-
1
-
-
33847458577
-
-
United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270, 301 (1966) (Stewart, J., dissenting)
-
United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270, 301 (1966) (Stewart, J., dissenting).
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
33847471226
-
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1225 (11th Cir. 1991); United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d 1278, 1286 (7th Cir. 1990); Hospital Corp. of Am. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 807 F.2d 1381, 1393 (7th Cir. 1986), cert, denied, 481 U.S. 1038 (1987); Federal Trade Comm'n v. Columbia Hosp. Corp., No. 93-30-C1V FTM-22D, 1993 WL 183557 (M.D. Fla., preliminary injunction issued May 21, 1993); In re American Med. Int'l, Inc., 104 F.T.C. 1, 239 (1984). But see United States v. Carillon Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 849 (W.D. Va.), aff'd, 892 F.2d 1042 (1989) (holding that the government failed to'prove that the planned merger would constitute unreasonable restraint of trade); In re Adventist Health System/West, 5 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 23,591, at 23,255 (Aug. 1, 1994) (FTC opinion holding that the evidence did not support the relevant geographic markets alleged in the Commission's complaint)
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1225 (11th Cir. 1991); United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d 1278, 1286 (7th Cir. 1990); Hospital Corp. of Am. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 807 F.2d 1381, 1393 (7th Cir. 1986), cert, denied, 481 U.S. 1038 (1987); Federal Trade Comm'n v. Columbia Hosp. Corp., No. 93-30-C1V FTM-22D, 1993 WL 183557 (M.D. Fla., preliminary injunction issued May 21, 1993); In re American Med. Int'l, Inc., 104 F.T.C. 1, 239 (1984). But see United States v. Carillon Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 849 (W.D. Va.), aff'd, 892 F.2d 1042 (1989) (holding that the government failed to'prove that the planned merger would constitute unreasonable restraint of trade); In re Adventist Health System/West, 5 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 23,591, at 23,255 (Aug. 1, 1994) (FTC opinion holding that the evidence did not support the relevant geographic markets alleged in the Commission's complaint).
-
-
-
-
5
-
-
33847488354
-
-
(Oct. 5, 1994), in 4 MILES, supra note 4, app. E46-1, at App. E46-3 (speech given as the Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice)
-
See, e.g., Anne K. Bingaman, The Importance of Antitrust in Health Care, Speech Before the University of Utah College of Law (Oct. 5, 1994), in 4 MILES, supra note 4, app. E46-1, at App. E46-3 (1996) (speech given as the Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice);
-
(1996)
The Importance of Antitrust in Health Care, Speech before the University of Utah College of Law
-
-
Bingaman, A.K.1
-
6
-
-
33847437894
-
Health Care and Antitrust Enforcement
-
(Feb. 28, 1989), in 4 MILES, supra, app. E14-1, at App. E14-1 (speech given as the Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice)
-
Charles F. Rule, Health Care and Antitrust Enforcement: The Buyer's Eye-View, Speech Before the Group Health Association of America (Feb. 28, 1989), in 4 MILES, supra, app. E14-1, at App. E14-1 (speech given as the Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice).
-
The Buyer's Eye-View, Speech before the Group Health Association of America
-
-
Rule, C.F.1
-
10
-
-
33847473951
-
-
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1303 (W.D. Mich. 1996)
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1303 (W.D. Mich. 1996);
-
-
-
-
11
-
-
33847461026
-
-
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. 1213, 1228 (W.D. Mo.), affd, 69 F.3d 260, 273 (8th Cir. 1995)
-
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. 1213, 1228 (W.D. Mo.), affd, 69 F.3d 260, 273 (8th Cir. 1995);
-
-
-
-
12
-
-
33847430185
-
-
United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995), vacated as moot, 107 F.3d 632, 634 (8th Cir. 1997)
-
United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995), vacated as moot, 107 F.3d 632, 634 (8th Cir. 1997).
-
-
-
-
13
-
-
33847479602
-
-
See. e.g., Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 268-72 (discussing precedent); Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 975-87 (same)
-
See. e.g., Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 268-72 (discussing precedent); Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 975-87 (same).
-
-
-
-
14
-
-
84866476856
-
-
15U.S.C. §18(1996)
-
15U.S.C. §18(1996).
-
-
-
-
15
-
-
33847467094
-
-
See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 315-23 (1962)
-
See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 315-23 (1962);
-
-
-
-
19
-
-
33847470489
-
-
See infra notes 20-21 and accompanying text
-
See infra notes 20-21 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
20
-
-
33847462044
-
-
See United States v. Philadelphia Nat'1 Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 356 (1963)
-
See United States v. Philadelphia Nat'1 Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 356 (1963).
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
33847433573
-
-
U See id. at 356
-
U See id. at 356.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
33847465315
-
-
See id. at 362
-
See id. at 362.
-
-
-
-
23
-
-
33847472288
-
-
See id. at 363
-
See id. at 363.
-
-
-
-
24
-
-
33847473250
-
-
See id. at 364 (stating that competition is clearly threatened when the combined share of merging banks constitutes over 30% of the market and the concentration level of the five largest banks constitutes 78% of the market)
-
See id. at 364 (stating that competition is clearly threatened when the combined share of merging banks constitutes over 30% of the market and the concentration level of the five largest banks constitutes 78% of the market).
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
33847448017
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
26
-
-
33847438847
-
-
See id. at 363 (observing that defendants must produce evidence clearly showing that the merger would not have an anticompetitive effect)
-
See id. at 363 (observing that defendants must produce evidence clearly showing that the merger would not have an anticompetitive effect).
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
33847449723
-
-
See United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 415 U.S. 486, 501 (1974). See also United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602, 603 (1974), in which the Supreme Court, without explanation, reiterated the Philadelphia National Bank presumptive rule but did not state that defendant's rebuttal evidence needed to clearly establish that the merger will not have anticompetitive effects
-
See United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 415 U.S. 486, 501 (1974). See also United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602, 603 (1974), in which the Supreme Court, without explanation, reiterated the Philadelphia National Bank presumptive rule but did not state that defendant's rebuttal evidence needed to clearly establish that the merger will not have anticompetitive effects.
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
33847424302
-
-
In United Stales v. Baker Hughes Inc., then-judge Clarence Thomas viewed the effects of General Dynamics as undermining almost completely the presumptive force of statistical evidence:Imposing a heavy burden of production on a defendant would be particularly anomalous where, as here, it is easy to establish a prima facie case. The government, after all, can carry its initial burden of production simply by presenting market concentration statistics. To allow the government virtually to rest its case at that point, leaving the defendant to prove the core of the dispute, would grossly inflate the role of statistics in actions brought under section 7. The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index cannot guarantee litigation victories. 908 F.2d 981, 992 (D.C. Cir. 1990) (citation omitted)
-
In United Stales v. Baker Hughes Inc., then-judge Clarence Thomas viewed the effects of General Dynamics as undermining almost completely the presumptive force of statistical evidence:Imposing a heavy burden of production on a defendant would be particularly anomalous where, as here, it is easy to establish a prima facie case. The government, after all, can carry its initial burden of production simply by presenting market concentration statistics. To allow the government virtually to rest its case at that point, leaving the defendant to prove the core of the dispute, would grossly inflate the role of statistics in actions brought under section 7. The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index cannot guarantee litigation victories. 908 F.2d 981, 992 (D.C. Cir. 1990) (citation omitted).
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
33847447295
-
-
Unlike other areas of antitrust law, the great majority of merger challenges are brought by government enforcement agencies: the FTC, the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice and the state attorneys general. Standing requirements and the lack of damages explain the paucity of private challenges. For a notable recent exception in which a private medical clinic challenged a hospital merger after the FTC entered into a limited consent decree with the parties, see Santa Cruz Medical Clinic v. Dominican Santa Cruz Hospital, No. C93 20613 RMW, 1994 WL 619288 (N.D. Cal. Oct. 26, 1994) (finding plaintiff did have standing to sue)
-
Unlike other areas of antitrust law, the great majority of merger challenges are brought by government enforcement agencies: the FTC, the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice and the state attorneys general. Standing requirements and the lack of damages explain the paucity of private challenges. For a notable recent exception in which a private medical clinic challenged a hospital merger after the FTC entered into a limited consent decree with the parties, see Santa Cruz Medical Clinic v. Dominican Santa Cruz Hospital, No. C93 20613 RMW, 1994 WL 619288 (N.D. Cal. Oct. 26, 1994) (finding plaintiff did have standing to sue).
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
84866473941
-
-
See Response of the United States to Defendants' Proposed Findings of Facts and Conclusions of Law at 57, United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251 (N.D. 111. 1989) (No. 88-C-20186) (stating that "a merger that reduces the number of competitors from three to two . . . with a market share of over 70 percent in a market where entry is unlikely violates Section 1")
-
See Response of the United States to Defendants' Proposed Findings of Facts and Conclusions of Law at 57, United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251 (N.D. 111. 1989) (No. 88-C-20186) (stating that "a merger that reduces the number of competitors from three to two . . . with a market share of over 70 percent in a market where entry is unlikely violates Section 1").
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
33847456361
-
-
See Hospital Corp. of Am. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 807 F.2d 1381, 1385-89 (7th Cir. 1986), aff g 106 F.T.C. 361 (1985)
-
See Hospital Corp. of Am. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 807 F.2d 1381, 1385-89 (7th Cir. 1986), aff g 106 F.T.C. 361 (1985).
-
-
-
-
32
-
-
33847468096
-
-
U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMM'N, MERGER GUIDELINES-1992, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) H 13,104, at 20,569 (Apr. 17, 1997) [hereinafter MERGER GUIDELINES]
-
U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMM'N, MERGER GUIDELINES-1992, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) H 13,104, at 20,569 (Apr. 17, 1997) [hereinafter MERGER GUIDELINES].
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
84866476873
-
-
Although the Guidelines contain the caveat that they do not attempt to assign or adjust the burden of proof or going forward with evidence, see MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 0.1 (May 5, 1992), they proceed to discuss in detail the presumptive consequences of certain levels of concentration and market share. See id. §§§ 1.5, 1.51 (Apr. 7, 1992); see also infra note 27 (discussing horizontal mergers). Moreover, despite disclaimers that the Guidelines do not affect the position that the agencies will take in court, it is widely recognized that they are intended to influence the direction of merger jurisprudence in the federal courts and that they are likely to shape future litigation strategy. See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 0.1 (May 5, 1992); see also AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 11, 1 905'h, at 752 (discussing the government's approach to merger analysis)
-
Although the Guidelines contain the caveat that they do not attempt to assign or adjust the burden of proof or going forward with evidence, see MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 0.1 (May 5, 1992), they proceed to discuss in detail the presumptive consequences of certain levels of concentration and market share. See id. §§§ 1.5, 1.51 (Apr. 7, 1992); see also infra note 27 (discussing horizontal mergers). Moreover, despite disclaimers that the Guidelines do not affect the position that the agencies will take in court, it is widely recognized that they are intended to influence the direction of merger jurisprudence in the federal courts and that they are likely to shape future litigation strategy. See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 0.1 (May 5, 1992); see also AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 11, 1 905'h, at 752 (discussing the government's approach to merger analysis).
-
-
-
-
34
-
-
84866473544
-
-
Using the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) as a measure of pre- and post-merger concentration levels, the Guidelines attach only modest consequences to high concentration levels and large increases in the HHI index. See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §1.51(c) (Apr. 7, 1992) (stating that post-merger increases that exceed 100 points in "highly concentrated markets" are presumed to create or enhance market power or facilitate its exercise; but the presumption "may be overcome by a showing that the [other, nonstatistical market] factors make it unlikely" that such effects will occur); see also id. §1.51(b) (stating that post-merger increases of more than 100 points in "moderately concentrated markets . . . potentially raise significant competitive concerns depending on [other, nonstatistical market] factors")
-
Using the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) as a measure of pre- and post-merger concentration levels, the Guidelines attach only modest consequences to high concentration levels and large increases in the HHI index. See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §1.51(c) (Apr. 7, 1992) (stating that post-merger increases that exceed 100 points in "highly concentrated markets" are presumed to create or enhance market power or facilitate its exercise; but the presumption "may be overcome by a showing that the [other, nonstatistical market] factors make it unlikely" that such effects will occur); see also id. §1.51(b) (stating that post-merger increases of more than 100 points in "moderately concentrated markets . . . potentially raise significant competitive concerns depending on [other, nonstatistical market] factors").
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
84866473547
-
-
See id. §1.51(c)
-
See id. §1.51(c).
-
-
-
-
36
-
-
84866476872
-
-
See id. § 2.1
-
See id. § 2.1.
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
84866474239
-
-
See id. § 2.211
-
See id. § 2.211.
-
-
-
-
38
-
-
84866473936
-
-
See id. § 2.22
-
See id. § 2.22.
-
-
-
-
39
-
-
84866473937
-
-
See id. §§ 3.0-.4
-
See id. §§ 3.0-.4.
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
84866473933
-
-
See id. §1.521
-
See id. §1.521.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
33847452049
-
-
See, e.g., United States v. Philadelphia National Bank which holds that a merger which produces a firm controlling an undue percentage share of the relevant market, and results in a significant increase in the concentration of firms in that market, is so inherently likely to lessen competition substantially that it must be enjoined in the absence of evidence clearly showing that the merger is not likely to have such anticompetitive effects. 374 U.S. 321, 363 (1963)
-
See, e.g., United States v. Philadelphia National Bank which holds that a merger which produces a firm controlling an undue percentage share of the relevant market, and results in a significant increase in the concentration of firms in that market, is so inherently likely to lessen competition substantially that it must be enjoined in the absence of evidence clearly showing that the merger is not likely to have such anticompetitive effects. 374 U.S. 321, 363 (1963).
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
84866471986
-
-
ANTITRUST, Spring 1997, at 5, 6 (noting that "enforcers ultimately care about [a] firm's ability to raise price after a merger")
-
See Robert H. Lande & James Langenfeld, from Surrogates to Stories: The Evolution of Federal Merger Policy,-ANTITRUST, Spring 1997, at 5, 6 (noting that "enforcers ultimately care about [a] firm's ability to raise price after a merger").
-
From Surrogates to Stories: the Evolution of Federal Merger Policy
-
-
Lande, R.H.1
Langenfeld, J.2
-
43
-
-
33847437406
-
-
ANTITRUST, Summer 1992, at 6, 6; Lande & Langenfeld, supra note 35, at 6-7
-
See Paul T. Denis, An Insider's Look at the New Horizontal Merger Guidelines, ANTITRUST, Summer 1992, at 6, 6; Lande & Langenfeld, supra note 35, at 6-7.
-
An Insider's Look at the New Horizontal Merger Guidelines
-
-
Denis, P.T.1
-
44
-
-
33847429067
-
-
AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 11, K 905'h, at 752
-
AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 11, K 905'h, at 752.
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
84866476870
-
-
See id. (stating that "neither the stability and clarity of the underlying economic theory nor the ability of courts to manage that theory has improved sufficiently to warrant a departure from [the presumptive approach]")
-
See id. (stating that "neither the stability and clarity of the underlying economic theory nor the ability of courts to manage that theory has improved sufficiently to warrant a departure from [the presumptive approach]").
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
84866476871
-
-
See Baker, supra note 39, at 21 (noting that "unilateral theories are now by far the most common in the internal analyses of the antitrust agencies")
-
See Baker, supra note 39, at 21 (noting that "[unilateral theories are now by far the most common in the internal analyses of the antitrust agencies").
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
84866473934
-
-
See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 2.0 (Apr. 7,1992)
-
See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 2.0 (Apr. 7,1992).
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
33847454566
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
51
-
-
84866473543
-
-
See United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 394-96 (1956) (noting that "commodities reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes" constitute the relevant product market); Twin City Sportservice, Inc. v. Charles O. Finley & Co. 512 F.2d 1264, 1271 (9th Cir. 1975) (discussing the high cross-elasticity of demand for similar products), cert, denied, 459 U.S. 1009(1982)
-
See United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 394-96 (1956) (noting that "commodities reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes" constitute the relevant product market); Twin City Sportservice, Inc. v. Charles O. Finley & Co. 512 F.2d 1264, 1271 (9th Cir. 1975) (discussing the high cross-elasticity of demand for similar products), cert, denied, 459 U.S. 1009(1982).
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
84866474236
-
-
MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §§ 1.11, 1.21 (Apr. 7, 1992)
-
MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §§ 1.11, 1.21 (Apr. 7, 1992).
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
84866476869
-
-
See id. §1.11
-
See id. §1.11.
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
84866473541
-
-
See id. § 1.21
-
See id. § 1.21.
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
84866473932
-
-
See 1 BARRY R. FURROW ET AL., HEALTH LAW §10-55, at 738 (1995) (stating "the concept of a market is probably best understood as an expression of the essential principals [sic] that must guide factual determinations rather than a precise analytic tool")
-
See 1 BARRY R. FURROW ET AL., HEALTH LAW §10-55, at 738 (1995) (stating "the concept of a market is probably best understood as an expression of the essential principals [sic] that must guide factual determinations rather than a precise analytic tool").
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
33847446958
-
-
A PHILLIP E. AREEDA ETAL., ANTITRUST LAW 538b, at 205 (1995) (noting that subjective testimony by customers that they would or would not defect in response to a price increase is unreliable)
-
2A PHILLIP E. AREEDA ETAL., ANTITRUST LAW 538b, at 205 (1995) (noting that subjective testimony by customers that they would or would not defect in response to a price increase is unreliable).
-
-
-
-
58
-
-
84866474237
-
-
See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §§1.11, 1.21 (Apr. 7, 1992) (identifying as relevant evidence responses to past price increases, the timing and costs of switching and proof that sellers base business decisions on the prospect of buyer substitution)
-
See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §§1.11, 1.21 (Apr. 7, 1992) (identifying as relevant evidence responses to past price increases, the timing and costs of switching and proof that sellers base business decisions on the prospect of buyer substitution).
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
33847458576
-
-
See E. THOMAS SULLIVAN & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW, POLICY AND PROCEDURE 818 (3d ed. 1994); Note, 94 YALE L.J.
-
See E. THOMAS SULLIVAN & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW, POLICY AND PROCEDURE 818 (3d ed. 1994); Gene C. Schaerr, Note, The Cellophane Fallacy and the Justice Department's Guidelines for Horizontal Mergers, 94 YALE L.J. 670, 675 (1985).
-
(1985)
The Cellophane Fallacy and the Justice Department's Guidelines for Horizontal Mergers
, vol.670
, pp. 675
-
-
Schaerr, G.C.1
-
60
-
-
33847433211
-
-
See Schaerr, supra note 51, at 676
-
See Schaerr, supra note 51, at 676.
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
84866476865
-
-
See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §1.11 (Apr. 7, 1992). This reflects a policy change from earlier versions of the Merger Guidelines which had adopted a standard based on prevailing prices apparently on the grounds that the Clayton Act was designed to prohibit only those mergers that enhanced market power. See SULLIVAN & HOVENKAMP, supra note 51, at 818; William F. Baxter, Responding to the Reaction: The Draftsman's View, 71 CAL. L. REV. 618, 620, 622 (1983)
-
See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, §1.11 (Apr. 7, 1992). This reflects a policy change from earlier versions of the Merger Guidelines which had adopted a standard based on prevailing prices apparently on the grounds that the Clayton Act was designed to prohibit only those mergers that enhanced market power. See SULLIVAN & HOVENKAMP, supra note 51, at 818; William F. Baxter, Responding to the Reaction: The Draftsman's View, 71 CAL. L. REV. 618, 620, 622 (1983).
-
-
-
-
62
-
-
84866473542
-
-
The Merger Guidelines cope with the problem by adopting a presumption that pre-merger prices are competitive. They provide that the enforcement agencies will use prevailing prices to perform the test "unless circumstances are strongly suggestive of coordinated interaction, in which case the Agency will use a price more reflective of the competitive price." MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 1.11 (Apr. 7, 1992)
-
The Merger Guidelines cope with the problem by adopting a presumption that pre-merger prices are competitive. They provide that the enforcement agencies will use prevailing prices to perform the test "unless circumstances are strongly suggestive of coordinated interaction, in which case the Agency will use a price more reflective of the competitive price." MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 1.11 (Apr. 7, 1992).
-
-
-
-
63
-
-
33847465677
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
33847456699
-
-
The statements were originally issued in 1993, see U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMM'N, STATEMENTS OF ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT POLICY IN THE HEALTH CARE AREA, reprinted In 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) U 13,151, at 20,755 (Sept. 5, 1993), and were revised and expanded in September 1994. See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMM'N, STATEMENTS OF ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT POLICY AND ANALYTICAL PRINCIPLES RELATING TO HEALTH CARE AND ANTITRUST, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 13,152, at 20,769 (Sept. 30, 1994) [hereinafter ENFORCEMENT POLICY]
-
The statements were originally issued in 1993, see U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMM'N, STATEMENTS OF ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT POLICY IN THE HEALTH CARE AREA, reprinted In 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) U 13,151, at 20,755 (Sept. 5, 1993), and were revised and expanded in September 1994. See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMM'N, STATEMENTS OF ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT POLICY AND ANALYTICAL PRINCIPLES RELATING TO HEALTH CARE AND ANTITRUST, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 13,152, at 20,769 (Sept. 30, 1994) [hereinafter ENFORCEMENT POLICY].
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
84866473931
-
-
See ENFORCEMENT POLICY, supra note 56, at 20,774 (setting forth nine statements regarding, inter alia, mergers, joint ventures, joint purchasing agreements, and multiprovider networks). The guidelines state that "[t]he Agencies will not challenge any merger between two general acute-care hospitals where one of the hospitals (1) has an average of fewer than 100 licensed beds . . . and (2) an average daily inpatient census of fewer than 40 patients . . . [unless] that hospital is less than 5 years old." Id
-
See ENFORCEMENT POLICY, supra note 56, at 20,774 (setting forth nine statements regarding, inter alia, mergers, joint ventures, joint purchasing agreements, and multiprovider networks). The guidelines state that "[t]he Agencies will not challenge any merger between two general acute-care hospitals where one of the hospitals (1) has an average of fewer than 100 licensed beds . . . and (2) an average daily inpatient census of fewer than 40 patients . . . [unless] that hospital is less than 5 years old." Id.
-
-
-
-
66
-
-
84866473652
-
-
See, e.g., MINN. STAT. ANN. §62J.2911-2921 (West 1996); N.D. CENT. CODE §23-17.5-11 (1993). 79 CORNELL L. REV (describing immunity statutes designed to facilitate cooperation among hospitals and other health care providers); Tina E. Kondo, State Enforcement Views, in ANTITRUST AND HEALTH CARE: NEW APPROACHES AND CHALLENGES 1, 1-8 (Health Law Section & Section of Antitrust Law, American Bar Ass'n Oct. 1996) (summarizing the regulatory orders of certain states which grant state approval for health care transactions)
-
See, e.g., MINN. STAT. ANN. §62J.2911-2921 (West 1996); N.D. CENT. CODE §23-17.5-11 (1993). See generally James F. Blumstein, Health Care Reform and Competing Visions of Medical Care: Antitrust and State Provider Cooperation Legislation, 79 CORNELL L. REV. 1459, 1486 (1994) (describing immunity statutes designed to facilitate cooperation among hospitals and other health care providers); Tina E. Kondo, State Enforcement Views, in ANTITRUST AND HEALTH CARE: NEW APPROACHES AND CHALLENGES 1, 1-8 (Health Law Section & Section of Antitrust Law, American Bar Ass'n Oct. 1996) (summarizing the regulatory orders of certain states which grant state approval for health care transactions).
-
(1994)
Health Care Reform and Competing Visions of Medical Care: Antitrust and State Provider Cooperation Legislation
, vol.1459
, pp. 1486
-
-
Blumstein, J.F.1
-
67
-
-
84866477811
-
-
See, e.g., Pennsylvania v. Capital Health Sys. Servs., No. ClV.A.4:CV-95-2096, 1995 WL 787534, at2 (M.D. Pa. Dec. 15, 1995) (ordering the merged entity to pass on at least 80% of the net cost savings to consumers "in the form of low-cost or no-cost health-care programs for the community or by reducing prices or limiting actual price increases for existing services") 1995 UTAH L. REV. (discussing how administrative agencies "have subtly shifted the locus of much decision-making authority in federal antitrust matters to themselves and away from the federal courts")
-
See, e.g., Pennsylvania v. Capital Health Sys. Servs., No. ClV.A.4:CV-95-2096, 1995 WL 787534, at2 (M.D. Pa. Dec. 15, 1995) (ordering the merged entity to pass on at least 80% of the net cost savings to consumers "in the form of low-cost or no-cost health-care programs for the community or by reducing prices or limiting actual price increases for existing services"). See generally Thomas L. Greaney, Regulating for Efficiency in Health Care Through the Antitrust Laws, 1995 UTAH L. REV. 465, .486-89 (discussing how administrative agencies "have subtly shifted the locus of much decision-making authority in federal antitrust matters to themselves and away from the federal courts").
-
Regulating for Efficiency in Health Care Through the Antitrust Laws
, vol.465
, pp. 486-489
-
-
Greaney, T.L.1
-
68
-
-
33847422865
-
-
See William J. Baer, Current Issues in Health Care Antitrust Enforcement at the Federal Trade Comm'n, Address Before the American Bar Association (Oct. 24, 1996), available in 1996 WL 613763 (address given as Director, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission)
-
See William J. Baer, Current Issues in Health Care Antitrust Enforcement at the Federal Trade Comm'n, Address Before the American Bar Association (Oct. 24, 1996), available in 1996 WL 613763 (address given as Director, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission).
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
33847466724
-
-
Between 1987 and 1991, the FTC and DOJ investigated only 27 out of some 229 hospital mergers; only five of those investigations resulted in challenges. See 1 ANTITRUST SECTION, AMERICAN BAR ASS'N, ANNUAL REVIEW OF 1992 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 301 (1993)
-
Between 1987 and 1991, the FTC and DOJ investigated only 27 out of some 229 hospital mergers; only five of those investigations resulted in challenges. See 1 ANTITRUST SECTION, AMERICAN BAR ASS'N, ANNUAL REVIEW OF 1992 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 301 (1993).
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
84866476866
-
-
See, e.g., United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d. 1278, 1284 (7th Cir. 1990) (reviewing a market that consisted of inpatient acute care services). In the recent cases, the parties stipulated that the relevant product market was inpatient general acute care services. See, e.g., United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 976 (N.D. Iowa 1995); In re American Med. Int'l, 104 F.T.C. 1, 192-94 (1984). But see United States v. Carilion Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 847 (W.D. Va.) (stating that a relevant product market includes "not only other inpatient hospitals but also various outpatient clinics that treat medical problems for which patients might otherwise have sought treatment in an inpatient hospital setting"), aff'd, 892 F.2d 1041, 1042 (4th Cir. 1989) (unpublished opinion)
-
See, e.g., United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d. 1278, 1284 (7th Cir. 1990) (reviewing a market that consisted of inpatient acute care services). In the recent cases, the parties stipulated that the relevant product market was inpatient general acute care services. See, e.g., United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 976 (N.D. Iowa 1995); In re American Med. Int'l, 104 F.T.C. 1, 192-94 (1984). But see United States v. Carilion Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 847 (W.D. Va.) (stating that a relevant product market includes "not only other inpatient hospitals but also various outpatient clinics that treat medical problems for which patients might otherwise have sought treatment in an inpatient hospital setting"), aff'd, 892 F.2d 1041, 1042 (4th Cir. 1989) (unpublished opinion).
-
-
-
-
72
-
-
33847486346
-
-
The point is summarized by Judge Posner: If you need a kidney transplant, or a mastectomy, or if you have a stroke or a heart attack or a gunshot wound, you will go (or be taken) to an acute-care hospital for inpatient treatment. The fact that for other services you have a choice between inpatient care at such a hospital and outpatient care elsewhere places no check on the prices of the services we have listed, for their prices are not linked to the prices of services that are not substitutes or complements. Rockford, 898 F.2d at 1284
-
The point is summarized by Judge Posner: If you need a kidney transplant, or a mastectomy, or if you have a stroke or a heart attack or a gunshot wound, you will go (or be taken) to an acute-care hospital for inpatient treatment. The fact that for other services you have a choice between inpatient care at such a hospital and outpatient care elsewhere places no check on the prices of the services we have listed, for their prices are not linked to the prices of services that are not substitutes or complements. Rockford, 898 F.2d at 1284.
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
84866476867
-
-
See 2 MILES, supra note 4, § 12:9, at 12-27 (noting that "courts and the Federal Trade Commission thus far (except Carilion) have defined the relevant product market simply as inpatient services provided by short-term general acute care hospitals"); see also infra Part III.C (discussing Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285 (W.D. Mich. 1996), which recognized that general .acute care inpatient hospital services and primary care inpatient services are both relevant product markets)
-
See 2 MILES, supra note 4, § 12:9, at 12-27 (noting that "courts and the Federal Trade Commission thus far (except Carilion) have defined the relevant product market simply as inpatient services provided by short-term general acute care hospitals"); see also infra Part III.C (discussing Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285 (W.D. Mich. 1996), which recognized that general .acute care inpatient hospital services and primary care inpatient services are both relevant product markets).
-
-
-
-
74
-
-
33847447664
-
-
See, e.g., United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1261-78 (N.D. III. 1989) (describing geographic markets). But see Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 986 (criticizing Rockford's assumptions)
-
See, e.g., United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1261-78 (N.D. III. 1989) (describing geographic markets). But see Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 986 (criticizing Rockford's assumptions).
-
-
-
-
75
-
-
33847455328
-
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d 260, 268 (8th Cir. 1995) (noting failure of the government to prove that patient flow to distant hospitals was to obtain sophisticated care or services unavailable in local facilities); Rockford, 717 F. Supp. at 1277 (discounting importance of flow of tertiary referral patients in constraining exercise of market power because many travel for services not offered by local hospitals)
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d 260, 268 (8th Cir. 1995) (noting failure of the government to prove that patient flow to distant hospitals was to obtain sophisticated care or services unavailable in local facilities); Rockford, 717 F. Supp. at 1277 (discounting importance of flow of tertiary referral patients in constraining exercise of market power because many travel for services not offered by local hospitals).
-
-
-
-
76
-
-
33847440244
-
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 976 (citing United States v. Citizens & S. Int'l Bank, 422 U.S. 86, 120-21 (1975))
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 976 (citing United States v. Citizens & S. Int'l Bank, 422 U.S. 86, 120-21 (1975)).
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
33847464381
-
-
See Rockford, 898 F. Supp. at 1278-91 (looking at factors such as concentration, barriers to entry and the nature of competition and market participants in order to determine whether practices are likely to be anticompetitive)
-
See Rockford, 898 F. Supp. at 1278-91 (looking at factors such as concentration, barriers to entry and the nature of competition and market participants in order to determine whether practices are likely to be anticompetitive).
-
-
-
-
78
-
-
33744643987
-
-
See, e.g., Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 987
-
See, e.g., Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 987.
-
-
-
-
79
-
-
33847479601
-
-
See, e.g., Rockford, 898 F.2d at 1285 (finding defendant's efficiencies evidence incomplete and questioning whether the claimed efficiencies were solely due to the merger, and requiring clear and convincing evidence showing that the benefits of the efficiencies outweighed the anticompetitive effects of the merger); Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 976 (holding that if the defendant is successful in rebutting the government's statistical evidence, the government then has the burden of presenting additional evidence that the merger will lessen competition)
-
See, e.g., Rockford, 898 F.2d at 1285 (finding defendant's efficiencies evidence incomplete and questioning whether the claimed efficiencies were solely due to the merger, and requiring clear and convincing evidence showing that the benefits of the efficiencies outweighed the anticompetitive effects of the merger); Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 976 (holding that if the defendant is successful in rebutting the government's statistical evidence, the government then has the burden of presenting additional evidence that the merger will lessen competition).
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
33847470488
-
-
10 ADMIN. L.J. AM. U. 291, (recommending procedural reforms to clarify standards and reduce uncertainty, and responding to criticisms that health care antitrust decisions are inconsistent)
-
See, e.g., Jonathan Choslovsky, Agency Review of Health Care Industry Mergers: Proper Procedure or Unnecessary Burden?, 10 ADMIN. L.J. AM. U. 291, 305-09, 319-24 (1996) (recommending procedural reforms to clarify standards and reduce uncertainty, and responding to criticisms that health care antitrust decisions are inconsistent).
-
(1996)
Agency Review of Health Care Industry Mergers: Proper Procedure or Unnecessary Burden?
, vol.305
, Issue.9
, pp. 319-324
-
-
Choslovsky, J.1
-
81
-
-
0030569765
-
-
MOD. HEALTHCARE, Feb. 5, 1996, at 33, 33 (reporting that 71% of hospitals sponsored physician-hospital organizations); Lisa Scott, Purchasing Groups Add to Their Bulk, MOD. HEALTHCARE, Sept. 23, 1996, at 54, 54 (reporting that the 10 largest group purchasing organizations accounted for 60% of all supply purchases by nonfederal hospitals in 1995); Lisa Scott, Will We Like Tomorrow's Giants?, MOD. HEALTHCARE, Aug. 5, 1996, at 79, 79-80 (citing estimates that 2.4 mergers and acquisitions occurred per day among all types of providers in the first half of 1996, one hospital merger occurred every three days in the past 2.5 years and one-fifth of all community hospitals changed ownership in 1994-1995)
-
See Mary Chris Jaklevic, Survey: PHOs a Popular Managed Care Strategy, MOD. HEALTHCARE, Feb. 5, 1996, at 33, 33 (reporting that 71% of hospitals sponsored physician-hospital organizations); Lisa Scott, Purchasing Groups Add to Their Bulk, MOD. HEALTHCARE, Sept. 23, 1996, at 54, 54 (reporting that the 10 largest group purchasing organizations accounted for 60% of all supply purchases by nonfederal hospitals in 1995); Lisa Scott, Will We Like Tomorrow's Giants?, MOD. HEALTHCARE, Aug. 5, 1996, at 79, 79-80 (citing estimates that 2.4 mergers and acquisitions occurred per day among all types of providers in the first half of 1996, one hospital merger occurred every three days in the past 2.5 years and one-fifth of all community hospitals changed ownership in 1994-1995).
-
Survey: PHOs A Popular Managed Care Strategy
-
-
Jaklevic, M.C.1
-
85
-
-
33847481452
-
-
For example, from the patient's perspective, inpatient obstetrical services are not substitutes for chemotherapy services. Nor are they complements in the sense that offering one service makes provision of the other less costly. Whether the joint provision of the two services affords transaction cost savings in managed care contracting will depend on the costs in carving out certain services from the package that the buyer negotiates with hospitals
-
For example, from the patient's perspective, inpatient obstetrical services are not substitutes for chemotherapy services. Nor are they complements in the sense that offering one service makes provision of the other less costly. Whether the joint provision of the two services affords transaction cost savings in managed care contracting will depend on the costs in carving out certain services from the package that the buyer negotiates with hospitals.
-
-
-
-
86
-
-
0023967294
-
-
51 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 93, 126 (1988) (arguing that if there is no compelling reason to believe that demand and supply substitutability opportunities, entry conditions 'or market shares differ significantly across individual products, then the antitrust analysis will be similar for each good so they may conveniently be analyzed as a collection)
-
See Jonathan B. Baker, The Antitrust Analysis of Hospital Mergers and the Transformation of the Hospital Industry, 51 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 93, 126 (1988) (arguing that if there is no compelling reason to believe that demand and supply substitutability opportunities, entry conditions 'or market shares differ significantly across individual products, then the antitrust analysis will be similar for each good so they may conveniently be analyzed as a collection).
-
The Antitrust Analysis of Hospital Mergers and the Transformation of the Hospital Industry
-
-
Baker, J.B.1
-
87
-
-
33847484406
-
-
To depict economically meaningful markets accurately it is necessary to fine tune the cluster, which includes only services that are purchased by buyers in a package because of complementarities or transaction cost savings. See id. at 126, 128. The trend in litigation has been to narrow the cluster, with the antitrust enforcement agencies eliminating tertiary care services, see United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 981-83 (N.D. Iowa 1995), or reducing the entire package to primary care services. See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Buttenvorth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1291 (W.D. Mich. 1996)
-
To depict economically meaningful markets accurately it is necessary to fine tune the cluster, which includes only services that are purchased by buyers in a package because of complementarities or transaction cost savings. See id. at 126, 128. The trend in litigation has been to narrow the cluster, with the antitrust enforcement agencies eliminating tertiary care services, see United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 981-83 (N.D. Iowa 1995), or reducing the entire package to primary care services. See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Buttenvorth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1291 (W.D. Mich. 1996).
-
-
-
-
88
-
-
33847489776
-
-
See infra Part IV (discussing these limitations of data in the context of three specific court opinions)
-
See infra Part IV (discussing these limitations of data in the context of three specific court opinions).
-
-
-
-
89
-
-
33847433931
-
-
See, e.g., Baker, supra note 39 (reviewing the unilateral theories of the adverse competitive effects of mergers and detailing an example); Shapiro, supra note 39 (discussing various supplemental methods used by the Antitrust Division of the DOJ to analyze unilateral effects in mergers involving differentiated products)
-
See, e.g., Baker, supra note 39 (reviewing the unilateral theories of the adverse competitive effects of mergers and detailing an example); Shapiro, supra note 39 (discussing various supplemental methods used by the Antitrust Division of the DOJ to analyze unilateral effects in mergers involving differentiated products);
-
-
-
-
91
-
-
84866474234
-
-
The 1982 Merger Guidelines stated that the Department of Justice was "more likely to challenge" mergers where the products of the merging firms were "particularly good substitutes for one another." See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, MERGER GUIDELINES-1982, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) H 13,102, at 20,538 (Apr. 23, 1997). In their current iteration, the Merger Guidelines explicate in considerable detail the circumstances in which the enforcement agencies may apply unilateral effects theories to challenge a merger. See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 2.2 (Apr. 7, 1992)
-
The 1982 Merger Guidelines stated that the Department of Justice was "more likely to challenge" mergers where the products of the merging firms were "particularly good substitutes for one another." See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, MERGER GUIDELINES-1982, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) H 13,102, at 20,538 (Apr. 23, 1997). In their current iteration, the Merger Guidelines explicate in considerable detail the circumstances in which the enforcement agencies may apply unilateral effects theories to challenge a merger. See MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 2.2 (Apr. 7, 1992).
-
-
-
-
92
-
-
33847425365
-
-
A number of conditions must be met however: the likelihood of the effect depends on, for example, whether other hospitals in the market can reposition themselves and the nature of consumers' demand for hospitals' services. See Baker, supra note 39, at 21-22 (discussing necessary conditions in the context of an auction model merger hypothetical); see also Shapiro, supra note 39, at 23
-
A number of conditions must be met however: the likelihood of the effect depends on, for example, whether other hospitals in the market can reposition themselves and the nature of consumers' demand for hospitals' services. See Baker, supra note 39, at 21-22 (discussing necessary conditions in the context of an auction model merger hypothetical); see also Shapiro, supra note 39, at 23.
-
-
-
-
93
-
-
33847484771
-
-
See Lande & Langenfeld, supra note 35, at 7
-
See Lande & Langenfeld, supra note 35, at 7.
-
-
-
-
94
-
-
84866473539
-
-
See id. at 6; see also MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 2.21 (Apr. 7, 1992) (discussing unilateral effects in price resulting from mergers between firms distinguished primarily by differentiated products)
-
See id. at 6; see also MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 25, § 2.21 (Apr. 7, 1992) (discussing unilateral effects in price resulting from mergers between firms distinguished primarily by differentiated products).
-
-
-
-
96
-
-
33847476119
-
-
See id. at 131-^stating that employers contributed on average 86% of the health insurance premium for employees with single coverage and over 66% of the premium for those with family coverage
-
See id. at 131-^stating that employers contributed on average 86% of the health insurance premium for employees with single coverage and over 66% of the premium for those with family coverage).
-
-
-
-
97
-
-
33847476847
-
-
See id. at 127 (stating that 62% of all workers offered two or more plans)
-
See id. at 127 (stating that 62% of all workers offered two or more plans).
-
-
-
-
99
-
-
33847438620
-
-
See id. at 152 (reporting that only two percent of small business employers offer more than one health insurance plan to its employees)
-
See id. at 152 (reporting that only two percent of small business employers offer more than one health insurance plan to its employees).
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
33847453806
-
-
See Id. at 826-27. 92 See id. at 827
-
See Id. at 826-27. 92 See id. at 827.
-
-
-
-
102
-
-
33847463996
-
-
See id. at 837-52 (summarizing studies which suggest an inverse relationship between hospital cost and concentration, but also noting that other studies suggest that this inverse relationship might not be due to a lack of competition)
-
See id. at 837-52 (summarizing studies which suggest an inverse relationship between hospital cost and concentration, but also noting that other studies suggest that this inverse relationship might not be due to a lack of competition).
-
-
-
-
103
-
-
33847484770
-
-
See id. at 854-72 (stating that unlike other monopolies, natural monopolies are believed to benefit consumers through increased efficiencies)
-
See id. at 854-72 (stating that unlike other monopolies, natural monopolies are believed to benefit consumers through increased efficiencies).
-
-
-
-
104
-
-
33847485126
-
-
See id. at 848
-
See id. at 848.
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
33847448999
-
-
See sources cited supra note 58
-
See sources cited supra note 58.
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
33847465676
-
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d 260, 266-73 (8th Cir. 1995) (discussing the FTC's jurisdiction over nonprofit hospital mergers under the Clayton Act and the application of the appropriate standard of review to the merits of the instant case)
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d 260, 266-73 (8th Cir. 1995) (discussing the FTC's jurisdiction over nonprofit hospital mergers under the Clayton Act and the application of the appropriate standard of review to the merits of the instant case).
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
33847448998
-
-
See id. at 263
-
See id. at 263.
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
84866476863
-
-
Judge Whipple initially denied preliminary relief to the FTC without holding an evidentiary hearing. See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., No. 95-5015-CV-SW-l, 1995 WL 228319, at1 (W.D. Mo. Feb. 28, 1995). In so doing, the court mentioned in its opinion that "[i]t looks to me like Washington D.C. once again thinks they know better what's going on in southwest Missouri. I think they ought to stay in D.C." and told complaint counsel "I don't think you've got any business being in here." Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d at 263 (quoting judge at temporary restraining order hearing). After remand from the court of appeals ordering an evidentiary hearing, the court conducted a two-day trial allowing each side to present only three witnesses. The court of appeals stated that it was "disturbed" about the "injudicious" remarks made by the district court judge but rejected the 'FTC's claim that they exhibited bias against the agency. See id. at 272-73
-
Judge Whipple initially denied preliminary relief to the FTC without holding an evidentiary hearing. See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hosp., No. 95-5015-CV-SW-l, 1995 WL 228319, at1 (W.D. Mo. Feb. 28, 1995). In so doing, the court mentioned in its opinion that "[i]t looks to me like Washington D.C. once again thinks they know better what's going on in southwest Missouri. I think they ought to stay in D.C." and told complaint counsel "I don't think you've got any business being in here." Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d at 263 (quoting judge at temporary restraining order hearing). After remand from the court of appeals ordering an evidentiary hearing, the court conducted a two-day trial allowing each side to present only three witnesses. The court of appeals stated that it was "disturbed" about the "injudicious" remarks made by the district court judge but rejected the 'FTC's claim that they exhibited bias against the agency. See id. at 272-73.
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
33847460331
-
-
See Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d at 266-73
-
See Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d at 266-73.
-
-
-
-
110
-
-
33847435623
-
-
See id. at 262
-
See id. at 262.
-
-
-
-
111
-
-
33847484405
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
112
-
-
33847462749
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
113
-
-
33847485817
-
-
See Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. at 1224-25
-
See Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. at 1224-25.
-
-
-
-
114
-
-
33847480723
-
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 263 n.4
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 263 n.4.
-
-
-
-
115
-
-
33847470844
-
-
See Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. at 1226-27
-
See Freeman Hosp., 911 F. Supp. at 1226-27.
-
-
-
-
116
-
-
33847427696
-
-
id. at 1227
-
id. at 1227.
-
-
-
-
117
-
-
33847433572
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
118
-
-
33847464380
-
-
See Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d at 272
-
See Freeman Hosp., 69 F.3d at 272.
-
-
-
-
119
-
-
33847468770
-
-
See id. at 263 n.4
-
See id. at 263 n.4.
-
-
-
-
120
-
-
33847450715
-
-
See Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1222
-
See Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1222.
-
-
-
-
121
-
-
33847442935
-
-
See ;U at 1224
-
See ;U at 1224.
-
-
-
-
122
-
-
33847463648
-
-
See id. at 1225
-
See id. at 1225.
-
-
-
-
123
-
-
33847480375
-
-
See id. at 1224-25
-
See id. at 1224-25.
-
-
-
-
124
-
-
84866474235
-
-
See id. "Because reimbursement amounts for Medicare and Medicaid patients are dictated by the government, the exercise of monopoly power through higher prices has an adverse effect only on private-pay patients." Id. at 1224116 Id, at 1223.
-
See id. "Because reimbursement amounts for Medicare and Medicaid patients are dictated by the government, the exercise of monopoly power through higher prices has an adverse effect only on private-pay patients." Id. at 1224. 116 Id, at 1223.
-
-
-
-
125
-
-
33847423595
-
-
See id. at 1223-24 (discussing the opinions of third-party payors who expressed no objection to the merger)
-
See id. at 1223-24 (discussing the opinions of third-party payors who expressed no objection to the merger).
-
-
-
-
126
-
-
33847466041
-
-
See id. at 1224-25 (discussing the competitive significance of the proportion of a hospital's private paying patients, the decline in a hospital's total inpatient admissions and the degree to which a seller in a particular market can underprice its rivals)
-
See id. at 1224-25 (discussing the competitive significance of the proportion of a hospital's private paying patients, the decline in a hospital's total inpatient admissions and the degree to which a seller in a particular market can underprice its rivals).
-
-
-
-
127
-
-
84866473540
-
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 271-72 (stating that the "FTC failed to meet its burden of establishing the relevant geographical market"); Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1220 holding that "(i]nformal, off-the-cuff remarks and anecdotal evidence concerning the marketplace are no substitute for solid economic analysis")
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 271-72 (stating that the "FTC failed to meet its burden of establishing the relevant geographical market"); Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1220 (holding that "(i]nformal, off-the-cuff remarks and anecdotal evidence concerning the marketplace are no substitute for solid economic analysis").
-
-
-
-
128
-
-
33847445076
-
-
Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 269
-
Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 269.
-
-
-
-
129
-
-
33847471608
-
-
See id. at 269-72 (itemizing and discussing the insufficiencies of the FTC's expert testimony in support of the preliminary injunction); Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1226-27 (same)
-
See id. at 269-72 (itemizing and discussing the insufficiencies of the FTC's expert testimony in support of the preliminary injunction); Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1226-27 (same).
-
-
-
-
130
-
-
84866473928
-
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 272-73; Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1227-28. To obtain a preliminary injunction under section 13(b) of the Federal Trade Commission Act, the FTC must raise "questions going to the merits so serious, substantial, difficult and doubtful as to make them fair ground for thorough investigation, study, deliberation and determination by the FTC in the first instance and ultimately by the Court of Appeals." Federal Trade Comm'n v. National Tea Co., 603 F.2d 694, 698 (8th Cir. 1979) (quoting Federal Trade Comm'n v. Beatrice Foods Co., 587 F.2d 1225, 1229 (D.C. Cir. 1978)). The Eighth Circuit rejected the FTC's argument that the National Tea standard applied to its burden with respect to proving a relevant geographic market. See Freeman Hasp., 69F.3dat268n.12
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 272-73; Freeman Hasp., 911 F. Supp. at 1227-28. To obtain a preliminary injunction under section 13(b) of the Federal Trade Commission Act, the FTC must raise "questions going to the merits so serious, substantial, difficult and doubtful as to make them fair ground for thorough investigation, study, deliberation and determination by the FTC in the first instance and ultimately by the Court of Appeals." Federal Trade Comm'n v. National Tea Co., 603 F.2d 694, 698 (8th Cir. 1979) (quoting Federal Trade Comm'n v. Beatrice Foods Co., 587 F.2d 1225, 1229 (D.C. Cir. 1978)). The Eighth Circuit rejected the FTC's argument that the National Tea standard applied to its burden with respect to proving a relevant geographic market. See Freeman Hasp., 69F.3dat268n.12.
-
-
-
-
131
-
-
33847482235
-
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 265. The district court adopted the alternative analysis of patient migration patterns offered by defendants' expert, Dr. Lynk. See id. at 266. However, the Eighth Circuit accepted for purposes of appeal the FTC's patient flow proof, but found it insufficient to establish a geographic market. See id. at 269 (noting that despite Dr. Lynk's concerns that the analysis by the plaintiffs expert, Dr. Leffier, was incomplete and incorrect, his analysis failed to resolve the market definition issue)
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 265. The district court adopted the alternative analysis of patient migration patterns offered by defendants' expert, Dr. Lynk. See id. at 266. However, the Eighth Circuit accepted for purposes of appeal the FTC's patient flow proof, but found it insufficient to establish a geographic market. See id. at 269 (noting that despite Dr. Lynk's concerns that the analysis by the plaintiffs expert, Dr. Leffier, was incomplete and incorrect, his analysis failed to resolve the market definition issue).
-
-
-
-
132
-
-
84866476864
-
-
Id. at 269. 1" See id
-
Id. at 269. 1" See id.
-
-
-
-
133
-
-
84866473929
-
-
See United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1266-75 (N.D. 111. 1989), aff'd, 898 F.2d 1278 (7th Cir. 1990); see also AREEDA ET AL., supra note 49, K 534a3, at 180 (stating that "antitrust authorities often have little choice but to rely on historical data of... trading patterns. They must always recognize, however, that the inferences to be drawn are, at best, presumptions that must give way when reliable adjustments are feasible to take account of their deficiencies.")
-
See United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1266-75 (N.D. 111. 1989), aff'd, 898 F.2d 1278 (7th Cir. 1990); see also AREEDA ET AL., supra note 49, K 534a3, at 180 (stating that "antitrust authorities often have little choice but to rely on historical data of... trading patterns. They must always recognize, however, that the inferences to be drawn are, at best, presumptions that must give way when reliable adjustments are feasible to take account of their deficiencies.");
-
-
-
-
134
-
-
0025326885
-
-
J. HEALTH ECON. (concluding that the most important issue in determining the geographic scope of hospital markets is whether an attempt to exercise market power by raising prices would be thwarted by changes in patient migration). See generally Elzinga & Hogarty, supra note 44, at 45 (noting that market is commonly defined as a seller of a particular product, a buyer of a particular product or a particular place of exchange)
-
Gregory J. Werden, The Limited Relevance of Patient Migration Data in Market Delineation for Hospital Merger Ca'ses, 8 J. HEALTH ECON. 363, 376 (1989) (concluding that the most important issue in determining the geographic scope of hospital markets is whether an attempt to exercise market power by raising prices would be thwarted by changes in patient migration). See generally Elzinga & Hogarty, supra note 44, at 45 (noting that market is commonly defined as a seller of a particular product, a buyer of a particular product or a particular place of exchange).
-
(1989)
The Limited Relevance of Patient Migration Data in Market Delineation for Hospital Merger Ca'ses, 8
, vol.363
, pp. 376
-
-
Werden, G.J.1
-
135
-
-
33847479278
-
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 269
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 269.
-
-
-
-
136
-
-
33847460329
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
137
-
-
33847438282
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
33847436344
-
-
U. at 270 (emphasis added)
-
U. at 270 (emphasis added).
-
-
-
-
139
-
-
33847470124
-
-
See AREEDA ET AL., supra note 49, H 538b, at 205-06
-
See AREEDA ET AL., supra note 49, H 538b, at 205-06.
-
-
-
-
140
-
-
33847466374
-
-
See id. ffl 538-538a, at 203-05
-
See id. ffl 538-538a, at 203-05.
-
-
-
-
141
-
-
33847427695
-
-
See id. 1J538, at 203
-
See id. 1J538, at 203.
-
-
-
-
142
-
-
33847484077
-
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 269
-
See Freeman Hasp., 69 F.3d at 269.
-
-
-
-
143
-
-
33847450714
-
-
See id. at 270
-
See id. at 270.
-
-
-
-
144
-
-
33847429066
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
145
-
-
33847441613
-
-
See id. The FTC advanced this testimony to establish that differences in quality and range of services differentiate Joplin hospitals from those in the markets identified by the defendants and tend to negate the assertions of the defendants' experts that such hospitals are competitors merely because of their geographic proximity to Joplin. See id
-
See id. The FTC advanced this testimony to establish that differences in quality and range of services differentiate Joplin hospitals from those in the markets identified by the defendants and tend to negate the assertions of the defendants' experts that such hospitals are competitors merely because of their geographic proximity to Joplin. See id.
-
-
-
-
146
-
-
84866473927
-
-
See id. The court noted that "the FTC could have compiled and analyzed the DRG [diagnostic-related group] records of hospitals potentially in the geographic market to determine whether significant differences exist." Id. at 271
-
See id. The court noted that "the FTC could have compiled and analyzed the DRG [diagnostic-related group] records of hospitals potentially in the geographic market to determine whether significant differences exist." Id. at 271.
-
-
-
-
147
-
-
33847426615
-
-
902 F. Supp. 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995). While the appeal was pending, the hospitals announced that they had abandoned plans to merge. See United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 107 F.3d 632, 635 (8th Cir. 1997). Although both the government and the defendants argued that the appeal was not moot because the parties had not foresworn the possibility of merging or forming an alliance in the future, see id., the Eighth Circuit dismissed the appeal and vacated the district court's decision. See id. at 634
-
902 F. Supp. 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995). While the appeal was pending, the hospitals announced that they had abandoned plans to merge. See United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 107 F.3d 632, 635 (8th Cir. 1997). Although both the government and the defendants argued that the appeal was not moot because the parties had not foresworn the possibility of merging or forming an alliance in the future, see id., the Eighth Circuit dismissed the appeal and vacated the district court's decision. See id. at 634.
-
-
-
-
148
-
-
33847437065
-
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 987
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 987.
-
-
-
-
149
-
-
33847458068
-
-
See id. at 976
-
See id. at 976.
-
-
-
-
150
-
-
33847450390
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
151
-
-
33847448016
-
-
See id. at 980. Although several small rural hospitals competed within a closer radius, the court found those hospitals could not similarly constrain the behavior of the merged hospital. See id
-
See id. at 980. Although several small rural hospitals competed within a closer radius, the court found those hospitals could not similarly constrain the behavior of the merged hospital. See id.
-
-
-
-
152
-
-
33847464759
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
153
-
-
33847463458
-
-
In United States v. Rockford Memorial Corp., Judge Posner derisively rejected defendants' proposed market: [F]or the most part, hospital services are local. People want to be hospitalized near their families and homes, in hospitals in which their own-local-doctors have hospital privileges.... [Defendants' proposal] is ridiculous-a ten county area in which it is assumed (without any evidence and contrary to common sense) that Rockford residents, or third party payers, will be searching out small, obscure hospitals in remote rural areas if the prices charged by the hospitals in Rockford rise above competitive levels. 898 F. 2d 1278, 1285 (7th Cir. 1990)
-
In United States v. Rockford Memorial Corp., Judge Posner derisively rejected defendants' proposed market: [F]or the most part, hospital services are local. People want to be hospitalized near their families and homes, in hospitals in which their own-local-doctors have hospital privileges.... [Defendants' proposal] is ridiculous-a ten county area in which it is assumed (without any evidence and contrary to common sense) that Rockford residents, or third party payers, will be searching out small, obscure hospitals in remote rural areas if the prices charged by the hospitals in Rockford rise above competitive levels. 898 F. 2d 1278, 1285 (7th Cir. 1990).
-
-
-
-
154
-
-
33847487374
-
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 978. Proof of where patients could
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 978. Proof of where patients could practically go "requires a fluid analysis. It is not sufficient to take a snapshot of the current situation and define the relevant geographic market to be synonymous with the current service areas of the defendant hospitals." Id.
-
-
-
-
155
-
-
33847487041
-
-
See id. at 978-79
-
See id. at 978-79.
-
-
-
-
156
-
-
33847478615
-
-
See id. at 979
-
See id. at 979.
-
-
-
-
157
-
-
33847447294
-
-
979-80S.I.A.
-
See id. at 979-80.
-
-
-
-
158
-
-
33847463647
-
-
See id. at 978
-
See id. at 978.
-
-
-
-
159
-
-
33847425929
-
-
See id. at 977-83
-
See id. at 977-83.
-
-
-
-
160
-
-
33847423594
-
-
The court refused to accept the government's
-
The court refused to accept the government's proof that geographic price discrimination, such as raising prices to managed care enrollees within the city, could result from the merger. See id. at 981.
-
-
-
-
161
-
-
33847425007
-
-
See id. at 981
-
See id. at 981.
-
-
-
-
162
-
-
33847474616
-
-
The court relied on past experience in which patients traveled to regional hospitals for certain services. See id. However, the services received were for the most part not available in Dubuque or not even part of the acute care in-patient product market, such as elective plastic surgery. See Combined Reply/Response Brief of the United States at 8-9, United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 107 F.3d 632 (8th Cir. 1997) (Nos. 95-4253, 96-1051). By generalizing from experiences involving obviously dissimilar circumstances and disparate, highly differentiated service markets, the court appears to have engaged in clearly erroneous reasoning. In addition, the court seemed persuaded by evidence that financial incentives from managed care organizations had induced some patients to choose regional hospitals for specific care; for example, some witnesses suggested that payments of 200-1000 would induce
-
The court relied on past experience in which patients traveled to regional hospitals for certain services. See id. However, the services received were for the most part not available in Dubuque or not even part of the acute care in-patient product market, such as elective plastic surgery. See Combined Reply/Response Brief of the United States at 8-9, United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 107 F.3d 632 (8th Cir. 1997) (Nos. 95-4253, 96-1051). By generalizing from experiences involving obviously dissimilar circumstances and disparate, highly differentiated service markets, the court appears to have engaged in clearly erroneous reasoning. In addition, the court seemed persuaded by evidence that financial incentives from managed care organizations had induced some patients to choose regional hospitals for specific care; for example, some witnesses suggested that payments of 200-1000 would induce patients to travel distances to receive nonsurgical cancer treatment or heart care. See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 982. This evidence however does not negate the substantial evidence that individuals would not buy insurance contracts with managed care requirements that would remove all local options for care. Even if point of service plans were offered, the potential switching for certain services would pose no credible threat to a dominant local hospital on which subscribers would still depend for their local needs.
-
-
-
-
163
-
-
33847426954
-
-
See id. at 987-88
-
See id. at 987-88.
-
-
-
-
164
-
-
33847484769
-
-
For example, the court stressed evidence of travel to distant markets for services that were not a part of the product market, patient shifting with an extremely limited number of patients and evidence that certain physicians shifted patients away for nonfinancial reasons. See id. at 981
-
For example, the court stressed evidence of travel to distant markets for services that were not a part of the product market, patient shifting with an extremely limited number of patients and evidence that certain physicians shifted patients away for nonfinancial reasons. See id. at 981.
-
-
-
-
165
-
-
33847444365
-
-
See id.; United States' Brief at 12-17, Mercy Health (Nos. 95-4253, 96-1051)
-
See id.; United States' Brief at 12-17, Mercy Health (Nos. 95-4253, 96-1051).
-
-
-
-
166
-
-
33847463134
-
-
See United States' Brief at 11-12, 15, Mercy Health (Nos. 95-4253, 96-1051)
-
See United States' Brief at 11-12, 15, Mercy Health (Nos. 95-4253, 96-1051).
-
-
-
-
167
-
-
84866473536
-
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 978-80. The government also adduced evidence addressing the quantity of switching (the "critical loss ratio") necessary to defeat supracompetitive pricing after the merger. See id. at 981. According to the government's expert witness, this evidence tended to prove that an extraordinary number of individuals (46% of all managed care patients) would have to be willing to pass up local hospitals and travel 70-100 miles. See id. However, the court specifically rejected the government's contention that such a degree of switching would not occur, finding that it rested on erroneous assumptions regarding the strength of patientphysician loyalty and the willingness of persons within 25 miles of Dubuque to switch to hospitals outside Dubuque. See id.
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 978-80. The government also adduced evidence addressing the quantity of switching (the "critical loss ratio") necessary to defeat supracompetitive pricing after the merger. See id. at 981. According to the government's expert witness, this evidence tended to prove that an extraordinary number of individuals (46% of all managed care patients) would have to be willing to pass up local hospitals and travel 70-100 miles. See id. However, the court specifically rejected the government's contention that such a degree of switching would not occur, finding that it rested on erroneous assumptions regarding the strength of patientphysician loyalty and the willingness of persons within 25 miles of Dubuque to switch to hospitals outside Dubuque. See id.
-
-
-
-
168
-
-
33847450389
-
-
See Id. at 981-82
-
See Id. at 981-82.
-
-
-
-
169
-
-
84866474231
-
-
The court found the merging hospitals found little significant competition except for the regional hospitals located 60-70 miles away, see id. at 982, but made no specific findings about the pre-merger intensity of competition in the market. And indeed, defendants contended that the merging hospitals "[had] not competed vigorously in the past." See Brief of Appellees/CrossAppellants Mercy Health Services and Finley Tri-States Health Group, Inc. at 3, Mercy Health (Nos. 95-4253,96-1051)
-
The court found the merging hospitals found little significant competition except for the regional hospitals located 60-70 miles away, see id. at 982, but made no specific findings about the pre-merger intensity of competition in the market. And indeed, defendants contended that the merging hospitals "[had] not competed vigorously in the past." See Brief of Appellees/CrossAppellants Mercy Health Services and Finley Tri-States Health Group, Inc. at 3, Mercy Health (Nos. 95-4253,96-1051).
-
-
-
-
170
-
-
33847464379
-
-
See supra notes 51-53 and accompanying text
-
See supra notes 51-53 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
171
-
-
33847441953
-
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 989
-
See Mercy Health, 902 F. Supp. at 989.
-
-
-
-
172
-
-
84866473537
-
-
The defendant had claimed over 2.1 million in savings would result from "best practices," i.e., improving efficiency in utilization and avoidance of duplication of expenses. The court doubted that the merger was necessary to accomplish these goals given the ready availability of information from a myriad of sources that would accomplish similar purposes. See id. at 988
-
The defendant had claimed over 2.1 million in savings would result from "best practices," i.e., improving efficiency in utilization and avoidance of duplication of expenses. The court doubted that the merger was necessary to accomplish these goals given the ready availability of information from a myriad of sources that would accomplish similar purposes. See id. at 988.
-
-
-
-
173
-
-
33847486023
-
-
See id. at 988-89
-
See id. at 988-89.
-
-
-
-
174
-
-
33847479958
-
-
946 F. Supp. 1285 (W.D. Mich. 1996)
-
946 F. Supp. 1285 (W.D. Mich. 1996).
-
-
-
-
175
-
-
33847448375
-
-
See id. at 1302-03
-
See id. at 1302-03.
-
-
-
-
176
-
-
33847449370
-
-
See id. at 1288
-
See id. at 1288.
-
-
-
-
177
-
-
33847439547
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
178
-
-
33847437405
-
-
See Id. at 1288-89
-
See Id. at 1288-89.
-
-
-
-
179
-
-
84866473925
-
-
The Kent County Area Health Care Facilities Commission concluded that existing hospital space for inpatient services was sufficient and suggested that Blodgett consider "reorganizing its present facilities onsite, consolidating inpatient services with other area hospitals and/or moving appropriate ambulatory and support services offsite." Id. at 1289
-
The Kent County Area Health Care Facilities Commission concluded that existing hospital space for inpatient services was sufficient and suggested that Blodgett consider "reorganizing its present facilities onsite, consolidating inpatient services with other area hospitals and/or moving appropriate ambulatory and support services offsite." Id. at 1289.
-
-
-
-
180
-
-
0030593044
-
-
MOD. HEALTHCARE, Feb.
-
See David Burda & Mary Chris Jaklevic, Promises, Promises: Hospitals Are Using Price Control Pledges to Win Antitrust Clearance from States, But the Feds are Wary, MOD. HEALTHCARE, Feb. 19,1996, at 26,26.
-
(1996)
Promises, Promises: Hospitals Are Using Price Control Pledges to Win Antitrust Clearance from States, but the Feds Are Wary
, vol.19
-
-
Burda, D.1
Jaklevic, M.C.2
-
181
-
-
33847472287
-
-
See Bulterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1289-94
-
See Bulterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1289-94.
-
-
-
-
182
-
-
33847480374
-
-
See id. at 1290
-
See id. at 1290.
-
-
-
-
183
-
-
33847449722
-
-
See id. at 1291
-
See id. at 1291.
-
-
-
-
184
-
-
33847464378
-
-
See id. at 1291
-
See id. at 1291.
-
-
-
-
185
-
-
33847457387
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
186
-
-
33847475622
-
-
See id. at 1293
-
See id. at 1293.
-
-
-
-
187
-
-
33847470842
-
-
See id. at 1292-94
-
See id. at 1292-94.
-
-
-
-
188
-
-
33847485816
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
189
-
-
33847442934
-
-
See id. at 1294
-
See id. at 1294.
-
-
-
-
190
-
-
33847440242
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
191
-
-
84866474233
-
-
See id. at 1298 (finding that "the greater range of services and the perceived higher quality of care at defendant hospitals" would limit St. Mary's and Metropolitan's ability to compete with the merged entity)
-
See id. at 1298 (finding that "the greater range of services and the perceived higher quality of care at defendant hospitals" would limit St. Mary's and Metropolitan's ability to compete with the merged entity).
-
-
-
-
192
-
-
33847432466
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
193
-
-
33847435622
-
-
see Proof Brief For Plaintiff-Appellant Fed. Trade Comm'n at 7-8, Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., No. 96-2440 (6th Cir. argued June 9, 1997) (citing trial record); see also Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1309 (reprinting defendants' Exhibit A which stated that the consolidation activities and facilities plan may be adjusted to improve clinical services and patient access to the merged hospital)
-
see Proof Brief For Plaintiff-Appellant Fed. Trade Comm'n at 7-8, Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., No. 96-2440 (6th Cir. argued June 9, 1997) (citing trial record); see also Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1309 (reprinting defendants' Exhibit A which stated that the consolidation activities and facilities plan may be adjusted to improve clinical services and patient access to the merged hospital).
-
-
-
-
194
-
-
33847426614
-
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1299
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1299.
-
-
-
-
195
-
-
84866476862
-
-
Id. at 1302. The court concluded that the two small hospitals in Grand Rapids, St. Mary's and Metropolitan, would not be able to compete with the merged entity because of the greater range of services offered by Blodgett and Butterworth and that their ability to defeat a small but significant price increase by the merged entity "would be limited, especially for the foreseeable future." See id. at 1298
-
Id. at 1302. The court concluded that the two small hospitals in Grand Rapids, St. Mary's and Metropolitan, would not be able to compete with the merged entity because of the greater range of services offered by Blodgett and Butterworth and that their ability to defeat a small but significant price increase by the merged entity "would be limited, especially for the foreseeable future." See id. at 1298.
-
-
-
-
196
-
-
33847453475
-
-
Seeid. at 1302
-
Seeid. at 1302.
-
-
-
-
197
-
-
33847472621
-
-
See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 12 (1984)
-
See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 12 (1984).
-
-
-
-
198
-
-
84866473924
-
-
See supra note 59 and accompanying text; see also Butterworth, 964 F. Supp. at 1303 (ordering parties to follow consent decree incorporating "community commitment" terms)
-
See supra note 59 and accompanying text; see also Butterworth, 964 F. Supp. at 1303 (ordering parties to follow consent decree incorporating "community commitment" terms).
-
-
-
-
199
-
-
33847454927
-
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1225 (11th Cir. 1991); United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d 1278, 1286 (7th Cir. 1990)
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1225 (11th Cir. 1991); United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d 1278, 1286 (7th Cir. 1990).
-
-
-
-
200
-
-
33847434959
-
-
See United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995). Two district courts gave some weight to the nonprofit status of merging hospitals after cursory analysis, but both approved the mergers on other grounds. See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hospital, 911 F. Supp. 1213, 1226-28, affd, 69 F.3d 260, 273 (8th Cir. 1995); United States v. Carilion Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 847-49 (W.D. Va.), affd on other grounds, 892 F. 2d 1042 (4th Cir. 1989)
-
See United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 989 (N.D. Iowa 1995). Two district courts gave some weight to the nonprofit status of merging hospitals after cursory analysis, but both approved the mergers on other grounds. See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Freeman Hospital, 911 F. Supp. 1213, 1226-28, affd, 69 F.3d 260, 273 (8th Cir. 1995); United States v. Carilion Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 847-49 (W.D. Va.), affd on other grounds, 892 F. 2d 1042 (4th Cir. 1989).
-
-
-
-
201
-
-
33847430184
-
-
See In re Hospital Corp. of Am., 106 F.T.C. 361, 502 (1985), affd, 807 F.2d 1381, 1393 (7th Cir. 1988)
-
See In re Hospital Corp. of Am., 106 F.T.C. 361, 502 (1985), affd, 807 F.2d 1381, 1393 (7th Cir. 1988).
-
-
-
-
202
-
-
33847459650
-
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1297
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1297.
-
-
-
-
203
-
-
33847424301
-
-
See id. at 1296-97. The court relied on expert studies showing that high market concentration among nonprofit hospitals does not cause higher prices and, in fact, may result in lower prices. See id. (citing William J. Lynk, Nonprofit Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power, 38 J.L. & ECON. 437, 459 (1995)); see also Thomas J. Hoerger, 'Profit' Variability in For-Profit and Not-For-Proflt Hospitals, 10 J. HEALTH ECON. 259 (1991) (proposing two tests to evaluate the hypothesis that not-for-profit hospitals behave differently than for-proflt hospitals)
-
See id. at 1296-97. The court relied on expert studies showing that high market concentration among nonprofit hospitals does not cause higher prices and, in fact, may result in lower prices. See id. (citing William J. Lynk, Nonprofit Hospital Mergers and the Exercise of Market Power, 38 J.L. & ECON. 437, 459 (1995)); see also Thomas J. Hoerger, 'Profit' Variability in For-Profit and Not-For-Proflt Hospitals, 10 J. HEALTH ECON. 259 (1991) (proposing two tests to evaluate the hypothesis that not-for-profit hospitals behave differently than for-proflt hospitals).
-
-
-
-
204
-
-
33847469152
-
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1296-97
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1296-97.
-
-
-
-
205
-
-
33847474615
-
-
See Brief for Fed. Trade Comm'n at 24, Butterworth (No. 96-2440)
-
See Brief for Fed. Trade Comm'n at 24, Butterworth (No. 96-2440).
-
-
-
-
206
-
-
33847455327
-
-
The FTC strenuously asserted that Dr. Lynk's analysis is flawed because it fails to hold constant cost differences among hospitals. See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1296. Lower prices in concentrated markets may really reflect the fact that rural hospitals tend to have lower costs and compete in less highly concentrated markets. See Brief for Fed. Trade Comm'n at 32-33, Butterworth (No. 96-2440)
-
The FTC strenuously asserted that Dr. Lynk's analysis is flawed because it fails to hold constant cost differences among hospitals. See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1296. Lower prices in concentrated markets may really reflect the fact that rural hospitals tend to have lower costs and compete in less highly concentrated markets. See Brief for Fed. Trade Comm'n at 32-33, Butterworth (No. 96-2440).
-
-
-
-
207
-
-
33847471224
-
-
See United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 415 U.S. 486, 498 (1974) (holding that statistics on market share and concentration are not conclusive indicators of anticompetitive effects and that forward-looking evidence may enable the court to discount the inferences drawn from such data); see also United States v. Brown Univ., 5 F.3d 658, 678 (3d Cir. 1993) (holding that noneconomic objectives of nonprofit defendants required full-scale rule of reason analysis for competitive effects of challenged practices)
-
See United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 415 U.S. 486, 498 (1974) (holding that statistics on market share and concentration are not conclusive indicators of anticompetitive effects and that forward-looking evidence may enable the court to discount the inferences drawn from such data); see also United States v. Brown Univ., 5 F.3d 658, 678 (3d Cir. 1993) (holding that noneconomic objectives of nonprofit defendants required full-scale rule of reason analysis for competitive effects of challenged practices).
-
-
-
-
208
-
-
33847439546
-
-
while rejecting similar claims in Rockford because they were premised on theoretical guesses, Judge Posner left open the possibility of accepting such a defense where defendants could offer studies and empirical evidence to support the presumption that high concentration among nonprofit hospitals does not result in higher prices. See United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d 1278, 1286 (7th Cir. 1990)
-
while rejecting similar claims in Rockford because they were premised on theoretical guesses, Judge Posner left open the possibility of accepting such a defense where defendants could offer studies and empirical evidence to support the presumption that high concentration among nonprofit hospitals does not result in higher prices. See United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 898 F.2d 1278, 1286 (7th Cir. 1990).
-
-
-
-
209
-
-
0026875087
-
-
For example, the FTC offered a wealth of evidence from internal planning documents and other sources demonstrating that Blodgett and Butterworth recognized that increased competitive pressures were forcing them to lower prices and adopt cost-control strategies. See Brief for Fed. Trade Comm'n at 28-30, Butterworth (No. 96-2440). Moreover, several studies of markets with considerably longer experience with competitive pressures than Michigan have found that price and concentration were positively correlated. See David Dranove et al., Is Hospital Competition Wasteful?, 23 RAND J. ECON. 247, 2478 (1992)
-
For example, the FTC offered a wealth of evidence from internal planning documents and other sources demonstrating that Blodgett and Butterworth recognized that increased competitive pressures were forcing them to lower prices and adopt cost-control strategies. See Brief for Fed. Trade Comm'n at 28-30, Butterworth (No. 96-2440). Moreover, several studies of markets with considerably longer experience with competitive pressures than Michigan have found that price and concentration were positively correlated. See David Dranove et al., Is Hospital Competition Wasteful?, 23 RAND J. ECON. 247, 2478 (1992) (using a third-party study to reexamine the hypothesis that hospitals compete by providing too many high-tech hospital services, and concluding that the extent of a market, proximate population and distance to markets predict the pattern of service provision);
-
-
-
-
211
-
-
0026615183
-
-
11 J. HEALTH ECON. see also Vita et al., supra note 75, at 78 (stating that a hospital's ability to exercise market power decreases if consumers perceive other local hospitals as economic substitutes)
-
Glenn A. Melnick et al., The Effects of Market Structure and Bargaining Position on Hospital Prices, 11 J. HEALTH ECON. 217, 229 (1992) (discussing the results of a study of the Blue Cross of California PPO network which found that less competitive markets engender higher prices); see also Vita et al., supra note 75, at 78 (stating that a hospital's ability to exercise market power decreases if consumers perceive other local hospitals as economic substitutes);
-
(1992)
The Effects of Market Structure and Bargaining Position on Hospital Prices
, vol.217
, pp. 229
-
-
Melnick, G.A.1
-
212
-
-
0028333949
-
-
19 J. HEALTH POL. POL'Y & L.
-
Jack Zwanziger et al., Hospitals and Antitrust: Defining Markets, Setting Standards, 19 J. HEALTH POL. POL'Y & L. 423, 428-29 (1994) (noting that the more hospitals within an insurer-dominated market are able to offer comparable services and quality, "the more imperative it becomes that [they] be competitive in price").
-
(1994)
Hospitals and Antitrust: Defining Markets, Setting Standards
, vol.423
, pp. 428-429
-
-
Zwanziger, J.1
-
213
-
-
33847454565
-
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1297
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1297.
-
-
-
-
214
-
-
33847436718
-
-
See id. at 1296
-
See id. at 1296.
-
-
-
-
215
-
-
33847469765
-
-
The court cited approvingly Dr. Lynk's contentions that hospitals with such governance structures were analogous to consumer cooperatives and lacked incentives to raise prices to monopoly levels. See id
-
The court cited approvingly Dr. Lynk's contentions that hospitals with such governance structures were analogous to consumer cooperatives and lacked incentives to raise prices to monopoly levels. See id.
-
-
-
-
216
-
-
33847450386
-
-
See id. at 1297
-
See id. at 1297.
-
-
-
-
217
-
-
33847454926
-
-
See id. at 1296
-
See id. at 1296.
-
-
-
-
218
-
-
84866470291
-
-
24 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 5, 9 (1989) see also FURROW ET AL., supra note 48, § 5-2, at 257-61 (describing for-profit corporations); id. § 5-11, at 292-94 (outlining distinguishing characteristics of nonprofit corporations); id. § 5-12, at 295-96 (describing nonprofit corporate governance); DANIEL L. KURTZ, BOARD LIABILITY: GUIDE FOR NONPROFIT DIRECTORS 6 (1988) (describing distinctive features of nonprofit boards)
-
See Robert W. Hamilton, Reliance and Liability Standards For Outside Directors, 24 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 5, 9 (1989) (observing that "[m]odern boards of directors have practically nothing to do with the day-to-day business of the corporation"); see also FURROW ET AL., supra note 48, § 5-2, at 257-61 (describing for-profit corporations); id. § 5-11, at 292-94 (outlining distinguishing characteristics of nonprofit corporations); id. § 5-12, at 295-96 (describing nonprofit corporate governance); DANIEL L. KURTZ, BOARD LIABILITY: GUIDE FOR NONPROFIT DIRECTORS 6 (1988) (describing distinctive features of nonprofit boards).
-
Reliance and Liability Standards for Outside Directors
-
-
Hamilton, R.W.1
-
219
-
-
84866476861
-
-
See FURROW ET AL., supra note 48, §§5-14 to -17, at 297-306
-
See FURROW ET AL., supra note 48, §§5-14 to -17, at 297-306.
-
-
-
-
220
-
-
33847474614
-
-
See Buttenvorth, 946 F. Supp. at 1297
-
See Buttenvorth, 946 F. Supp. at 1297.
-
-
-
-
221
-
-
33847445578
-
-
210 See id. at 1303
-
210 See id. at 1303.
-
-
-
-
222
-
-
33847442933
-
-
See id. at 1298
-
See id. at 1298.
-
-
-
-
223
-
-
33847463457
-
-
See id. at 1299
-
See id. at 1299.
-
-
-
-
224
-
-
33847438846
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
226
-
-
33847450387
-
-
See id. WSee Pennsylvania v. Capital Health Sys. Servs., No. Civ.A.4:CV-95-2096, 1995 WL 787534, at2 (M.D. Pa. Dec. 15, 1995); Greaney, supra note 59, at 487-88 (describing highly prescriptive consent decrees in Massachusetts and Pennsylvania)
-
See id. WSee Pennsylvania v. Capital Health Sys. Servs., No. Civ.A.4:CV-95-2096, 1995 WL 787534, at2 (M.D. Pa. Dec. 15, 1995); Greaney, supra note 59, at 487-88 (describing highly prescriptive consent decrees in Massachusetts and Pennsylvania).
-
-
-
-
227
-
-
33847442221
-
-
See generally Greaney, supra note 59, at 475-82 (discussing efficiency's role in the DOJ/FTC Health Care Policy Statements, which are used to evaluate potential antitrust litigation)
-
See generally Greaney, supra note 59, at 475-82 (discussing efficiency's role in the DOJ/FTC Health Care Policy Statements, which are used to evaluate potential antitrust litigation).
-
-
-
-
228
-
-
33847485125
-
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1298-99 (W.D. Mich. 1996)
-
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1298-99 (W.D. Mich. 1996).
-
-
-
-
229
-
-
33847448642
-
-
See id. at 1298-1300
-
See id. at 1298-1300.
-
-
-
-
230
-
-
33847482564
-
-
See id. af 1299
-
See id. af 1299.
-
-
-
-
231
-
-
84866474229
-
-
There is a great deal of literature applying this analysis to criticize anti-price discrimination aspects of antitrust law, such as the Robinson-Patman Price Discrimination Act, 15 U.S.C. §§1313b, 21a (1994).
-
There is a great deal of literature applying this analysis to criticize anti-price discrimination aspects of antitrust law, such as the Robinson-Patman Price Discrimination Act, 15 U.S.C. §§1313b, 21a (1994).
-
-
-
-
233
-
-
33847441952
-
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1301
-
See Butterworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1301.
-
-
-
-
234
-
-
33847463456
-
-
See, e.g., ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 127 (1978)
-
See, e.g., ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 127 (1978);
-
-
-
-
236
-
-
33847454194
-
-
supra note 10, at 1592; Joseph Kattan, 62 ANTITRUST L.J.
-
Fisher & Lande, supra note 10, at 1592; Joseph Kattan, Efficiencies and Merger Analysis, 62 ANTITRUST L.J. 513 (1994);
-
(1994)
Efficiencies and Merger Analysis
, pp. 513
-
-
Lande, F.1
-
237
-
-
33847484404
-
-
81 GEO. L.J.
-
Robert Pitofsky, Proposals for Revised United States Merger Enforcement in a Global Economy, 81 GEO. L.J. 195 (1992). The seminal thinking in this area is found in the scholarship of Oliver E. Williamson. See, e.g., Oliver E. Williamson, Economies as an Antitrust Defense Revisited, 125 U. PA. L. REV. 699 (1977).
-
(1992)
Proposals for Revised United States Merger Enforcement in A Global Economy
, pp. 195
-
-
Pitofsky, R.1
-
238
-
-
33847476118
-
-
Most courts have rejected the defense, finding the claimed efficiencies could be achieved by means other than merger, were not adequately proved or were not significant net efficiencies once the costs of attaining those efficiencies were offset against the claimed savings. See, e.g.. Federal Trade Comm'n v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1223 (11th Cir. 1991); United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 987-89 (N.D. Iowa 1995). Courts, however, have accepted efficiencies claims. See, e.g., United States v. Carillon Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 849 (W.D. Va.), aff'd on other grounds, 892 F.2d 1042, 1042 (4th Cir. 1989)
-
Most courts have rejected the defense, finding the claimed efficiencies could be achieved by means other than merger, were not adequately proved or were not significant net efficiencies once the costs of attaining those efficiencies were offset against the claimed savings. See, e.g.. Federal Trade Comm'n v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1223 (11th Cir. 1991); United States v. Mercy Health Servs., 902 F. Supp. 968, 987-89 (N.D. Iowa 1995). Courts, however, have accepted efficiencies claims. See, e.g., United States v. Carillon Health Sys., 707 F. Supp. 840, 849 (W.D. Va.), aff'd on other grounds, 892 F.2d 1042, 1042 (4th Cir. 1989).
-
-
-
-
239
-
-
33847453114
-
-
See Butlerworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1301
-
See Butlerworth, 946 F. Supp. at 1301.
-
-
-
-
240
-
-
33847489392
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
241
-
-
84866473534
-
-
After setting forth the parties contentions regarding efficiencies, the court stated: "Because measuring the efficiencies of a proposed transaction is inherently difficult and because both sides' estimates are clearly based in some measure on speculative self-serving assertions . . . the Court finds it neither appropriate nor necessary to engage in a detailed evaluation of the competing views." Id
-
After setting forth the parties contentions regarding efficiencies, the court stated: "Because measuring the efficiencies of a proposed transaction is inherently difficult and because both sides' estimates are clearly based in some measure on speculative self-serving assertions . . . the Court finds it neither appropriate nor necessary to engage in a detailed evaluation of the competing views." Id.
-
-
-
-
242
-
-
33847457732
-
-
See id. at 1301 (describing Butterworth's successful rebuttal of the FTC's prima facie case, thus creating a presumption of legality). But cf. United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1291 (N.D. 111. 1989) (holding that the defendants failed to demonstrate clearly and convincingly that the merger would create a net economic benefit for the health care consumer). See generally AREEDA & TURNER, supra note 11, ffl 939-62, at 146-99 (addressing the legal and practical implications of courts recognizing an economics or efficiencies defense to allegations of unlawful mergers)
-
See id. at 1301 (describing Butterworth's successful rebuttal of the FTC's prima facie case, thus creating a presumption of legality). But cf. United States v. Rockford Mem'1 Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1291 (N.D. 111. 1989) (holding that the defendants failed to demonstrate clearly and convincingly that the merger would create a net economic benefit for the health care consumer). See generally AREEDA & TURNER, supra note 11, ffl 939-62, at 146-99 (addressing the legal and practical implications of courts recognizing an economics or efficiencies defense to allegations of unlawful mergers).
-
-
-
-
243
-
-
84866476858
-
-
See United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 622 (1972) (Burger, C.J., dissenting) (asserting that "courts are of limited utility in examining difficult economic problems" and Congress has not yet freed courts to "ramble through the wilds of economic theory in order to maintain a flexible approach")
-
See United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 622 (1972) (Burger, C.J., dissenting) (asserting that "courts are of limited utility in examining difficult economic problems" and Congress has not yet freed courts to "ramble through the wilds of economic theory in order to maintain a flexible approach").
-
-
-
-
244
-
-
33847438845
-
-
The district court opinions in the Mercy Health, Freeman Hospital and Butter-worth cases were all authored by Reagan or Bush appointees. See 1 ASPEN LAW & Bus., ALMANAC OF THE FEDERAL JUDICIARY, 8th Cir. Section at 15, 47, 6th Cir. Section at 37 (Megan Chase ed., 1996-2 Supp.). Two members of the Eighth Circuit panel deciding the Freeman Hospital case, including the author of the opinion, were Reagan appointees; the third member was appointed by President Clinton. See 2 ASPEN LAW & Bus., ALMANAC OF THE FEDERAL JUDICIARY, 8th Cir. Section at 4, 9, 11 (Megan Chase ed., 1997-1 Supp.). Empirical analyses of the antitrust decisions show that judges appointed by Presidents Reagan and Bush have been more conservative (i.e., permissive) on antitrust matters including horizontal mergers than those appointed by President Carter
-
The district court opinions in the Mercy Health, Freeman Hospital and Butter-worth cases were all authored by Reagan or Bush appointees. See 1 ASPEN LAW & Bus., ALMANAC OF THE FEDERAL JUDICIARY, 8th Cir. Section at 15, 47, 6th Cir. Section at 37 (Megan Chase ed., 1996-2 Supp.). Two members of the Eighth Circuit panel deciding the Freeman Hospital case, including the author of the opinion, were Reagan appointees; the third member was appointed by President Clinton. See 2 ASPEN LAW & Bus., ALMANAC OF THE FEDERAL JUDICIARY, 8th Cir. Section at 4, 9, 11 (Megan Chase ed., 1997-1 Supp.). Empirical analyses of the antitrust decisions show that judges appointed by Presidents Reagan and Bush have been more conservative (i.e., permissive) on antitrust matters including horizontal mergers than those appointed by President Carter.
-
-
-
-
245
-
-
33847429464
-
-
ANTITRUST, Spring 1993, at 8, 9; William E. Kovacic, Reagan 's Judicial Appointments and Antitrust in the Nineties, 60 FORDHAM L. REV.
-
See William E. Kovacic, Judicial Appointment and the Future of Antitrust Policy, ANTITRUST, Spring 1993, at 8, 9; William E. Kovacic, Reagan 's Judicial Appointments and Antitrust in the Nineties, 60 FORDHAM L. REV. 49, 53-67 (1991).
-
(1991)
Judicial Appointment and the Future of Antitrust Policy
, vol.49
, pp. 53-67
-
-
Kovacic, W.E.1
|