-
1
-
-
0042675050
-
-
note
-
There are a number of other reasons for this. Antitrust traditions differ across the world and common rules and principles, beyond it is said a ban on cartels, would be hard to establish. There is also an instinctive feeling among most trade specialists that free trade itself is the one basic way to ensure open and so competitive markets. Moreover many writers in the Chicago tradition in fact view antitrust laws as devices similar to external trade protection that can be used by weaker inefficient (usually small) firms to mitigate the impact of competition from successful firms. From this perspective most of the calls for international rules on competition have undertones of demands for 'fairness' which is suspect from a Chicago perspective. See in addition Shugart, WF et al. 'Antitrust enforcement and foreign competition', pp. 179-188 in McChesney F and Shugart, WF (eds) The Causes and Consequences of Anti-trust: a Public Choice Perspective University of Chicago Press (1995).
-
-
-
-
2
-
-
0042675040
-
Evolution of the ITU
-
See Codding, G 'Evolution of the ITU' Telecommunications Policy 1991 15 (4) 271-285. See also Renaud, J 'The role of the International Telecommunication Union: conflict, resolution and the industrialized countries' in Dyson, K and Humphreys, P (eds) The Political Economy of Communications Routledge, London (1990).
-
(1991)
Telecommunications Policy
, vol.15
, Issue.4
, pp. 271-285
-
-
Codding, G.1
-
3
-
-
0042675040
-
The role of the international telecommunication union: Conflict, resolution and the industrialized countries
-
Dyson, K and Humphreys, P (eds) Routledge, London
-
See Codding, G 'Evolution of the ITU' Telecommunications Policy 1991 15 (4) 271-285. See also Renaud, J 'The role of the International Telecommunication Union: conflict, resolution and the industrialized countries' in Dyson, K and Humphreys, P (eds) The Political Economy of Communications Routledge, London (1990).
-
(1990)
The Political Economy of Communications
-
-
Renaud, J.1
-
4
-
-
84976111338
-
The international telecommunications regime: The political roots of regimes for high technology
-
Cowhey, P 'The international telecommunications regime: the political roots of regimes for high technology' International Organization 1990 44 (2) 169-199.
-
(1990)
International Organization
, vol.44
, Issue.2
, pp. 169-199
-
-
Cowhey, P.1
-
7
-
-
0042173875
-
World telecommunications revenues in 1994 were $513 bn
-
May
-
World telecommunications revenues in 1994 were $513 bn, Financial Times 2 May 1996.
-
(1996)
Financial Times
, vol.2
-
-
-
8
-
-
0043176131
-
-
note
-
Commission of the European Communities, Towards a Dynamic European Economy, Green Paper on the Development of the Common Market for Telecommunications Services and Equipment, COM (87) 29, Brussels.
-
-
-
-
9
-
-
0041673221
-
-
Council Directive 95/62/EC, OJ L 321/95
-
Council Directive 95/62/EC, OJ L 321/95
-
-
-
-
11
-
-
0041673217
-
-
note
-
The Article 90(3) Directives in the telecommunications sector already implemented are: Terminals (1988), Services (1990), Satellites (1994), Cable TV Networks (1995), Mobile and Personal Communications (1996) and, most recently, Full Competition in Telecommunications Service (1996)
-
-
-
-
12
-
-
0042675049
-
Deregulation and competition: Telecommunications as a case study in liberalisation
-
Brussels, November
-
In this sense, Article 90 should be viewed as a tool used to ensure the correct implementation of European law, and, hence, similar to Articles 89 or 169, rather than as an additional means to introduce harmonizing or other legislation. Sandler, P 'Deregulation and competition: telecommunications as a case study in liberalisation', Paper presented at 1st Annual IBC Conference, Brussels, November 1994.
-
(1994)
1st Annual IBC Conference
-
-
Sandler, P.1
-
13
-
-
0030394512
-
Determining the level of regulation in EU telecommunications: A preliminary assessment
-
in press
-
Cave, M and Crowther, P 'Determining the level of regulation in EU telecommunications: a preliminary assessment, Telecommunications Policy, in press.
-
Telecommunications Policy
-
-
Cave, M.1
Crowther, P.2
-
15
-
-
0042173858
-
Baumol-Willig rules, OK? Clear v telecom (part III): Decision of the privy Council
-
In New Zealand recently (where recourse to a specific telecommunications regulator is not possible) there has been a long court case on whether the incumbent operator was abusing a dominant position by using the Baumol-Willig (Efficient Component Pricing) principle to determine the price it charged for access to interconnection facilities. This case illustrates the problems which will face competition authorities in trying to determine whether behaviour has been anticompetitive using only ex post competition law. See Tollemache, M 'Baumol-Willig rules, OK? Clear v telecom (part III): decision of the Privy Council' European Competition Law Review 1995 4 248-251.
-
(1995)
European Competition Law Review
, vol.4
, pp. 248-251
-
-
Tollemache, M.1
-
16
-
-
0030105332
-
Users' rights? the multilateral rules on access to telecommunications
-
See, for example, Tuthill, L 'Users' rights? The multilateral rules on access to telecommunications' Telecommunications Policy 20 (2) 199689-99
-
Telecommunications Policy
, vol.20
, Issue.2
, pp. 199689-199699
-
-
Tuthill, L.1
-
19
-
-
0043176132
-
-
note
-
Argentina, Australia, Barbados,* Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Ivory Coast, Cuba,* Cyprus,* Czech Republic, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt,* the European Communities and their Member States (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, The Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, UK), Hong Kong, Hungary, Iceland, India, Israel, Japan, Korea, Mauritius, Mexico, Morocco, New Zealand, Norway, Pakistan, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Singapore, Slovak Republic, Switzerland, Thailand, Tunisia,* Turkey, USA and Venezuela. (An asterisk marks those countries which did not make offers but participated in the talks.)
-
-
-
|