-over-price as a definition of market power).
  • 60
    • 18944395109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 504 U.S. 451 (1992)
    • 504 U.S. 451 (1992).
  • 61
    • 84865913348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 2.2 et seq. (1992), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104
    • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 2.2 et seq. (1992), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104.
  • 62
    • 18944396851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 93 F.3d at 1361
    • 93 F.3d at 1361.
  • 63
    • 18944380356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1362
    • Id. at 1362.
  • 64
    • 18944363603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 65
    • 0003406637 scopus 로고
    • 93 F.3d at 1361 (citing Mandeville Island Farms v. American Crystal Sugar Co., 334 U.S. 219, rehearing denied, 334 U.S. 835 (1948)). For a comprehensive discussion of monopsony power, see ROGER BLAIR & JEFFREY HARRISON, MONOPSONY: ANTITRUST LAW & ECONOMICS (1993).
    • (1993) Monopsony: Antitrust Law & Economics
    • Blair, R.1    Harrison, J.2
  • 66
    • 84865913349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This analysis is explained in HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY: THE LAW OF COMPETITION AND ITS PRACTICE § 1.2b (1994)
    • This analysis is explained in HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY: THE LAW OF COMPETITION AND ITS PRACTICE § 1.2b (1994).
  • 67
    • 18944398980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Quoting from Matsushita, Justice O'Connor wrote in Khan that "cutting prices in order to increase business often is the very essence of competition." 118 S. Ct at 282. But cutting prices to increase business may not be what the supplier is about when it imposes a resale price ceiling. Instead, the purpose of the supplier might be increasing its share of the consumer's dollar paid for gasoline without increasing the price paid by the consumer, an action that will distort competition because it squeezes the dealer's margin below a competitive level. See infra note 81 and accompanying text
  • 68
    • 0000432057 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration and Antitrust Policy
    • In a landmark article, Spengler used economic theory to demonstrate that even if a monopolist supplier has extracted maximum profit in sales to a monopoly retailer, the retailer would still impose an additional monopoly markup. Joseph J. Spengler, Vertical Integration and Antitrust Policy, 58 J. POL. ECON. 347 (1950). Although Spengler's model can be questioned (for example, because it does not account for the vertical dimension of competition between a retailer and a supplier), his conclusions have implications for the efficiency inherent in some vertical integration and may justify a manufacturer's imposition of a maximum resale price if a price limit is a reasonable way of limiting the monopoly retailer's exploitation of market power. See discussion infra part V.D, suggesting that a supplier could rebut a presumption of illegality under certain conditions. Spengler's analysis, however, does not reach the important question of the nature of the supplier's market power over the dealer that allows imposition of the resale price restraint As explained in this section, depending on the nature of the supplier's market power, the supplier's imposition of the price restraint may be procompetitive, competitively benign, or anticompetitive.
    • (1950) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.58 , pp. 347
    • Spengler, J.J.1
  • 69
    • 18944406610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If the monopolist manufacturer attempted to raise its price to the dealer above the optimal monopoly price, the dealer would maintain its margin, setting the resale price at a level that caused a fall-off in sales of the supplier's product. Or, the dealer might simply refuse to carry the product if it felt its retail margin were unduly squeezed. There might be an exception if the product is a necessity that the dealer must carry in order to bring business into the store. In that case, the dealer might be forced to carry the product at a loss.
  • 70
    • 0031486086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Manufacturers Deal with the Price-cutting Retailer: When Are Vertical Restraints Efficient?
    • If a product is distributed through multibrand retailers, the supplier of a strong brand is less likely to feel a need for vertical restraints as a means of obtaining a dealer network because consumer demand for the brand will make dealers anxious to carry it. Robert L. Steiner, How Manufacturers Deal with the Price-cutting Retailer: When Are Vertical Restraints Efficient?, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 407, 412 (1997) (noting that "famous advertised brands are sold at very thin [retail] markups over factory price.").
    • (1997) Antitrust L.J. , vol.65 , pp. 407
    • Steiner, R.L.1
  • 71
    • 18944381250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kiefer-Stewart, 182 F.2d at 230
    • Kiefer-Stewart, 182 F.2d at 230.
  • 72
    • 18944367525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although there is no rigid definition of franchising, a typical franchise arrangement involves a substantial franchisee investment in carrying and promoting the franchisor's line. Economists sometimes describe franchising as an intermediate stage in a vertical marketing continuum in which one extreme is common ownership of suppliers and retailers (vertical integration) and the other is short-term buying and selling transactions between independent suppliers and retailers. In franchising, the franchisee may commit to carrying the franchisor's line exclusively and agree to pay a royalty to the franchisor. The franchisor retains some control over the franchisee's operations but gives the franchisee license to use the franchisor's trademark, logos, and marketing strategies. The franchisor may also provide training for franchisees. See Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 107.
  • 73
    • 84881962199 scopus 로고
    • Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts
    • Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 125
    • For a discussion of franchisee sunk costs, see Gillian Hadfield, Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts, 42 STANFORD L. REV. 927, 951-52 (1990); Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 125.
    • (1990) Stanford L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 927
    • Hadfield, G.1
  • 74
    • 21344486769 scopus 로고
    • Chicago Takes it on the Chin: Imperfect Information Could Play a Crucial Role in the Post-Kodak World
    • 504 U.S. 451 (1992). Kodak has generated a great deal of analysis and comment. For commentary supportive of Kodak, see Robert H. Lande, Chicago Takes it on the Chin: Imperfect Information Could Play a Crucial Role in the Post-Kodak World, 62 ANTITRUST L.J. 193 (1993); Warren S. Grimes, Antitrust Tie-In Analysis After Kodak: A Reply to Larson's Comment, 63 ANTITRUST L.J. 267 (1994). For commentary critical of Kodak, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Market Power in Aftermarkets: Antitrust Policy and the Kodak Case, 40 U.C.L.A. L. REV. 1447, 1452-53 (1993); Arthur, supra note 51.
    • (1993) Antitrust L.J. , vol.62 , pp. 193
    • Lande, R.H.1
  • 75
    • 18944397330 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Tie-In Analysis after Kodak: A Reply to Larson's Comment
    • 504 U.S. 451 (1992). Kodak has generated a great deal of analysis and comment. For commentary supportive of Kodak, see Robert H. Lande, Chicago Takes it on the Chin: Imperfect Information Could Play a Crucial Role in the Post-Kodak World, 62 ANTITRUST L.J. 193 (1993); Warren S. Grimes, Antitrust Tie-In Analysis After Kodak: A Reply to Larson's Comment, 63 ANTITRUST L.J. 267 (1994). For commentary critical of Kodak, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Market Power in Aftermarkets: Antitrust Policy and the Kodak Case, 40 U.C.L.A. L. REV. 1447, 1452-53 (1993); Arthur, supra note 51.
    • (1994) Antitrust L.J. , vol.63 , pp. 267
    • Grimes, W.S.1
  • 76
    • 21144476421 scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Aftermarkets: Antitrust Policy and the Kodak Case
    • Arthur, supra note 51
    • 504 U.S. 451 (1992). Kodak has generated a great deal of analysis and comment. For commentary supportive of Kodak, see Robert H. Lande, Chicago Takes it on the Chin: Imperfect Information Could Play a Crucial Role in the Post-Kodak World, 62 ANTITRUST L.J. 193 (1993); Warren S. Grimes, Antitrust Tie-In Analysis After Kodak: A Reply to Larson's Comment, 63 ANTITRUST L.J. 267 (1994). For commentary critical of Kodak, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Market Power in Aftermarkets: Antitrust Policy and the Kodak Case, 40 U.C.L.A. L. REV. 1447, 1452-53 (1993); Arthur, supra note 51.
    • (1993) U.C.L.A. L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 1447
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 77
    • 18944369565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 504 U.S. at 476
    • 504 U.S. at 476.
  • 78
    • 18944401433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 484
    • Id. at 484.
  • 79
    • 18944405607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Image Technical Servs. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997), cert. denied, 118 S. Ct. 1560 (1998)
    • Image Technical Servs. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997), cert. denied, 118 S. Ct. 1560 (1998).
  • 80
    • 18944372396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 54 F.2d 363 (7th Cir. 1971)
    • 54 F.2d 363 (7th Cir. 1971).
  • 81
    • 18944378673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 368 (emphasis added)
    • Id. at 368 (emphasis added).
  • 82
    • 18944368355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 721 F.2d 1207 (9th Cir. 1983)
    • 721 F.2d 1207 (9th Cir. 1983).
  • 83
    • 18944380589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1210-11. Other dealers testified that they were threatened with loss of their lease if they refused to buy tires or other Mobil products. Id.
    • Id. at 1210-11. Other dealers testified that they were threatened with loss of their lease if they refused to buy tires or other Mobil products. Id.
  • 84
    • 18944364094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arnott v. American Oil Co., 609 F.2d 873, 877 (8th Cir. 1979) (service station lessee gave up a station in Minneapolis and relocated in South Dakota on the franchisor's promise of a more lucrative outlet); Greene v. General Foods Corp., 517 F.2d 635, 639 (5th Cir. 1975) (food distributor moved from South Carolina to Florida at the request of General Foods to run a different distributorship)
    • Arnott v. American Oil Co., 609 F.2d 873, 877 (8th Cir. 1979) (service station lessee gave up a station in Minneapolis and relocated in South Dakota on the franchisor's promise of a more lucrative outlet); Greene v. General Foods Corp., 517 F.2d 635, 639 (5th Cir. 1975) (food distributor moved from South Carolina to Florida at the request of General Foods to run a different distributorship).
  • 85
    • 18944386728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 19 F.3d 745 (1st Cir. 1994)
    • 19 F.3d 745 (1st Cir. 1994).
  • 86
    • 18944376372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 737 F.2d 698, 706 (7th Cir. 1984). In Acquaire v. Canada Dry Bottling Co. of New York, Inc., 24 F.3d 401 (2d Cir. 1994), the court's recitation of the record reveals no sunk costs, but the soft drink dealers' vigorous challenge to the maximum resale prices is consistent with either or both of two factual settings: (1) margin-squeezing by the supplier that can be enforced because the dealer has substantial non-recoverable investments in carrying the supplier's line; (2) the supplier's unexercised product market power that was being exploited by the dealer. Unless one or both of these circumstances were present, a dealer would be unlikely to bear the substantial risks of litigation to contest the supplier's resale price limit.
  • 87
    • 18944378411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 390 U.S. at 152
    • 390 U.S. at 152.
  • 88
    • 18944373329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co. Justice Portas did draw a distinction between the non-risk bearing dealer acting as an agent in a consignment arrangement and the dealer who puchases and accepts title to the product. 388 U.S. 365, 378-79 (1967). Of course, many dealers who purchase inventory and accept title to that inventory still have no significant sunk costs invested in carrying a particular supplier's line.
  • 89
    • 18944385504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This literature is surveyed in Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 107-11
    • This literature is surveyed in Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 107-11.
  • 90
    • 18944379851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Food: Prices Tumble on Big Macs, but Fries Rise
    • Apr. 25, col. 6
    • Food: Prices Tumble on Big Macs, But Fries Rise, WALL ST. J., Apr. 25, 1997, at B1, col. 6.
    • (1997) Wall St. J.
  • 91
    • 2942672090 scopus 로고
    • Congress and the Sherman Antitrust Law: 1887-1890
    • Although frequently overlooked, a major concern that underlay passage of the Sherman Act was the corrupting effects of monopoly power, both in sense of distorting competition and of corrupting firm management, civil servants, and legislators. See generally, William L. Letwin, Congress and the Sherman Antitrust Law: 1887-1890, 23 U. CHI. L. REV. 221 (1956).
    • (1956) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.23 , pp. 221
    • Letwin, W.L.1
  • 92
    • 18944364827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some of this competition-distorting behavior might constitute a crime (such as offering or accepting a bribe). But the coverage of the criminal law will reach only egregious instances of this competition distorting behavior. Even if the criminal law reaches a particular franchisor competition-distorting abuse, the franchisee may be unable to convince a public prosecutor that this matter deserves priority among the many demands on law enforcement resources, or the higher burden of proof in a criminal proceeding may prevent successful prosecution even when the anticompetitive effects are obvious.
  • 93
    • 18944404683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although the potentially corrupting nature of supplier payments to the franchisor often goes unrecognized, it is not difficult to find examples of such payments in reported cases. See, e.g., Valley Products Co v. Landmark, 128 F.3d 398, 401 (6th Cir. 1997) (two francisor-selected soap suppliers pay "access" fees to franchisor in return for exclusive right to sell to franchisees); Milsen v. Southland Corp., 54 F.2d 363, 368 (7th Cir. 1971) (franchisor-selected dairy products supplier pays 14% rebate to franchisor-described as a franchise fee - on all sales to franchisees); Wilson v. Mobil Oil Corp., 940 F. Supp. 944, 947 (E.D. La. 1996) (franchisor-selected petroleum products supplier pays franchisor $650,000, said to be designated for advertising for franchisees but allegedly misappropriated by the franchisor, in return for exclusive supplier status). Regardless of the label placed upon it, any supplier payment to the franchisor in return for exclusive supplier status is potentially corrupting because it can force the franchisee to purchase a competitively less desirable product and divert business from suppliers offering competitively more attractive products. Even if the franchisor chooses a reputable supplier offering competitive prices, the franchisee loses much of its leverage over that supplier should the supplier raise its price or occasionally provide defective goods or services.
  • 94
    • 18944391619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 142-51. A few recent decisions suggest an unwillingness of some courts to recognize the competition-distorting injury often associated with franchisor-dictated supplier choices. Valley Prods. Co. v. Landmark, 128 F.3d 398 (6th Cir. 1997) (affirming dismissal of a franchisor-imposed tie-in despite claims that franchisees were forced to pay higher prices for a non-superior product); Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino's Pizza, Inc., 124 F.3d 430 (3d Cir.), reh'g denied, 129 F.3d 724 (3d Cir. 1997) (same), cert. denied, 118 S. Ct. 1385 (1998). But see Wilson v. Mobil Oil Corp., 910 F. Supp. 944 (E.D. La. 1996); Collins v. International Dairy Queen, Inc., 939 F. Supp. 875 (M.D. Ga. 1996).
  • 95
    • 18944368002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Traditional antitrust remedies afforded to franchisees include those based on claims of monopolization, tie-ins, exclusive dealing, and vertical maximum price fixing. Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 136-54.
  • 96
    • 9944253962 scopus 로고
    • Market Power Through Imperfect Information: The Staggering Implications of Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services and a Modest Proposal for Limiting Them
    • see also Arthur, supra note 51
    • Michael S. Jacobs, Market Power Through Imperfect Information: The Staggering Implications of Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services and a Modest Proposal for Limiting Them, 52 MD. L. REV. 336 (1993); see also Arthur, supra note 51; Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis After Kodak, 3 S. CT. ECON. REV. 43 (1994).
    • (1993) Md. L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 336
    • Jacobs, M.S.1
  • 97
    • 0040380193 scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis after Kodak
    • Michael S. Jacobs, Market Power Through Imperfect Information: The Staggering Implications of Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services and a Modest Proposal for Limiting Them, 52 MD. L. REV. 336 (1993); see also Arthur, supra note 51; Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis After Kodak, 3 S. CT. ECON. REV. 43 (1994).
    • (1994) S. Ct. Econ. Rev. , vol.3 , pp. 43
    • Klein, B.1
  • 98
    • 18944363602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 344 (1962)
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 344 (1962).
  • 99
    • 18944384048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This would appear to be the interpretation favored by writers such as Arthur, supra note 51, and Klein, supra note 87, and has been followed in some lower court decisions. See, e.g, Valley Products Co. v. Landmark, 128 F.3d 398 (6th Cir. 1997) (assessing only interbrand market power and declining to recognize a Kodak lock-in theory); Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino's Pizza, Inc., 124 F.3d 430 (3d Cir. 1997), reh'g denied, 129 F.3d 1997) (same).
  • 100
    • 0003973837 scopus 로고
    • In his discussion of the legislative history of the Sherman Act, Thorelli says there is "no doubt that the Congress felt that the ultimate beneficiary of this whole process [competition] was the consumer," but notes that a more immediate beneficiary Congress had in mind was "in all probability the small business proprietor or tradesman whose opportunities were to be safeguarded from the dangers emanating from [the trusts] HANS B. THORELLI, THE FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 226-29 (1955). Writing seven years after the Sherman Act was enacted, Justice Peckham also saw harm to the small competitor and to the public as linked: a trust could "dictate the price at which the article shall be sold, the effect being to drive out of business all the small dealers in the commodity and to render the public subject to the decision of the combination as to what price shall be paid for the article." United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Ass'n, 166 U.S. 290, 323 (1897).
    • (1955) The Federal Antitrust Policy , pp. 226-229
    • Thorelli, H.B.1
  • 101
    • 18944383008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 193 U.S. 38 (1904)
    • 193 U.S. 38 (1904).
  • 102
    • 18944407324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 359 U.S. 207 (1959)
    • 359 U.S. 207 (1959).
  • 103
    • 18944392358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 472 U.S. 585 (1985)
    • 472 U.S. 585 (1985).
  • 104
    • 21344498207 scopus 로고
    • Is the Glass Half-Empty or Half-Full?: Reflections on the Kodak Case
    • Among those making this point are George A. Hay, Is the Glass Half-Empty or Half-Full?: Reflections on the Kodak Case, 62 ANTITRUST L.J. 177, 185-88 (1993); Benjamin Klein & Lester F. Saft, The Law and Economics of Franchise Tying Contracts, 28 J.L. & ECON. 345, 367-58 (1985).
    • (1993) Antitrust L.J. , vol.62 , pp. 177
    • Hay, G.A.1
  • 105
    • 84934562569 scopus 로고
    • The Law and Economics of Franchise Tying Contracts
    • Among those making this point are George A. Hay, Is the Glass Half-Empty or Half-Full?: Reflections on the Kodak Case, 62 ANTITRUST L.J. 177, 185-88 (1993); Benjamin Klein & Lester F. Saft, The Law and Economics of Franchise Tying Contracts, 28 J.L. & ECON. 345, 367-58 (1985).
    • (1985) J.L. & Econ. , vol.28 , pp. 345
    • Klein, B.1    Saft, L.F.2
  • 106
    • 18944369564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 125-3
    • Grimes, Franchisor Market Power, supra note 40, at 125-3.
  • 107
    • 18944406095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There would be an exception if the supplier is a monopolist selling a product that a dealer must carry in order to run a successful business.
  • 108
    • 18944390181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even if the wholesaler's survival depended on its ability to cany the Seagram's line, if the wholesaler's inventory and warehouse facilities could have been sold at or near cost, the wholesaler's sunk costs might have been insubstantial.
  • 109
    • 0032371225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strategic Motives for Vertical Separation: Evidence from Retail Gasoline
    • Gasoline retailing in the United States varies widely. Some service stations are owned by oil companies, some by distributors, others by operators. Among owner-operated stations, some are franchised while others are operated independently of franchise obligations. For a discussion of the various forms of gasoline retailing in Vancouver, Canada, see Margaret Slade, Strategic Motives for Vertical Separation: Evidence from Retail Gasoline, 14 J.L., ECON. & ORG. 84 (1998).
    • (1998) J.L., Econ. & Org. , vol.14 , pp. 84
    • Slade, M.1
  • 110
    • 18944370547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 472 U.S. 585 (1985)
    • 472 U.S. 585 (1985).
  • 111
    • 18944370776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One might construe the defendant's past cooperation as pivotal in determining that the defendant must continue to cooperate in issuing joint lift tickets. Another (and perhaps more sound) interpretation is that the past cooperation merely demonstrates that such cooperative behavior was efficient and would likely be abandoned only at the cost of efficient allocation beneficial to consumers.
  • 112
    • 18944394877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 504 U.S. at 458
    • 504 U.S. at 458.
  • 113
    • 18944381746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 477 n.24
    • Id. at 477 n.24.
  • 114
    • 18944393124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino's Pizza, Inc., 124 F.3d 430, 439 (3d Cir. 1997); PSI Repair Servs., Inc. v. Honeywell Inc., 104 F.3d 811 (6th Cir. 1997); Digital Equip. Corp. v. Uniq Digital Tech., Inc., 73 F.3d 756, 762 (7th Cir. 1996)
    • Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino's Pizza, Inc., 124 F.3d 430, 439 (3d Cir. 1997); PSI Repair Servs., Inc. v. Honeywell Inc., 104 F.3d 811 (6th Cir. 1997); Digital Equip. Corp. v. Uniq Digital Tech., Inc., 73 F.3d 756, 762 (7th Cir. 1996).
  • 115
    • 18944392621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 504 U.S. at 473
    • 504 U.S. at 473.
  • 116
    • 18944386218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kodak may have sought to exploit less-knowledgeable buyers by discriminating in making its spare parts available to large users of its original equipment who did their own maintenance but denying spare parts to all other users unless they used Kodak servicing. Id. at 475-76
    • Kodak may have sought to exploit less-knowledgeable buyers by discriminating in making its spare parts available to large users of its original equipment who did their own maintenance but denying spare parts to all other users unless they used Kodak servicing. Id. at 475-76.
  • 117
    • 18944379378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 392 U.S. 134 (1968)
    • 392 U.S. 134 (1968).
  • 118
    • 18944383270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 139
    • Id. at 139.
  • 119
    • 18944387386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 12 (1984)
    • Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 12 (1984).
  • 120
    • 18944376632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 356 U.S. 1 (1958)
    • 356 U.S. 1 (1958).
  • 121
    • 18944369319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 454 (emphasis added)
    • Id. at 454 (emphasis added).
  • 122
    • 18944390180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A supplier might still advance an argument that the dealer's knowing acceptance of a clause imposing a resale price ceiling suggests procompetitive effects of the price ceiling, but the argued procompetitive effects would have to be consistent with other evidence.
  • 123
    • 18944397083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • According to Justice Douglas's separate opinion in Albrecht, the dealer in that case purchased its route for $11,000 and received: (1) a list of subscribers; (2) a used truck; and (3) a newspaper tying machine. 390 U.S. at 155. This outlay does not suggest major sunk costs.
  • 124
    • 18944378410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An example of such forward vertical integration is described in Paschall v. Kansas City Star Co., 727 F.2d 692 (8th Cir. 1984)
    • An example of such forward vertical integration is described in Paschall v. Kansas City Star Co., 727 F.2d 692 (8th Cir. 1984).
  • 125
    • 18944402170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In Khan the Supreme Court apparently assumed that forced vertical integration associated with a per se rule against vertical maximum price fixing would necessarily be undesirable. The Court said: "the ban on maximum resale price limitations declared in Albrecht in the name of 'dealer freedom" has actually prompted many suppliers to integrate forward into distribution, thus eliminating the very independent trader for whom Albrecht professed solicitude." 118 S. Ct. at 282 (quoting 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1635, at 395 (1989)). A prohibition of certain applications of vertical maximum price fixing may encourage some forward vertical integration, but such encouragement is consistent with antitrust goals when the vertical integration is an efficient choice.
  • 126
    • 18944382744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In Kiefer-Stewart the Court did not hesitate to label the defendants' conduct as involving maximum price fixing, but the opinion suggests that the prices that were fixed ended up being minimum prices as well. 340 U.S. 211 (1951).
  • 127
    • 18944392880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 390 U.S. at 153
    • 390 U.S. at 153.
  • 128
    • 0041126160 scopus 로고
    • In Defense of Discounters: The No-Frills Case for a Per Se Rule Against Vertical Price Fixing
    • 118 S. Ct. at 283. The Court cites discussion of this issue by Easterbrook, supra note 19 at 901-04, and Robert Pitofsky, In Defense of Discounters: The No-Frills Case for a Per Se Rule Against Vertical Price Fixing, 71 GEO. L.J. 1487, 1490 n.17 (1983).
    • (1983) Geo. L.J. , vol.71 , Issue.17 , pp. 1487
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 129
    • 18944367275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On remand, the plaintiff in Khan unsuccessfully argued that the price fixing constituted minimum price fixing. 143 F.3d 362 (7th Cir. 1998)
    • On remand, the plaintiff in Khan unsuccessfully argued that the price fixing constituted minimum price fixing. 143 F.3d 362 (7th Cir. 1998).
  • 130
    • 18944370287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. General Motors Corp., 384 U.S. 127 (1966) (distribution restraints imposed by General Motors at the behest of a dealers association held to involve a classic horizontal restraint of trade)
    • United States v. General Motors Corp., 384 U.S. 127 (1966) (distribution restraints imposed by General Motors at the behest of a dealers association held to involve a classic horizontal restraint of trade).
  • 131
    • 18944399960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 457 U.S. 332 (1982)
    • 457 U.S. 332 (1982).
  • 132
    • 18944362926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 485 U.S. 717 (1988)
    • 485 U.S. 717 (1988).
  • 133
    • 18944373818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court may have more to say about distinguishing between vertical and horizontal conspiracies in its resolution of NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., cert. granted, 118 S. Ct. 1298 (1998)
    • The Supreme Court may have more to say about distinguishing between vertical and horizontal conspiracies in its resolution of NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., cert. granted, 118 S. Ct. 1298 (1998).
  • 134
    • 18944403985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • California courts have interpreted langauge in the Cartwright Act, CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 16700 et seq., to impose a per se ban on maximum as well as minimum vertically imposed prices. See, e.g., Mailand v. Burckle, 20 Cal. 3d 367 (1978); R.E. Spriggs Co. v. Adolph Coors Co., 94 Cal. App. 3d 419 (1979); Kolling v. Dow Jones & Co., 137 Cal. App. 3d 709, 720-21 (1982) (affirming judgment that a maximum resale price ceiling is a per se violation of the Cartwright Act).
  • 135
    • 18944390416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In New Jersey, for example, the state antitrust law requires that state provisions be "construed in harmony with ruling judicial interpretations of comparable Federal antitrust statutes . . ." N.J. STAT. ANN. § 56: 9-18.
  • 136
    • 18944366078 scopus 로고
    • States have enacted a variety of franchise regulation legislation as well as more specific provisions governing automobile, petroleum, alcoholic beverage, and farm equipment dealers. ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, MONOGRAPH 17, FRANCHISE PROTECTION: LAWS AGAINST TERMINATION AND THE ESTABLISHMENT OF ADDITIONAL FRANCHISES 16-19 (1990). Going beyond the franchisee protections provided by these statutes, a few courts have granted relief to franchisees based upon the franchisor's implied covenant of good faith linked to the franchise contract. Vylene Enterprizes, Inc. v. Naugles, Inc., 90 F.3d 1472 (9th Cir. 1996); Scheck v. Burger King Corp., 798 F. Supp. 692 (S.D. Fla. 1992); Cherick Distrib. Inc. v. Polar Corp., 41 Mass. App. Ct. 125 (1996).
    • (1990) ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Monograph 17, Franchise Protection: Laws Against Termination and the Establishment of Additional Franchises , pp. 16-19
  • 137
    • 0003761921 scopus 로고
    • nn.162-65
    • The Roman Emperor Diocletian (284-305 A.D.) decreed price ceilings on goods and services, such as bread, beer, haircuts, and children's school tuition. Although the death penalty was decreed for violators, the effort apparently was abandoned by Diocletian's successors. For a description of Diocletian's maximum price ceilings, see R. ZIMMERMANN, THE LAW OF OBLIGATION, ROMAN FOUNDATIONS OF THE CIVILIAN TRADITION 260-61 & nn.162-65 (1990).
    • (1990) The Law of Obligation, Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition , pp. 260-261
    • Zimmermann, R.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.