메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 24, Issue 4, 1996, Pages 411-432

Market failures and the distribution of wealth: A perspective from the economics of information

(1)  Hoff, Karla a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0030300572     PISSN: 00323292     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1177/0032329296024004009     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (24)

References (71)
  • 2
    • 0030300564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Efficient redistribution: New rules for markets, states, and communities
    • Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, "Efficient Redistribution: New Rules for Markets, States, and Communities," Politics and Society 24, no. 4 (1996): 313-14.
    • (1996) Politics and Society , vol.24 , Issue.4 , pp. 313-314
    • Bowles, S.1    Gintis, H.2
  • 3
    • 84963086963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial fragility and economic performance
    • I discuss theoretical and empirical work below. Recent theoretical work includes Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler, "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance," Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (1990): 87-115; Karla Hoff and Andrew Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets: Optimal Redistributive Taxation and Agency Costs," Journal of Public Economics 58 (1995): 365-90; Patrick Legros and Andrew Newman, "Wealth Effects, Distribution, and the Theory of Organization," Journal of Economic Theory (forthcoming); and Philippe Aghion and Patrick Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development," Review of Economic Studies (forthcoming). A precursor to this work is David Sappington, "Limited Liability Contracts between Principal and Agent," Journal of Economic Theory 29 (1983): 1-21, which demonstrates the importance of liability limitations in settings of imperfect information.
    • (1990) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.105 , pp. 87-115
    • Bernanke, B.1    Gertler, M.2
  • 4
    • 0001505119 scopus 로고
    • Non-leaky buckets: Optimal redistributive taxation and agency costs
    • I discuss theoretical and empirical work below. Recent theoretical work includes Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler, "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance," Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (1990): 87-115; Karla Hoff and Andrew Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets: Optimal Redistributive Taxation and Agency Costs," Journal of Public Economics 58 (1995): 365-90; Patrick Legros and Andrew Newman, "Wealth Effects, Distribution, and the Theory of Organization," Journal of Economic Theory (forthcoming); and Philippe Aghion and Patrick Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development," Review of Economic Studies (forthcoming). A precursor to this work is David Sappington, "Limited Liability Contracts between Principal and Agent," Journal of Economic Theory 29 (1983): 1-21, which demonstrates the importance of liability limitations in settings of imperfect information.
    • (1995) Journal of Public Economics , vol.58 , pp. 365-390
    • Hoff, K.1    Lyon, A.2
  • 5
    • 84963086963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wealth effects, distribution, and the theory of organization
    • forthcoming
    • I discuss theoretical and empirical work below. Recent theoretical work includes Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler, "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance," Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (1990): 87-115; Karla Hoff and Andrew Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets: Optimal Redistributive Taxation and Agency Costs," Journal of Public Economics 58 (1995): 365-90; Patrick Legros and Andrew Newman, "Wealth Effects, Distribution, and the Theory of Organization," Journal of Economic Theory (forthcoming); and Philippe Aghion and Patrick Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development," Review of Economic Studies (forthcoming). A precursor to this work is David Sappington, "Limited Liability Contracts between Principal and Agent," Journal of Economic Theory 29 (1983): 1-21, which demonstrates the importance of liability limitations in settings of imperfect information.
    • Journal of Economic Theory
    • Legros, P.1    Newman, A.2
  • 6
    • 84963086963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A theory of trickle-down growth and development
    • forthcoming
    • I discuss theoretical and empirical work below. Recent theoretical work includes Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler, "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance," Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (1990): 87-115; Karla Hoff and Andrew Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets: Optimal Redistributive Taxation and Agency Costs," Journal of Public Economics 58 (1995): 365-90; Patrick Legros and Andrew Newman, "Wealth Effects, Distribution, and the Theory of Organization," Journal of Economic Theory (forthcoming); and Philippe Aghion and Patrick Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development," Review of Economic Studies (forthcoming). A precursor to this work is David Sappington, "Limited Liability Contracts between Principal and Agent," Journal of Economic Theory 29 (1983): 1-21, which demonstrates the importance of liability limitations in settings of imperfect information.
    • Review of Economic Studies
    • Aghion, P.1    Bolton, P.2
  • 7
    • 0001797981 scopus 로고
    • Limited liability contracts between principal and agent
    • I discuss theoretical and empirical work below. Recent theoretical work includes Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler, "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance," Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (1990): 87-115; Karla Hoff and Andrew Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets: Optimal Redistributive Taxation and Agency Costs," Journal of Public Economics 58 (1995): 365-90; Patrick Legros and Andrew Newman, "Wealth Effects, Distribution, and the Theory of Organization," Journal of Economic Theory (forthcoming); and Philippe Aghion and Patrick Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development," Review of Economic Studies (forthcoming). A precursor to this work is David Sappington, "Limited Liability Contracts between Principal and Agent," Journal of Economic Theory 29 (1983): 1-21, which demonstrates the importance of liability limitations in settings of imperfect information.
    • (1983) Journal of Economic Theory , vol.29 , pp. 1-21
    • Sappington, D.1
  • 8
    • 84960609976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income distribution and macroeconomics
    • See Oded Galor and Joseph Zeira, "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," Review of Economic Studies (1993): 35-52; Abhijit Banerjee and Andrew Newman, "Occupational Choice and the Process of Development, Journal of Political Economy 101 (1993): 274-98; Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development"; Vicky Barham, Robin Boadway, Maurice Marchand, and Pierre Pestieau, "Education and the Poverty Trap," European Economic Review 39:1257-75 ; and Ronald Bénabou, "Inequality and Growth," NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1996).
    • (1993) Review of Economic Studies , pp. 35-52
    • Galor, O.1    Zeira, J.2
  • 9
    • 0027756557 scopus 로고
    • Occupational choice and the process of development
    • See Oded Galor and Joseph Zeira, "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," Review of Economic Studies (1993): 35-52; Abhijit Banerjee and Andrew Newman, "Occupational Choice and the Process of Development, Journal of Political Economy 101 (1993): 274-98; Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development"; Vicky Barham, Robin Boadway, Maurice Marchand, and Pierre Pestieau, "Education and the Poverty Trap," European Economic Review 39:1257-75 ; and Ronald Bénabou, "Inequality and Growth," NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1996).
    • (1993) Journal of Political Economy , vol.101 , pp. 274-298
    • Banerjee, A.1    Newman, A.2
  • 10
    • 84960609976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Oded Galor and Joseph Zeira, "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," Review of Economic Studies (1993): 35-52; Abhijit Banerjee and Andrew Newman, "Occupational Choice and the Process of Development, Journal of Political Economy 101 (1993): 274-98; Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development"; Vicky Barham, Robin Boadway, Maurice Marchand, and Pierre Pestieau, "Education and the Poverty Trap," European Economic Review 39:1257-75 ; and Ronald Bénabou, "Inequality and Growth," NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1996).
    • A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development
    • Aghion1    Bolton2
  • 11
    • 0029544476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Education and the poverty trap
    • See Oded Galor and Joseph Zeira, "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," Review of Economic Studies (1993): 35-52; Abhijit Banerjee and Andrew Newman, "Occupational Choice and the Process of Development, Journal of Political Economy 101 (1993): 274-98; Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development"; Vicky Barham, Robin Boadway, Maurice Marchand, and Pierre Pestieau, "Education and the Poverty Trap," European Economic Review 39:1257-75 ; and Ronald Bénabou, "Inequality and Growth," NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1996).
    • European Economic Review , vol.39 , pp. 1257-1275
    • Barham, V.1    Boadway, R.2    Marchand, M.3    Pestieau, P.4
  • 12
    • 1542605536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inequality and growth
    • See Oded Galor and Joseph Zeira, "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," Review of Economic Studies (1993): 35-52; Abhijit Banerjee and Andrew Newman, "Occupational Choice and the Process of Development, Journal of Political Economy 101 (1993): 274-98; Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development"; Vicky Barham, Robin Boadway, Maurice Marchand, and Pierre Pestieau, "Education and the Poverty Trap," European Economic Review 39:1257-75 ; and Ronald Bénabou, "Inequality and Growth," NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1996).
    • (1996) NBER Macroeconomics Annual
    • Bénabou, R.1
  • 13
    • 85033647631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • And so within this model, the statement cited above by the Joint Economic Committee of the U.S. Congress is valid.
  • 14
    • 0003336819 scopus 로고
    • Capital accumulation and economic growth
    • ed. Nicholas Kaldor (New York: Holmes and Meier Publishers)
    • Kaldor assumes that the marginal rate of savings for low-income persons is low, and on this basis builds his famous model, "Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth," in Further Essays in Economic Theory, ed. Nicholas Kaldor (New York: Holmes and Meier Publishers, 1978). His hypothesis regarding savings behavior has not been established in empirical studies: see Mark Gersovitz, "Saving and Development," in Handbook of Development Economics vol. 1, ed. Hollis Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1988), and Jeffrey Williamson, Inequality, Poverty, and History: The Kuznets Memorial Lectures, Lecture 3 (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991).
    • (1978) Further Essays in Economic Theory
    • Kaldor1
  • 15
    • 0024225984 scopus 로고
    • Saving and development
    • ed. Hollis Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan (Amsterdam: North-Holland)
    • Kaldor assumes that the marginal rate of savings for low-income persons is low, and on this basis builds his famous model, "Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth," in Further Essays in Economic Theory, ed. Nicholas Kaldor (New York: Holmes and Meier Publishers, 1978). His hypothesis regarding savings behavior has not been established in empirical studies: see Mark Gersovitz, "Saving and Development," in Handbook of Development Economics vol. 1, ed. Hollis Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1988), and Jeffrey Williamson, Inequality, Poverty, and History: The Kuznets Memorial Lectures, Lecture 3 (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991).
    • (1988) Handbook of Development Economics , vol.1
    • Gersovitz, M.1
  • 16
    • 0003856372 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell
    • Kaldor assumes that the marginal rate of savings for low-income persons is low, and on this basis builds his famous model, "Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth," in Further Essays in Economic Theory, ed. Nicholas Kaldor (New York: Holmes and Meier Publishers, 1978). His hypothesis regarding savings behavior has not been established in empirical studies: see Mark Gersovitz, "Saving and Development," in Handbook of Development Economics vol. 1, ed. Hollis Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1988), and Jeffrey Williamson, Inequality, Poverty, and History: The Kuznets Memorial Lectures, Lecture 3 (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1991).
    • (1991) Inequality, Poverty, and History: The Kuznets Memorial Lectures, Lecture , vol.3
    • Williamson, J.1
  • 17
    • 0002379704 scopus 로고
    • Limited knowledge and economic analysis
    • Two overviews of the economics of information are Kenneth Arrow, "Limited Knowledge and Economic Analysis," American Economic Review (1974): 1-10, and Joseph Stiglitz, "Information and Economic Analysis: A Perspective," Economic Journal (1985): 21-41. They are interesting to read together as the first was written when the new paradigm was just emerging, and the second reviews the achievements of the period 1975-1985.
    • (1974) American Economic Review , pp. 1-10
    • Arrow, K.1
  • 18
    • 0002265883 scopus 로고
    • Information and economic analysis: A perspective
    • Two overviews of the economics of information are Kenneth Arrow, "Limited Knowledge and Economic Analysis," American Economic Review (1974): 1-10, and Joseph Stiglitz, "Information and Economic Analysis: A Perspective," Economic Journal (1985): 21-41. They are interesting to read together as the first was written when the new paradigm was just emerging, and the second reviews the achievements of the period 1975-1985.
    • (1985) Economic Journal , pp. 21-41
    • Stiglitz, J.1
  • 19
    • 0000488805 scopus 로고
    • The economic theory of agency: The principal's problem
    • The use of the terms principal and agent in economic theory is due to Stephen Ross, "The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem," American Economic Review 63 (1973): 134-39. Helpful and accessible overviews are Kenneth Arrow, "Agency and the Market," in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 3, ed. Kenneth Arrow and Michael Intriligator (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1986) 1183-95, and David Sappington, "Incentives in Principal-Agent Relationships," Journal of Economic Perspectives (1991): 45-66.
    • (1973) American Economic Review , vol.63 , pp. 134-139
    • Ross, S.1
  • 20
    • 77956843460 scopus 로고
    • Agency and the market
    • ed. Kenneth Arrow and Michael Intriligator (Amsterdam: North-Holland)
    • The use of the terms principal and agent in economic theory is due to Stephen Ross, "The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem," American Economic Review 63 (1973): 134-39. Helpful and accessible overviews are Kenneth Arrow, "Agency and the Market," in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 3, ed. Kenneth Arrow and Michael Intriligator (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1986) 1183-95, and David Sappington, "Incentives in Principal-Agent Relationships," Journal of Economic Perspectives (1991): 45-66.
    • (1986) Handbook of Mathematical Economics , vol.3 , pp. 1183-1195
    • Arrow, K.1
  • 21
    • 0002088929 scopus 로고
    • Incentives in principal-agent relationships
    • The use of the terms principal and agent in economic theory is due to Stephen Ross, "The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem," American Economic Review 63 (1973): 134-39. Helpful and accessible overviews are Kenneth Arrow, "Agency and the Market," in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 3, ed. Kenneth Arrow and Michael Intriligator (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1986) 1183-95, and David Sappington, "Incentives in Principal-Agent Relationships," Journal of Economic Perspectives (1991): 45-66.
    • (1991) Journal of Economic Perspectives , pp. 45-66
    • Sappington, D.1
  • 23
    • 85033635946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The model presented in this section is based on Bernanke and Gertler, "Financial Fragility," and Hoff and Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets." The same result - that low-wealth individuals lose access to credit - is derived from quite different information assumptions in Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development."
    • Financial Fragility
    • Bernanke1    Gertler2
  • 24
    • 85033648520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The model presented in this section is based on Bernanke and Gertler, "Financial Fragility," and Hoff and Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets." The same result - that low-wealth individuals lose access to credit - is derived from quite different information assumptions in Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development."
    • Non-Leaky Buckets
    • Hoff1    Lyon2
  • 25
    • 0004335737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The model presented in this section is based on Bernanke and Gertler, "Financial Fragility," and Hoff and Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets." The same result - that low-wealth individuals lose access to credit - is derived from quite different information assumptions in Aghion and Bolton, "A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development."
    • A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development
    • Aghion1    Bolton2
  • 26
    • 85033648520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A proof is in Hoff and Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets," 373. For simplicity, Figure 2 assumes that pure time cost of funds is zero. This means that the opportunity cost of capital in end-of-period dollars (= 1) is the same as the initial fixed capital cost. Thus for W ≥ 1, individuals do not borrow. Since they then face no agency costs (L = 0), their expected gain from preparing a project is S - L = S, invariant with respect to their initial wealth.
    • Non-Leaky Buckets , pp. 373
    • Hoff1    Lyon2
  • 27
    • 85033641325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A proof is in Bemanke and Gertler, "Financial Fragility". Part of the proof entails showing that the optimal financial contract is a debt contract. An interpretation of conditions under which debt is the optimal contract is in Karla Hoff and Andrew Lyon, "On the Self-limiting Entry of Lemons" (University of Maryland, 1996, mimeographed).
    • Financial Fragility
    • Bemanke1    Gertler2
  • 28
    • 85033644070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • University of Maryland, mimeographed
    • A proof is in Bemanke and Gertler, "Financial Fragility". Part of the proof entails showing that the optimal financial contract is a debt contract. An interpretation of conditions under which debt is the optimal contract is in Karla Hoff and Andrew Lyon, "On the Self-limiting Entry of Lemons" (University of Maryland, 1996, mimeographed).
    • (1996) On the Self-limiting Entry of Lemons
    • Hoff, K.1    Lyon, A.2
  • 29
    • 85033648520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A proof is in Hoff and Lyon, "Non-Leaky Buckets," 381-82. The proof uses the fact that transfers, by permitting individuals to increase their stake in the project, increase the average quality of borrowers and so lower equilibrium interest rates, while subsidies lower the average quality of borrowers and so increase equilibrium interest rates. As a result, individuals' willingness to trade off grants for subsidies is less than the trade-off between grants and subsidies that government can provide out of any given budget.
    • Non-Leaky Buckets , pp. 381-382
    • Hoff1    Lyon2
  • 30
    • 85033648520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a proof, see Hoff and Lyon, "Non-leaky Buckets," 374-79. In the case that transfers are financed by taxes on labor, what is required to obtain this result is that the efficiency gains from the collateralizable transfer exceed the efficiency costs of the tax. A sufficient, but not necessary, condition is that the labor market be initially undistorted. See ibid., 385.
    • Non-leaky Buckets , pp. 374-379
    • Hoff1    Lyon2
  • 31
    • 85033658363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a proof, see Hoff and Lyon, "Non-leaky Buckets," 374-79. In the case that transfers are financed by taxes on labor, what is required to obtain this result is that the efficiency gains from the collateralizable transfer exceed the efficiency costs of the tax. A sufficient, but not necessary, condition is that the labor market be initially undistorted. See ibid., 385.
    • Non-leaky Buckets , pp. 385
  • 32
    • 0001290420 scopus 로고
    • Financial structure and aggregate economic activity: An overview
    • A survey of this work is outside the scope of this article. The reader is referred to Mark Gertler, "Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity: An Overview," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 20 (1988): 559-88. See also Mark Gertler and Simon Gilchrist, "Monetary Policy, Business Cycles, and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (1994): 309-40. These studies, like the ones cited in the text below, are based on econometric analysis of data generated by the market. Interest in testing the extent of the barriers that low-wealth individuals face in participating in credit markets and in making productive investments has also motivated the undertaking of randomized experiments. Michael Kremer is undertaking an experiment in Vietnam where grants equal to a substantial fraction of average household annual income will be awarded to a random sample of households and their behavior compared to a control group's. If limited access to credit markets is important, then farm productivity, the establishment of small businesses, self-employment, and investment in education should be greater in the households that receive the grants than in the control group. See Michael Kremer, "Testing the Relationship Between Credit Constraints, Efficiency, and Redistribution Using Randomized Trials" (Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA, 1996, mimeographed).
    • (1988) Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking , vol.20 , pp. 559-588
    • Gertler, M.1
  • 33
    • 34547433726 scopus 로고
    • Monetary policy, business cycles, and the behavior of small manufacturing firms
    • A survey of this work is outside the scope of this article. The reader is referred to Mark Gertler, "Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity: An Overview," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 20 (1988): 559-88. See also Mark Gertler and Simon Gilchrist, "Monetary Policy, Business Cycles, and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (1994): 309-40. These studies, like the ones cited in the text below, are based on econometric analysis of data generated by the market. Interest in testing the extent of the barriers that low-wealth individuals face in participating in credit markets and in making productive investments has also motivated the undertaking of randomized experiments. Michael Kremer is undertaking an experiment in Vietnam where grants equal to a substantial fraction of average household annual income will be awarded to a random sample of households and their behavior compared to a control group's. If limited access to credit markets is important, then farm productivity, the establishment of small businesses, self-employment, and investment in education should be greater in the households that receive the grants than in the control group. See Michael Kremer, "Testing the Relationship Between Credit Constraints, Efficiency, and Redistribution Using Randomized Trials" (Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA, 1996, mimeographed).
    • (1994) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.109 , pp. 309-340
    • Gertler, M.1    Gilchrist, S.2
  • 34
    • 0011597341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA, mimeographed
    • A survey of this work is outside the scope of this article. The reader is referred to Mark Gertler, "Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity: An Overview," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 20 (1988): 559-88. See also Mark Gertler and Simon Gilchrist, "Monetary Policy, Business Cycles, and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (1994): 309-40. These studies, like the ones cited in the text below, are based on econometric analysis of data generated by the market. Interest in testing the extent of the barriers that low-wealth individuals face in participating in credit markets and in making productive investments has also motivated the undertaking of randomized experiments. Michael Kremer is undertaking an experiment in Vietnam where grants equal to a substantial fraction of average household annual income will be awarded to a random sample of households and their behavior compared to a control group's. If limited access to credit markets is important, then farm productivity, the establishment of small businesses, self-employment, and investment in education should be greater in the households that receive the grants than in the control group. See Michael Kremer, "Testing the Relationship Between Credit Constraints, Efficiency, and Redistribution Using Randomized Trials" (Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA, 1996, mimeographed).
    • (1996) Testing the Relationship Between Credit Constraints, Efficiency, and Redistribution Using Randomized Trials
    • Kremer, M.1
  • 36
    • 0029729897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • House prices, the supply of collateral and the enterprise economy
    • Jane Black, David de Meza, and David Jeffreys, "House Prices, the Supply of Collateral and the Enterprise Economy," Economic Journal 106 (1996) 60-75.
    • (1996) Economic Journal , vol.106 , pp. 60-75
    • Black, J.1    De Meza, D.2    Jeffreys, D.3
  • 38
    • 0011655507 scopus 로고
    • Some skeptical observations on real business cycle theory
    • Minneapolis Federal Reserve, Fall
    • Lawrence Summers, "Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle Theory," Minneapolis Federal Reserve, Bank Quarterly Review (Fall 1986): 23-27.
    • (1986) Bank Quarterly Review , pp. 23-27
    • Summers, L.1
  • 39
    • 21144465223 scopus 로고
    • Financial market imperfections and business cycles
    • Bruce Greenwald and Joseph Stiglitz, Financial Market Imperfections and Business Cycles," Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (1993): 77-114.
    • (1993) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.108 , pp. 77-114
    • Greenwald, B.1    Stiglitz, J.2
  • 40
    • 84934564112 scopus 로고
    • Internal net worth and the investment process: An application to U.S. Agriculture
    • Glenn Hubbard and Anil Kashyap, "Internal Net Worth and the Investment Process: An Application to U.S. Agriculture," Journal of Political Economy 100 (1989): 506-34.
    • (1989) Journal of Political Economy , vol.100 , pp. 506-534
    • Hubbard, G.1    Kashyap, A.2
  • 41
    • 85033655984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • b]π′ is in effect the price (in expected value terms) paid for an additional expenditure of effort; it determines the agent's incentives to expend effort. The assumption of risk neutrality is important here because it means that labor contracts have no welfare dimension other than that of the implicit price. Allowing for risk aversion means that such contracts may also serve as insurance devices.
  • 42
    • 85033657392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For the same reason, the tenant's access to credit is limited.
  • 43
    • 84959812005 scopus 로고
    • Moral hazard, financial constraints and sharecropping in El Oulja
    • Jean-Jacques Laffont and Mohamed Salah Matoussi, "Moral Hazard, Financial Constraints and Sharecropping in El Oulja," Review of Economic Studies 62 (1995): 381-99. See also Radwan Shaban, "Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping," Journal of Political Economy 95 (1987): 893-920. Related studies have been undertaken in the U.S. service industry by comparing the performance of owner-operated outlets and outlets run by hired managers. For instance, in a study of restaurants that experienced a shift from franchisee-ownership to company-ownership, or vice versa, J. P. Shelton found that the profit margin under franchisee ownership was 9.5 percent, compared to 1.8 percent under company management. See J. P. Shelton, "Allocative Efficiency vs. 'X-Efficiency': Comment," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 1252-58. A study of agency contracts in the fast food industry is Alan Krueger, "Ownership, Agency and Wages: An Examination of Franchising in the Fast Food Industry," Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (1991): 75-101.
    • (1995) Review of Economic Studies , vol.62 , pp. 381-399
    • Laffont, J.-J.1    Matoussi, M.S.2
  • 44
    • 0023519256 scopus 로고
    • Testing between competing models of sharecropping
    • Jean-Jacques Laffont and Mohamed Salah Matoussi, "Moral Hazard, Financial Constraints and Sharecropping in El Oulja," Review of Economic Studies 62 (1995): 381-99. See also Radwan Shaban, "Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping," Journal of Political Economy 95 (1987): 893-920. Related studies have been undertaken in the U.S. service industry by comparing the performance of owner-operated outlets and outlets run by hired managers. For instance, in a study of restaurants that experienced a shift from franchisee-ownership to company-ownership, or vice versa, J. P. Shelton found that the profit margin under franchisee ownership was 9.5 percent, compared to 1.8 percent under company management. See J. P. Shelton, "Allocative Efficiency vs. 'X-Efficiency': Comment," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 1252-58. A study of agency contracts in the fast food industry is Alan Krueger, "Ownership, Agency and Wages: An Examination of Franchising in the Fast Food Industry," Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (1991): 75-101.
    • (1987) Journal of Political Economy , vol.95 , pp. 893-920
    • Shaban, R.1
  • 45
    • 84959812005 scopus 로고
    • Allocative efficiency vs. 'x-efficiency': Comment
    • Jean-Jacques Laffont and Mohamed Salah Matoussi, "Moral Hazard, Financial Constraints and Sharecropping in El Oulja," Review of Economic Studies 62 (1995): 381-99. See also Radwan Shaban, "Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping," Journal of Political Economy 95 (1987): 893-920. Related studies have been undertaken in the U.S. service industry by comparing the performance of owner-operated outlets and outlets run by hired managers. For instance, in a study of restaurants that experienced a shift from franchisee-ownership to company-ownership, or vice versa, J. P. Shelton found that the profit margin under franchisee ownership was 9.5 percent, compared to 1.8 percent under company management. See J. P. Shelton, "Allocative Efficiency vs. 'X-Efficiency': Comment," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 1252-58. A study of agency contracts in the fast food industry is Alan Krueger, "Ownership, Agency and Wages: An Examination of Franchising in the Fast Food Industry," Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (1991): 75-101.
    • (1967) American Economic Review , vol.57 , pp. 1252-1258
    • Shelton, J.P.1
  • 46
    • 84959812005 scopus 로고
    • Ownership, agency and wages: An examination of franchising in the fast food industry
    • Jean-Jacques Laffont and Mohamed Salah Matoussi, "Moral Hazard, Financial Constraints and Sharecropping in El Oulja," Review of Economic Studies 62 (1995): 381-99. See also Radwan Shaban, "Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping," Journal of Political Economy 95 (1987): 893-920. Related studies have been undertaken in the U.S. service industry by comparing the performance of owner-operated outlets and outlets run by hired managers. For instance, in a study of restaurants that experienced a shift from franchisee-ownership to company-ownership, or vice versa, J. P. Shelton found that the profit margin under franchisee ownership was 9.5 percent, compared to 1.8 percent under company management. See J. P. Shelton, "Allocative Efficiency vs. 'X-Efficiency': Comment," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 1252-58. A study of agency contracts in the fast food industry is Alan Krueger, "Ownership, Agency and Wages: An Examination of Franchising in the Fast Food Industry," Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (1991): 75-101.
    • (1991) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.106 , pp. 75-101
    • Krueger, A.1
  • 47
    • 85033655870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An alternative explanation that Laffont and Matoussi consider, and reject, is that more able tenants have earned more in the past, have greater wealth, and so are more likely to be given rental contracts. When they eliminate this effect by restricting the analysis to young tenants, they obtain similar results.
  • 48
    • 0003909060 scopus 로고
    • Contractual arrangements, employment, and wages in rural labor markets: A critical review
    • ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig (New Haven, CN: Yale University Press)
    • The idea is expressed, for example, by Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, a minister under Louis XVI, cited in Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, "Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor markets: A Critical Review," in Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia, ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig (New Haven, CN: Yale University Press, 1984), 49.
    • (1984) Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia , pp. 49
    • Binswanger, H.1    Rosenzweig, M.2
  • 51
    • 85033645164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The aggregate pattern that the authors seek to explain is as follows: Between 1968 and 1981 the annual average rate of growth of production of food grains in West Bengal was 0.43 percent, whereas that of India was 1.94 percent. However, between 1981 and 1992, the respective growth rates were 5.05 percent and 3.08 percent. Ibid., 2.
    • Empowerment and Efficiency: The Economics of Tenancy Reform , pp. 2
  • 53
    • 38149147318 scopus 로고
    • The second theorem of the second best
    • A formal statement of this result is Karla Hoff, "The Second Theorem of the Second Best," Journal of Public Economics 45 (1994): 223-42.
    • (1994) Journal of Public Economics , vol.45 , pp. 223-242
    • Hoff, K.1
  • 56
    • 85033658872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For simplicity, the model abstracts from the possibility of a continuum of effort levels.
  • 57
    • 85033645927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 22 = 1.2.
  • 58
    • 85033635385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The equilibrium concept that Legros and Newman use in their proof is that of "the core," which is a stronger notion of equilibrium than that of a perfectly competitive market. In their model, an outcome is an equilibrium if no finite subset of individuals, by trading among themselves, can on their own improve their own lot. The usual definition of competitive equilibrium is one that no single individual can deviate from and thereby improve his own lot. Thus the core embodies a notion of unrestricted competition.
  • 59
    • 85033644642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is because of the particular assumptions about technology and information made in the example. From note 36, it does not pay to expand firm size beyond three individuals. And poor individuals do not themselves have the initial wealth needed to create a firm. A general statement of the results of the model, which does not depend on this particular example, is Result 5 below.
  • 60
    • 0004345677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If agents are risk averse, a further obstacle to the transfer of ownership is that workers would not wish to concentrate their wealth in a single asset, as Bowles and Gintis emphasize in "Efficient Redistribution" (307-42).
    • Efficient Redistribution , pp. 307-342
    • Bowles1    Gintis2
  • 61
    • 0003782046 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
    • Including John Roemer, A General Theory of Exploitation and Class (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982); Pranab Bardhan, "Determinants of Supply and Demand for Labor in a Poor Agrarian Economy: An Analysis of Household Survey Data for Rural West Bengal," in Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia, ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 242-62; Samuel Bowles, "The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models," American Economic Review 75 (1985): 16-36; Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, "Contested Exchange: Political Economy and Modern Economic Theory," American Economic Review 78 (1988): 145-50; Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal, "Why Are Capitalists the Bosses," Economic Journal 99 (1989): 162-76; and Dilip Mookherjee, "Informational Rents and Property Rights in Land," in Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare, ed. John Roemer (MacMillan Press, forthcoming).
    • (1982) A General Theory of Exploitation and Class
    • Roemer, J.1
  • 62
    • 0003350292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Determinants of supply and demand for labor in a poor agrarian economy: An analysis of household survey data for Rural West Bengal
    • ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
    • Including John Roemer, A General Theory of Exploitation and Class (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982); Pranab Bardhan, "Determinants of Supply and Demand for Labor in a Poor Agrarian Economy: An Analysis of Household Survey Data for Rural West Bengal," in Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia, ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 242-62; Samuel Bowles, "The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models," American Economic Review 75 (1985): 16-36; Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, "Contested Exchange: Political Economy and Modern Economic Theory," American Economic Review 78 (1988): 145-50; Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal, "Why Are Capitalists the Bosses," Economic Journal 99 (1989): 162-76; and Dilip Mookherjee, "Informational Rents and Property Rights in Land," in Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare, ed. John Roemer (MacMillan Press, forthcoming).
    • Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia , pp. 242-262
    • Bardhan, P.1
  • 63
    • 84968384319 scopus 로고
    • The production process in a competitive economy: Walrasian, neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian models
    • Including John Roemer, A General Theory of Exploitation and Class (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982); Pranab Bardhan, "Determinants of Supply and Demand for Labor in a Poor Agrarian Economy: An Analysis of Household Survey Data for Rural West Bengal," in Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia, ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 242-62; Samuel Bowles, "The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models," American Economic Review 75 (1985): 16-36; Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, "Contested Exchange: Political Economy and Modern Economic Theory," American Economic Review 78 (1988): 145-50; Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal, "Why Are Capitalists the Bosses," Economic Journal 99 (1989): 162-76; and Dilip Mookherjee, "Informational Rents and Property Rights in Land," in Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare, ed. John Roemer (MacMillan Press, forthcoming).
    • (1985) American Economic Review , vol.75 , pp. 16-36
    • Bowles, S.1
  • 64
    • 0001427176 scopus 로고
    • Contested exchange: Political economy and modern economic theory
    • Including John Roemer, A General Theory of Exploitation and Class (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982); Pranab Bardhan, "Determinants of Supply and Demand for Labor in a Poor Agrarian Economy: An Analysis of Household Survey Data for Rural West Bengal," in Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia, ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 242-62; Samuel Bowles, "The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models," American Economic Review 75 (1985): 16-36; Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, "Contested Exchange: Political Economy and Modern Economic Theory," American Economic Review 78 (1988): 145-50; Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal, "Why Are Capitalists the Bosses," Economic Journal 99 (1989): 162-76; and Dilip Mookherjee, "Informational Rents and Property Rights in Land," in Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare, ed. John Roemer (MacMillan Press, forthcoming).
    • (1988) American Economic Review , vol.78 , pp. 145-150
    • Bowles, S.1    Gintis, H.2
  • 65
    • 0001404353 scopus 로고
    • Why are capitalists the bosses
    • Including John Roemer, A General Theory of Exploitation and Class (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982); Pranab Bardhan, "Determinants of Supply and Demand for Labor in a Poor Agrarian Economy: An Analysis of Household Survey Data for Rural West Bengal," in Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia, ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 242-62; Samuel Bowles, "The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models," American Economic Review 75 (1985): 16-36; Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, "Contested Exchange: Political Economy and Modern Economic Theory," American Economic Review 78 (1988): 145-50; Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal, "Why Are Capitalists the Bosses," Economic Journal 99 (1989): 162-76; and Dilip Mookherjee, "Informational Rents and Property Rights in Land," in Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare, ed. John Roemer (MacMillan Press, forthcoming).
    • (1989) Economic Journal , vol.99 , pp. 162-176
    • Eswaran, M.1    Kotwal, A.2
  • 66
    • 0003234240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Informational rents and property rights in land
    • ed. John Roemer (MacMillan Press, forthcoming)
    • Including John Roemer, A General Theory of Exploitation and Class (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982); Pranab Bardhan, "Determinants of Supply and Demand for Labor in a Poor Agrarian Economy: An Analysis of Household Survey Data for Rural West Bengal," in Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia, ed. Hans Binswanger and Mark Rosenzweig, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 242-62; Samuel Bowles, "The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models," American Economic Review 75 (1985): 16-36; Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, "Contested Exchange: Political Economy and Modern Economic Theory," American Economic Review 78 (1988): 145-50; Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal, "Why Are Capitalists the Bosses," Economic Journal 99 (1989): 162-76; and Dilip Mookherjee, "Informational Rents and Property Rights in Land," in Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare, ed. John Roemer (MacMillan Press, forthcoming).
    • Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare
    • Mookherjee, D.1
  • 67
    • 84920558670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income distribution and sustainable growth: A Latin American perspective
    • ed. Vito Tanzi and Keyoung Chu (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming)
    • Enrique Iglesias, "Income Distribution and Sustainable Growth: A Latin American Perspective," in Income Distribution and High-Quality Growth, ed. Vito Tanzi and Keyoung Chu (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming).
    • Income Distribution and High-Quality Growth
    • Iglesias, E.1
  • 68
    • 85033644964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The example of section 1 assumes that projects have fixed capital costs, a special case of increasing returns. The example of section 3 assumes, in addition, increasing returns to scale with respect to labor inputs over some initial range.
  • 69
    • 85033643940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moneylenders and bankers: Price-increasing subsidies with monopolistic competition
    • forthcoming
    • Karla Hoff and Joseph E. Stiglitz, "Moneylenders and Bankers: Price-Increasing Subsidies with Monopolistic Competition," Journal of Development Economics (forthcoming).
    • Journal of Development Economics
    • Hoff, K.1    Stiglitz, J.E.2
  • 70
    • 0003609517 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
    • Joseph Stiglitz, Whither Socialism? (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1994), 174.
    • (1994) Whither Socialism? , pp. 174
    • Stiglitz, J.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.