메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 18, Issue 3, 1998, Pages 325-340

No-fault laws and at-fault people

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0013068690     PISSN: 01448188     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1016/S0144-8188(98)00008-8     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (54)

References (76)
  • 1
    • 85030051101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Finding fault
    • February 13
    • Wark, John T. "Finding Fault." Detroit News, February 13, 1996.
    • (1996) Detroit News
    • Wark, J.T.1
  • 2
    • 0000620362 scopus 로고
    • Marriage and divorce: Informational constraints and private contracting
    • Peters, H. Elizabeth. (1986). "Marriage and Divorce: Informational Constraints and Private Contracting." American Economic Review 76:437.
    • (1986) American Economic Review , vol.76 , pp. 437
    • Peters, H.E.1
  • 3
    • 0039779363 scopus 로고
    • University of Chicago Press
    • The popular objections to fault grounds, including the distasteful and collusive process of "staged" grounds, are discussed in Herbert Jacobs, The Silent Revolution, University of Chicago Press, 1988.
    • (1988) The Silent Revolution
    • Jacobs, H.1
  • 4
    • 85030040785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 9A U.L.A. § 305.
  • 5
    • 0347046018 scopus 로고
    • § 14-10-107
    • Colo. Rev. Stat. § 14-10-107 (1995).
    • (1995) colo. Rev. Stat.
  • 6
    • 84928851321 scopus 로고
    • Divorce rates and the fault requirement
    • See Marvell, Thomas B., (1989). "Divorce Rates and the Fault Requirement." Law & Society Review 23:543, 544; Paul A. Nakonezy, Robert D. Shull, and Joseph Lee Rodgers. (1995). "The Effect of No-Fault Divorce Law on the Divorce Rates Across the 50 States and Its Relation to Income, Education and Religiosity." Journal of Marriage and the Family 57:477.
    • (1989) Law & Society Review , vol.23 , pp. 543
    • Marvell, T.B.1
  • 7
    • 84937298683 scopus 로고
    • The effect of no-fault divorce law on the divorce rates across the 50 states and its relation to income, education and religiosity
    • See Marvell, Thomas B., (1989). "Divorce Rates and the Fault Requirement." Law & Society Review 23:543, 544; Paul A. Nakonezy, Robert D. Shull, and Joseph Lee Rodgers. (1995). "The Effect of No-Fault Divorce Law on the Divorce Rates Across the 50 States and Its Relation to Income, Education and Religiosity." Journal of Marriage and the Family 57:477.
    • (1995) Journal of Marriage and the Family , vol.57 , pp. 477
    • Nakonezy, P.A.1    Shull, R.D.2    Rodgers, J.L.3
  • 8
    • 0000565909 scopus 로고
    • Bargaining in the shadow of the law: The case of divorce
    • Mnookin, Robert H., and Lewis Kornhauser. (1979). "Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: The Case of Divorce." Yale Law Journal 88:950.
    • (1979) Yale Law Journal , vol.88 , pp. 950
    • Mnookin, R.H.1    Kornhauser, L.2
  • 9
    • 85030045168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2
    • Peters, supra note 2.
    • Peters1
  • 10
    • 0001068513 scopus 로고
    • Marriage and divorce: A comment
    • Allen, Douglas W., (1992). "Marriage and Divorce: A Comment." American Economic Review 82:297. See also, Allen Parkman, (1992). "Unilateral Divorce and the Labor Force Participation Rate of Married Women, Revisited." American Economic Review 82:671.
    • (1992) American Economic Review , vol.82 , pp. 297
    • Allen, D.W.1
  • 11
    • 0000062085 scopus 로고
    • Unilateral divorce and the labor force participation rate of married women, revisited
    • Allen, Douglas W., (1992). "Marriage and Divorce: A Comment." American Economic Review 82:297. See also, Allen Parkman, (1992). "Unilateral Divorce and the Labor Force Participation Rate of Married Women, Revisited." American Economic Review 82:671.
    • (1992) American Economic Review , vol.82 , pp. 671
    • Parkman, A.1
  • 13
    • 0013158894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inefficient dissolutions as a consequence of public goods: The case of no-fault divorce
    • "Inefficient Dissolutions as a Consequence of Public Goods: The Case of No-Fault Divorce." Journal of Legal Studies 22:503.
    • Journal of Legal Studies , vol.22 , pp. 503
  • 14
    • 0001789204 scopus 로고
    • Rational decisionmaking about marriage and divorce
    • at note 8
    • About 60% of married couples have children. Elizabeth Scott, (1990). "Rational Decisionmaking about Marriage and Divorce." Virginia Law Review 76:9, 94, at note 8.
    • (1990) Virginia Law Review , vol.76 , pp. 9
    • Scott, E.1
  • 15
    • 85030050618 scopus 로고
    • § 25.24.050
    • We preferred our definition of fault to that of the 1996 American Law Institute (ALI) Principles of Family Dissolution - Analysis and Recommendations 60 (Tentative Draft No. 2). Our list of fault states differs from that of the ALI Report in three respects. First, unlike the ALI, we label a state as a fault state if divorces maybe obtained on fault grounds, because this permits the innocent party to introduce marital misbehavior into settlement negotiations. By contrast, the ALI looks only to fault as it involves alimony or property distribution. Id. at 17. This difference affects three states. See Alaska Rev. Stat. § 25.24.050 (1995); Maine Rev. Stat. Ann. tit 19, § 691 (1995); and N.M. Stat. Ann. § 40-4-1 (1996). Second, our list is based on the 1979 to 1990 period, whereas the ALI list is from 1996. Fault is penalized in fewer states today than during the period of our study. Delaware, Illinois, and Kentucky all moved to no-fault between 1979 and 1990. Third, we excluded Nevada from our study as an outlier because it is a national divorce haven.
    • (1995) Alaska Rev. Stat.
  • 16
    • 85030054531 scopus 로고
    • tit 19, § 691
    • We preferred our definition of fault to that of the 1996 American Law Institute (ALI) Principles of Family Dissolution - Analysis and Recommendations 60 (Tentative Draft No. 2). Our list of fault states differs from that of the ALI Report in three respects. First, unlike the ALI, we label a state as a fault state if divorces maybe obtained on fault grounds, because this permits the innocent party to introduce marital misbehavior into settlement negotiations. By contrast, the ALI looks only to fault as it involves alimony or property distribution. Id. at 17. This difference affects three states. See Alaska Rev. Stat. § 25.24.050 (1995); Maine Rev. Stat. Ann. tit 19, § 691 (1995); and N.M. Stat. Ann. § 40-4-1 (1996). Second, our list is based on the 1979 to 1990 period, whereas the ALI list is from 1996. Fault is penalized in fewer states today than during the period of our study. Delaware, Illinois, and Kentucky all moved to no-fault between 1979 and 1990. Third, we excluded Nevada from our study as an outlier because it is a national divorce haven.
    • (1995) Maine Rev. Stat. Ann.
  • 17
    • 0039779351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 40-4-1 Second, our list is based on the 1979 to 1990 period, whereas the ALI list is from 1996. Fault is penalized in fewer states today than during the period of our study. Delaware, Illinois, and Kentucky all moved to no-fault between 1979 and 1990. Third, we excluded Nevada from our study as an outlier because it is a national divorce haven
    • We preferred our definition of fault to that of the 1996 American Law Institute (ALI) Principles of Family Dissolution - Analysis and Recommendations 60 (Tentative Draft No. 2). Our list of fault states differs from that of the ALI Report in three respects. First, unlike the ALI, we label a state as a fault state if divorces maybe obtained on fault grounds, because this permits the innocent party to introduce marital misbehavior into settlement negotiations. By contrast, the ALI looks only to fault as it involves alimony or property distribution. Id. at 17. This difference affects three states. See Alaska Rev. Stat. § 25.24.050 (1995); Maine Rev. Stat. Ann. tit 19, § 691 (1995); and N.M. Stat. Ann. § 40-4-1 (1996). Second, our list is based on the 1979 to 1990 period, whereas the ALI list is from 1996. Fault is penalized in fewer states today than during the period of our study. Delaware, Illinois, and Kentucky all moved to no-fault between 1979 and 1990. Third, we excluded Nevada from our study as an outlier because it is a national divorce haven.
    • (1996) N.M. Stat. Ann.
  • 18
    • 85030054547 scopus 로고
    • The "relevant facts" might refer to the parties' age or earning capacity but not to matrimonial fault
    • § 40-4-203
    • Mont. Code Anno. § 40-4-203 (1995). The "relevant facts" might refer to the parties' age or earning capacity but not to matrimonial fault.
    • (1995) Mont. Code Anno.
  • 19
    • 85030039686 scopus 로고
    • Labeling the law as fault or no-fault sometimes required an examination of case law to see whether fault was penalized in states where the parties were given the option of seeking a divorce on either fault or no-fault grounds
    • § 20-107.1
    • Va. Code Ann. § 20-107.1 (1995). Labeling the law as fault or no-fault sometimes required an examination of case law to see whether fault was penalized in states where the parties were given the option of seeking a divorce on either fault or no-fault grounds.
    • (1995) Va. Code Ann.
  • 20
    • 85030044710 scopus 로고
    • 256 S.C. 307, 182 S.E.2d 53
    • Towles v. Towles, 256 S.C. 307, 182 S.E.2d 53 (1971).
    • (1971) Towles V. Towles
  • 21
    • 0004039332 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
    • Richard A. Posner, (1992). Sex and Reason, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, p. 249;
    • (1992) Sex and Reason , pp. 249
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 22
  • 23
    • 84936628735 scopus 로고
    • Economic conditions and the divorce rate: A time-series analysis of the postwar United States
    • Scott J. South, (1985). "Economic Conditions and the Divorce Rate: A Time-Series Analysis of the Postwar United States." Journal of Marriage and Family 47:31. Writing much earlier, this is the sentiment of David Hume, (1987). Of polygamy and divorces. In Essays: Moral, Political and Literary, Eugene Miller, ed. 181-190. Indianopolis, IN: Liberty Classics. The fact that law does have an impact on behavior, particularly moral behavior, is the focus of Carl E. Schneider, (1992). "The Channelling Function in Family Law." Hofstra Law Review 20:495.
    • (1985) Journal of Marriage and Family , vol.47 , pp. 31
    • South, S.J.1
  • 24
    • 0039779343 scopus 로고
    • Of polygamy and divorces
    • Eugene Miller, ed.
    • Scott J. South, (1985). "Economic Conditions and the Divorce Rate: A Time-Series Analysis of the Postwar United States." Journal of Marriage and Family 47:31. Writing much earlier, this is the sentiment of David Hume, (1987). Of polygamy and divorces. In Essays: Moral, Political and Literary, Eugene Miller, ed. 181-190. Indianopolis, IN: Liberty Classics. The fact that law does have an impact on behavior, particularly moral behavior, is the focus of Carl E. Schneider, (1992). "The Channelling Function in Family Law." Hofstra Law Review 20:495.
    • (1987) Essays: Moral, Political and Literary , pp. 181-190
    • Hume, D.1
  • 25
    • 0040371514 scopus 로고
    • The channelling function in family law
    • Scott J. South, (1985). "Economic Conditions and the Divorce Rate: A Time-Series Analysis of the Postwar United States." Journal of Marriage and Family 47:31. Writing much earlier, this is the sentiment of David Hume, (1987). Of polygamy and divorces. In Essays: Moral, Political and Literary, Eugene Miller, ed. 181-190. Indianopolis, IN: Liberty Classics. The fact that law does have an impact on behavior, particularly moral behavior, is the focus of Carl E. Schneider, (1992). "The Channelling Function in Family Law." Hofstra Law Review 20:495.
    • (1992) Hofstra Law Review , vol.20 , pp. 495
    • Schneider, C.E.1
  • 26
    • 85030051260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 17
    • Brinig and Crafton, supra note 17.
    • Brinig1    Crafton2
  • 27
    • 85030043339 scopus 로고
    • 288 S.W.2d 473 Tenn. (suggesting that a financial penalty for divorce in antenuptial agreement would be contrary to public policy if the divorce suit was prosecuted in good faith and on reasonable grounds)
    • Sanders v. Sanders, 288 S.W.2d 473 (Tenn. 1955) (suggesting that a financial penalty for divorce in antenuptial agreement would be contrary to public policy if the divorce suit was prosecuted in good faith and on reasonable grounds); Norris v. Norris, 174 N.W.2d 368 (Iowa 1970) (impeaching an antenuptial fault clause). See further Theodore F. Haas, (1988). "Rationality and Enforceability of Contractual Restrictions on Divorce." North Carolina Law Review 66:879 (arguing for the enforceability of financial fetters on divorce in antenuptial agreements); Elizabeth Scott, (1994). "Rehabilitating Liberalism in Modern Divorce." Utah Law Review 687:722.
    • (1955) sanders V. Sanders
  • 28
    • 85030052158 scopus 로고
    • 174 N.W.2d 368 Iowa (impeaching an antenuptial fault clause)
    • Sanders v. Sanders, 288 S.W.2d 473 (Tenn. 1955) (suggesting that a financial penalty for divorce in antenuptial agreement would be contrary to public policy if the divorce suit was prosecuted in good faith and on reasonable grounds); Norris v. Norris, 174 N.W.2d 368 (Iowa 1970) (impeaching an antenuptial fault clause). See further Theodore F. Haas, (1988). "Rationality and Enforceability of Contractual Restrictions on Divorce." North Carolina Law Review 66:879 (arguing for the enforceability of financial fetters on divorce in antenuptial agreements); Elizabeth Scott, (1994). "Rehabilitating Liberalism in Modern Divorce." Utah Law Review 687:722.
    • (1970) Norris v. Norris
  • 29
    • 0040965727 scopus 로고
    • Rationality and enforceability of contractual restrictions on divorce
    • arguing for the enforceability of financial fetters on divorce in antenuptial agreements
    • Sanders v. Sanders, 288 S.W.2d 473 (Tenn. 1955) (suggesting that a financial penalty for divorce in antenuptial agreement would be contrary to public policy if the divorce suit was prosecuted in good faith and on reasonable grounds); Norris v. Norris, 174 N.W.2d 368 (Iowa 1970) (impeaching an antenuptial fault clause). See further Theodore F. Haas, (1988). "Rationality and Enforceability of Contractual Restrictions on Divorce." North Carolina Law Review 66:879 (arguing for the enforceability of financial fetters on divorce in antenuptial agreements); Elizabeth Scott, (1994). "Rehabilitating Liberalism in Modern Divorce." Utah Law Review 687:722.
    • (1988) North Carolina Law Review , vol.66 , pp. 879
    • Haas, F.1
  • 30
    • 0040371491 scopus 로고
    • Rehabilitating liberalism in modern divorce
    • Sanders v. Sanders, 288 S.W.2d 473 (Tenn. 1955) (suggesting that a financial penalty for divorce in antenuptial agreement would be contrary to public policy if the divorce suit was prosecuted in good faith and on reasonable grounds); Norris v. Norris, 174 N.W.2d 368 (Iowa 1970) (impeaching an antenuptial fault clause). See further Theodore F. Haas, (1988). "Rationality and Enforceability of Contractual Restrictions on Divorce." North Carolina Law Review 66:879 (arguing for the enforceability of financial fetters on divorce in antenupti0al agreements); Elizabeth Scott, (1994). "Rehabilitating Liberalism in Modern Divorce." Utah Law Review 687:722.
    • (1994) Utah Law Review , vol.687 , pp. 722
    • Scott, E.1
  • 31
    • 0040965718 scopus 로고
    • Mandatory planning for divorce
    • The signaling problem would persist if the parties were asked to elect between a fault and a no-fault regime, as Jeffrey Stake has suggested. Jeffrey E. Stake, (1992). "Mandatory Planning for Divorce." Vanderbilt Law Review 45:397. In the past, the signaling problem was addressed through the appointment of parents to bargain on behalf of their engaged children. Apart from illegality and signaling problems, the myopic might fail to provide for the consequences of divorce in an antenuptial agreement because they ascribe too low a probability to divorce. See Scott, supra note 20, at 722.
    • (1992) Vanderbilt Law Review , vol.45 , pp. 397
    • Stake, J.E.1
  • 32
    • 85030043819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 20, at 722
    • The signaling problem would persist if the parties were asked to elect between a fault and a no-fault regime, as Jeffrey Stake has suggested. Jeffrey E. Stake, (1992). "Mandatory Planning for Divorce." Vanderbilt Law Review 45:397. In the past, the signaling problem was addressed through the appointment of parents to bargain on behalf of their engaged children. Apart from illegality and signaling problems, the myopic might fail to provide for the consequences of divorce in an antenuptial agreement because they ascribe too low a probability to divorce. See Scott, supra note 20, at 722.
    • Scott1
  • 34
    • 85030043949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We obtained the number of married couples in each state for 1980 and 1990 from the decennial censuses. For intervening years, we multiplied the state population by the married couple ratio, which we constructed by assuming an equal change each year.
  • 35
    • 85030048480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Table available from authors.
  • 36
    • 85030035161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • From 1973 to 1991, Nevada's average annual divorce rate was 15.47 per 1000, about three times higher than the mean of 5.08 when Nevada was excluded. The next highest rate was approximately 8.
  • 37
    • 85030048906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra text in notes 14 and 15.
  • 38
    • 0040371483 scopus 로고
    • Fraud in courtship
    • In egregious cases, issues of fault may surface in tort actions See Brinig and Crafton, supra note 17, at 893 and note 108. Fault might also result in an annulment. See Brinig, Margaret F., and Michael V. Alexeev, (1994). "Fraud in Courtship." European Journal of Law and Economics 2:45.
    • (1994) European Journal of Law and Economics , vol.2 , pp. 45
    • Brinig, M.F.1    Alexeev, M.V.2
  • 39
    • 0040371439 scopus 로고
    • Trading at divorce: Preferences, legal rules and transaction costs
    • The evidence from panel studies indicates that payouts are higher in fault states (as we have defined that term). See Margaret F. Brinig, and Michael V. Alexeev, (1993). "Trading at Divorce: Preferences, Legal Rules and Transaction Costs." Ohio State Journal of Dispute Resolution 8:279; Marsha Garrison, (1991). "Good Intentions Gone Awry: The Impact of New York's Equitable Distribution Law on Divorce Outcomes." Brooklyn Law Review 57:621; Michael Kelly and Greer Litton Fox, (1993). "Determinants of Alimony Awards." Syracuse Law Review 44:641; Elisabeth Landes, (1978). "The Economics of Alimony." Journal of Legal Studies 7:35. For example, Yoram Weiss, and Robert Willis, (1993). "Transfers Among Couples in Divorce Settlements." Journal of Labor Economics 11:629, 656 at Table 4, show that divorced wives with children received a mean of $9313 in no-fault states, compared to $5220 in fault states (as we define them). In most of these studies, however, the difference in payouts is not significant.
    • (1993) Ohio State Journal of Dispute Resolution , vol.8 , pp. 279
    • Brinig, M.F.1    Alexeev, M.V.2
  • 40
    • 0039186875 scopus 로고
    • Good intentions gone awry: The impact of New York's equitable distribution law on divorce outcomes
    • The evidence from panel studies indicates that payouts are higher in fault states (as we have defined that term). See Margaret F. Brinig, and Michael V. Alexeev, (1993). "Trading at Divorce: Preferences, Legal Rules and Transaction Costs." Ohio State Journal of Dispute Resolution 8:279; Marsha Garrison, (1991). "Good Intentions Gone Awry: The Impact of New York's Equitable Distribution Law on Divorce Outcomes." Brooklyn Law Review 57:621; Michael Kelly and Greer Litton Fox, (1993). "Determinants of Alimony Awards." Syracuse Law Review 44:641; Elisabeth Landes, (1978). "The Economics of Alimony." Journal of Legal Studies 7:35. For example, Yoram Weiss, and Robert Willis, (1993). "Transfers Among Couples in Divorce Settlements." Journal of Labor Economics 11:629, 656 at Table 4, show that divorced wives with children received a mean of $9313 in no-fault states, compared to $5220 in fault states (as we define them). In most of these studies, however, the difference in payouts is not significant.
    • (1991) Brooklyn Law Review , vol.57 , pp. 621
    • Garrison, M.1
  • 41
    • 0011253939 scopus 로고
    • Determinants of alimony awards
    • The evidence from panel studies indicates that payouts are higher in fault states (as we have defined that term). See Margaret F. Brinig, and Michael V. Alexeev, (1993). "Trading at Divorce: Preferences, Legal Rules and Transaction Costs." Ohio State Journal of Dispute Resolution 8:279; Marsha Garrison, (1991). "Good Intentions Gone Awry: The Impact of New York's Equitable Distribution Law on Divorce Outcomes." Brooklyn Law Review 57:621; Michael Kelly and Greer Litton Fox, (1993). "Determinants of Alimony Awards." Syracuse Law Review 44:641; Elisabeth Landes, (1978). "The Economics of Alimony." Journal of Legal Studies 7:35. For example, Yoram Weiss, and Robert Willis, (1993). "Transfers Among Couples in Divorce Settlements." Journal of Labor Economics 11:629, 656 at Table 4, show that divorced wives with children received a mean of $9313 in no-fault states, compared to $5220 in fault states (as we define them). In most of these studies, however, the difference in payouts is not significant.
    • (1993) Syracuse Law Review , vol.44 , pp. 641
    • Kelly, M.1    Fox, G.L.2
  • 42
    • 84909769712 scopus 로고
    • The economics of alimony
    • The evidence from panel studies indicates that payouts are higher in fault states (as we have defined that term). See Margaret F. Brinig, and Michael V. Alexeev, (1993). "Trading at Divorce: Preferences, Legal Rules and Transaction Costs." Ohio State Journal of Dispute Resolution 8:279; Marsha Garrison, (1991). "Good Intentions Gone Awry: The Impact of New York's Equitable Distribution Law on Divorce Outcomes." Brooklyn Law Review 57:621; Michael Kelly and Greer Litton Fox, (1993). "Determinants of Alimony Awards." Syracuse Law Review 44:641; Elisabeth Landes, (1978). "The Economics of Alimony." Journal of Legal Studies 7:35. For example, Yoram Weiss, and Robert Willis, (1993). "Transfers Among Couples in Divorce Settlements." Journal of Labor Economics 11:629, 656 at Table 4, show that divorced wives with children received a mean of $9313 in no-fault states, compared to $5220 in fault states (as we define them). In most of these studies, however, the difference in payouts is not significant.
    • (1978) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.7 , pp. 35
    • Landes, E.1
  • 43
    • 0027687018 scopus 로고
    • Transfers among couples in divorce settlements
    • at Table 4, show that divorced wives with children received a mean of $9313 in no-fault states, compared to $5220 in fault states (as we define them). In most of these studies, however, the difference in payouts is not significant
    • The evidence from panel studies indicates that payouts are higher in fault states (as we have defined that term). See Margaret F. Brinig, and Michael V. Alexeev, (1993). "Trading at Divorce: Preferences, Legal Rules and Transaction Costs." Ohio State Journal of Dispute Resolution 8:279; Marsha Garrison, (1991). "Good Intentions Gone Awry: The Impact of New York's Equitable Distribution Law on Divorce Outcomes." Brooklyn Law Review 57:621; Michael Kelly and Greer Litton Fox, (1993). "Determinants of Alimony Awards." Syracuse Law Review 44:641; Elisabeth Landes, (1978). "The Economics of Alimony." Journal of Legal Studies 7:35. For example, Yoram Weiss, and Robert Willis, (1993). "Transfers Among Couples in Divorce Settlements." Journal of Labor Economics 11:629, 656 at Table 4, show that divorced wives with children received a mean of $9313 in no-fault states, compared to $5220 in fault states (as we define them). In most of these studies, however, the difference in payouts is not significant.
    • (1993) Journal of Labor Economics , vol.11 , pp. 629
    • Weiss, Y.1    Willis, R.2
  • 44
    • 85030035744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 17
    • The reductionist and unverifiable claim that all variables are social in nature is as unreasonable as the claim that at the bottom all variables are proxies for more fundamental economic conditions or legal variables. For a political explanation of when no-fault laws were introduced, employing a logit estimation technique, see Brinig and Crafton, supra note 17.
    • Brinig1    Crafton2
  • 45
    • 85030038794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is the percentage of members of the labor force who are actively looking for employment.
  • 46
    • 0039186932 scopus 로고
    • Madison, WI: Center for Demography and Ecology, unpublished manuscript, reporting a two-thirds greater probability of divorce if the husband was unemployed at any time during the first year of marriage
    • Bumpass, Larry, Teresa Castro Martin and James Sweet, (1990). "Background and Early Marital Factors in Marital Disruption." Madison, WI: Center for Demography and Ecology, unpublished manuscript, pp. 10 and 16 (reporting a two-thirds greater probability of divorce if the husband was unemployed at any time during the first year of marriage).
    • (1990) Background and Early Marital Factors in Marital Disruption , pp. 10
    • Bumpass, L.1    Martin, T.C.2    Sweet, J.3
  • 47
    • 0004106624 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
    • Becker, Gary S., (1991). A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, p. 339.
    • (1991) A Treatise on the Family , pp. 339
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 49
    • 85030041672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 18, at 37
    • South, supra note 18, at 37.
    • South1
  • 50
    • 0001310390 scopus 로고
    • Regional differences in divorce in the United States
    • Norval D. Glenn, and Beth Ann Shelton, (1985). "Regional Differences in Divorce in the United States." Journal Marriage and Family 47:641; Norval D. Glenn, and Michael Supanic, (1984). "The Social and Demographic Correlates of Divorce and Separation in the United States: An Update and Reconsideration." Journal of Marriage and Family 47:563.
    • (1985) Journal Marriage and Family , vol.47 , pp. 641
    • Glenn, N.D.1    Shelton, B.A.2
  • 51
    • 5244374131 scopus 로고
    • The social and demographic correlates of divorce and separation in the United States: An update and reconsideration
    • Norval D. Glenn, and Beth Ann Shelton, (1985). "Regional Differences in Divorce in the United States." Journal Marriage and Family 47:641; Norval D. Glenn, and Michael Supanic, (1984). "The Social and Demographic Correlates of Divorce and Separation in the United States: An Update and Reconsideration." Journal of Marriage and Family 47:563.
    • (1984) Journal of Marriage and Family , vol.47 , pp. 563
    • Glenn, N.D.1    Supanic, M.2
  • 52
    • 0040371484 scopus 로고
    • Reprinted Westport, CT
    • In 1908, the Labor Department reported that "the divorce rate increases as one goes westward." United States Department of Labor and Commerce, (1908). Marriage and Divorce 1867-1906, I, 14-15, (Reprinted Westport, CT, 1978).
    • (1908) Marriage and Divorce 1867-1906 , vol.1 , pp. 14-15
  • 53
    • 0004012894 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Roderick Phillips, (1988). Putting Asunder. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, p. 452.
    • (1988) Putting Asunder , pp. 452
    • Phillips, R.1
  • 54
  • 55
    • 0003461404 scopus 로고
    • New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
    • The ENTRY variable took the value of 1 for each of the original thirteen states. An ENTRY variable was used to predict state economic growth in Olson, Mancur. (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
    • (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations
    • Olson, M.1
  • 56
    • 85030055417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36
    • Phillips, supra note 36.
    • Phillips1
  • 57
    • 0000982594 scopus 로고
    • The economic way of looking at behavior
    • Gary S. Becker, (1993). "The Economic Way of Looking at Behavior." Journal of Political Economy 101:385. See also, ChristopherJ. Bruce, (1994). "An Economic Model of Spousal Support," Part III. Working paper, University of Calgary Department of Economics.
    • (1993) Journal of Political Economy , vol.101 , pp. 385
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 58
    • 85030055959 scopus 로고
    • Working paper, University of Calgary Department of Economics
    • Gary S. Becker, (1993). "The Economic Way of Looking at Behavior." Journal of Political Economy 101:385. See also, ChristopherJ. Bruce, (1994). "An Economic Model of Spousal Support," Part III. Working paper, University of Calgary Department of Economics.
    • (1994) An Economic Model of Spousal Support , Issue.PART III
    • Bruce, C.1
  • 59
    • 0040965641 scopus 로고
    • Behind the law of divorce
    • A point noted well before Becker. See, e.g., Karl Llewellyn, (1932). "Behind the Law of Divorce," Part 1. Columbia Law Review 32:1281, 1290.
    • (1932) Columbia Law Review , vol.32 , Issue.PART 1 , pp. 1281
    • Llewellyn, K.1
  • 60
    • 85030038911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • West Virginia Code §48-1-12b (1994), and the traditional marriage ceremony in the Book of Common Prayer
    • See, e.g., West Virginia Code §48-1-12b (1994), and the traditional marriage ceremony in the Book of Common Prayer.
  • 61
    • 85030045002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 33
    • Becker, et al. supra note 33, pp. 1147-1148; Paula England and Gary Farkas, (1988). Households, Employment and Gender. New York: Aldine Press; William Bishop, (1984). "Is He Married?: Marriage as Information." University of Toronto Law Journal 23:245, 249; Becker, supra note 32, at 337.
    • Becker1
  • 62
    • 0003740641 scopus 로고
    • New York: Aldine Press
    • Becker, et al. supra note 33, pp. 1147-1148; Paula England and Gary Farkas, (1988). Households, Employment and Gender. New York: Aldine Press; William Bishop, (1984). "Is He Married?: Marriage as Information." University of Toronto Law Journal 23:245, 249; Becker, supra note 32, at 337.
    • (1988) Households, Employment and Gender
    • England, P.1    Farkas, G.2
  • 63
    • 84926282046 scopus 로고
    • Is he married?: Marriage as information
    • Becker, et al. supra note 33, pp. 1147-1148; Paula England and Gary Farkas, (1988). Households, Employment and Gender. New York: Aldine Press; William Bishop, (1984). "Is He Married?: Marriage as Information." University of Toronto Law Journal 23:245, 249; Becker, supra note 32, at 337.
    • (1984) University of Toronto Law Journal , vol.23 , pp. 245
    • Bishop, W.1
  • 64
    • 85030042156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 32, at 337
    • Becker, et al. supra note 33, pp. 1147-1148; Paula England and Gary Farkas, (1988). Households, Employment and Gender. New York: Aldine Press; William Bishop, (1984). "Is He Married?: Marriage as Information." University of Toronto Law Journal 23:245, 249; Becker, supra note 32, at 337.
    • Becker1
  • 65
    • 85030038201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We re-estimated divorce levels in regressions that omitted the INSURE variable and found that little changed, particularly with respect to our legal coefficients. Data available from authors.
  • 66
    • 85030044669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reed Reference Publishing Company, New Providence, NJ
    • 45 Source: Official Catholic Directory, years 1970 to 1991, published by P.J. Kennedy & Sons in association with R.R. Bowker, A. Reed Reference Publishing Company, New Providence, NJ.
    • Kennedy, P.J.1    Bowker, R.R.2
  • 68
    • 85030048731 scopus 로고
    • Attitudes on marriage surveyed; catholic, protestant divorce rates similar
    • Saturday, April 8, at CIS. These figures understate the difference in divorce rates, because Protestants are more likely to remarry and have a second divorce. Although 54% of divorced Protestants remarry, only 39% of divorced Catholics do so. Once again, we re-estimated divorce levels in regressions that omitted the CATHOLIC variable and found that little changed, particularly for our legal coefficients. Data available from authors
    • George Gallup Jr. and Jim Castelli, "Attitudes On Marriage Surveyed; Catholic, Protestant Divorce Rates Similar," Washington Post, Saturday, April 8, 1989, at CIS. These figures understate the difference in divorce rates, because Protestants are more likely to remarry and have a second divorce. Although 54% of divorced Protestants remarry, only 39% of divorced Catholics do so. Once again, we re-estimated divorce levels in regressions that omitted the CATHOLIC variable and found that little changed, particularly for our legal coefficients. Data available from authors.
    • (1989) Washington Post
    • Gallup G., Jr.1    Castelli, J.2
  • 69
    • 0040371440 scopus 로고
    • Comments on Danzon, Maki, Murray, and Allen
    • New York, NY: MacMillan
    • Judge 1988: § 11.4. On the need to employ a fixed-state effect model for TSCS data, see Gary Becker, (1993). "Comments on Danzon, Maki, Murray, and Allen." Journal of Labor Economics New York, NY: MacMillan, 11:S326.
    • (1993) Journal of Labor Economics , vol.11
    • Becker, G.1
  • 70
    • 85030034788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 were 173.857 and 162.311, respectively (again, with 23 degrees of freedom).
  • 71
    • 0004106009 scopus 로고
    • New York, NY: MacMillan
    • On CHTA estimation, see Jan Kmenta, (1986). Elements of Econometrics. New York, NY: MacMillan, 618-622.
    • (1986) Elements of Econometrics , pp. 618-622
    • Kmenta, J.1
  • 73
    • 85030036410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, printouts for various years.
  • 76
    • 85030050212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In an OLS model employing a lagged dependent variable, the NO-FAULT coefficient was positive and significant, whereas the PETERS coefficient was positive and insignificant. In an OLS non-fixed-state effects model, both coefficients were positive and insignificant when a lagged dependent variable was employed, and they were positive and significant when it was not. Tables available from authors on request.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.