-
1
-
-
0000638836
-
A paradigm of entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial management
-
summer
-
A growing consensus has emerged that entrepreneurship is defined by the pursuit of opportunity rather than the size of a business or its stage in the life cycle. See H.H. Stevenson and J.C. Jarillo, "A Paradigm of Entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial Management," Strategic Management Journal 11 (summer 1990): 17-27; and S. Shane and S. Venkataraman, "The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research," Academy of Management Review 25, no. 1 (January 2000): 217-226. For a comparison of how an opportunity-based strategic logic contrasts with the resource-based and positional logics of strategy, see K.M. Eisenhardt and D.N. Sull, "Strategy as Simple Rules," Harvard Business Review 79 (January 2001): 107-116.
-
(1990)
Strategic Management Journal
, vol.11
, pp. 17-27
-
-
Stevenson, H.H.1
Jarillo, J.C.2
-
2
-
-
0034341743
-
The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research
-
January
-
A growing consensus has emerged that entrepreneurship is defined by the pursuit of opportunity rather than the size of a business or its stage in the life cycle. See H.H. Stevenson and J.C. Jarillo, "A Paradigm of Entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial Management," Strategic Management Journal 11 (summer 1990): 17-27; and S. Shane and S. Venkataraman, "The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research," Academy of Management Review 25, no. 1 (January 2000): 217-226. For a comparison of how an opportunity-based strategic logic contrasts with the resource-based and positional logics of strategy, see K.M. Eisenhardt and D.N. Sull, "Strategy as Simple Rules," Harvard Business Review 79 (January 2001): 107-116.
-
(2000)
Academy of Management Review
, vol.25
, Issue.1
, pp. 217-226
-
-
Shane, S.1
Venkataraman, S.2
-
3
-
-
0035220009
-
Strategy as simple rules
-
January
-
A growing consensus has emerged that entrepreneurship is defined by the pursuit of opportunity rather than the size of a business or its stage in the life cycle. See H.H. Stevenson and J.C. Jarillo, "A Paradigm of Entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial Management," Strategic Management Journal 11 (summer 1990): 17-27; and S. Shane and S. Venkataraman, "The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research," Academy of Management Review 25, no. 1 (January 2000): 217-226. For a comparison of how an opportunity-based strategic logic contrasts with the resource-based and positional logics of strategy, see K.M. Eisenhardt and D.N. Sull, "Strategy as Simple Rules," Harvard Business Review 79 (January 2001): 107-116.
-
(2001)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.79
, pp. 107-116
-
-
Eisenhardt, K.M.1
Sull, D.N.2
-
4
-
-
0004066308
-
-
Boston: Houghton Mifflin
-
Theorists have delineated multiple ways in which our knowledge of the future is incomplete, which I group under the broad term "uncertainty. " These categories include: Risk, or a variable known to be relevant to an agent's decision (for example, financial return to investors) with a known probability distribution. See F. Knight, "Risk, Uncertainty and Profit" (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1921); Complexity, or "the minimum number of distinct variables a formula or model must possess in order to reproduce the characteristic patterns of a structure." Complexity multiplies both the number of relevant variables that must be included in a model and their potential interactions, thereby increasing the difficulty of predicting outcomes. See F. Hayek, "Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967), 25; Ignorance, or "unknown unknowns," which results when a variable's existence or importance is unknown to an agent at a point in time. Israel Kirzner placed this at the center of his theory of entrepreneurial discovery. See I.M. Kirzner, "Perception, Opportunity and Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979); Indeterminism that results because an agent's actions - particularly in response to unforeseen events influence ultimate outcomes. Because the agent can respond creatively to unforeseen events, outcomes are not determined by initial conditions. See K.R. Popper, 'The Open Universe: An Argument for Indeterminism" (London: Routledge, 1982).
-
(1921)
Risk, Uncertainty and Profit
-
-
Knight, F.1
-
5
-
-
0003631667
-
-
Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
Theorists have delineated multiple ways in which our knowledge of the future is incomplete, which I group under the broad term "uncertainty. " These categories include: Risk, or a variable known to be relevant to an agent's decision (for example, financial return to investors) with a known probability distribution. See F. Knight, "Risk, Uncertainty and Profit" (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1921); Complexity, or "the minimum number of distinct variables a formula or model must possess in order to reproduce the characteristic patterns of a structure." Complexity multiplies both the number of relevant variables that must be included in a model and their potential interactions, thereby increasing the difficulty of predicting outcomes. See F. Hayek, "Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967), 25; Ignorance, or "unknown unknowns," which results when a variable's existence or importance is unknown to an agent at a point in time. Israel Kirzner placed this at the center of his theory of entrepreneurial discovery. See I.M. Kirzner, "Perception, Opportunity and Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979); Indeterminism that results because an agent's actions - particularly in response to unforeseen events influence ultimate outcomes. Because the agent can respond creatively to unforeseen events, outcomes are not determined by initial conditions. See K.R. Popper, 'The Open Universe: An Argument for Indeterminism" (London: Routledge, 1982).
-
(1967)
Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics
, pp. 25
-
-
Hayek, F.1
-
6
-
-
0003681443
-
-
Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
Theorists have delineated multiple ways in which our knowledge of the future is incomplete, which I group under the broad term "uncertainty. " These categories include: Risk, or a variable known to be relevant to an agent's decision (for example, financial return to investors) with a known probability distribution. See F. Knight, "Risk, Uncertainty and Profit" (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1921); Complexity, or "the minimum number of distinct variables a formula or model must possess in order to reproduce the characteristic patterns of a structure." Complexity multiplies both the number of relevant variables that must be included in a model and their potential interactions, thereby increasing the difficulty of predicting outcomes. See F. Hayek, "Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967), 25; Ignorance, or "unknown unknowns," which results when a variable's existence or importance is unknown to an agent at a point in time. Israel Kirzner placed this at the center of his theory of entrepreneurial discovery. See I.M. Kirzner, "Perception, Opportunity and Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979); Indeterminism that results because an agent's actions - particularly in response to unforeseen events influence ultimate outcomes. Because the agent can respond creatively to unforeseen events, outcomes are not determined by initial conditions. See K.R. Popper, 'The Open Universe: An Argument for Indeterminism" (London: Routledge, 1982).
-
(1979)
Perception, Opportunity and Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship
-
-
Kirzner, I.M.1
-
7
-
-
0003699336
-
-
London: Routledge
-
Theorists have delineated multiple ways in which our knowledge of the future is incomplete, which I group under the broad term "uncertainty. " These categories include: Risk, or a variable known to be relevant to an agent's decision (for example, financial return to investors) with a known probability distribution. See F. Knight, "Risk, Uncertainty and Profit" (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1921); Complexity, or "the minimum number of distinct variables a formula or model must possess in order to reproduce the characteristic patterns of a structure." Complexity multiplies both the number of relevant variables that must be included in a model and their potential interactions, thereby increasing the difficulty of predicting outcomes. See F. Hayek, "Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967), 25; Ignorance, or "unknown unknowns," which results when a variable's existence or importance is unknown to an agent at a point in time. Israel Kirzner placed this at the center of his theory of entrepreneurial discovery. See I.M. Kirzner, "Perception, Opportunity and Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship" (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979); Indeterminism that results because an agent's actions - particularly in response to unforeseen events influence ultimate outcomes. Because the agent can respond creatively to unforeseen events, outcomes are not determined by initial conditions. See K.R. Popper, 'The Open Universe: An Argument for Indeterminism" (London: Routledge, 1982).
-
(1982)
The Open Universe: An Argument for Indeterminism
-
-
Popper, K.R.1
-
8
-
-
0003679946
-
-
New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers
-
Economic theory linking entrepreneurship with the management of uncertainty has a long and distinguished pedigree. The first definition of an entrepreneur, made by Richard de Cantillon in the 1750s, defined the entrepreneur's role in terms of bearing the uncertainty inherent in a new undertaking. See R. de Cantillon, "Essay on the Nature of Commerce in General" (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers, 2001). More recently, the economists collectively known as 'The Austrian School" studied the role of entrepreneurship and focused on entrepreneurs as economic agents who deploy resources in new uses and therefore face challenges of incomplete knowledge about the returns from the resources in their new deployment. See J.A. Schumpeter, 'The Theory of Economic Development" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1934), 64-83; and L. von Mises, "Human Action: A Treatise on Economies" (San Francisco: Fox & Wilkes, 1996), 252-256.
-
(2001)
Essay on the Nature of Commerce in General
-
-
De Cantillon, R.1
-
9
-
-
0003971613
-
-
Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press
-
Economic theory linking entrepreneurship with the management of uncertainty has a long and distinguished pedigree. The first definition of an entrepreneur, made by Richard de Cantillon in the 1750s, defined the entrepreneur's role in terms of bearing the uncertainty inherent in a new undertaking. See R. de Cantillon, "Essay on the Nature of Commerce in General" (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers, 2001). More recently, the economists collectively known as 'The Austrian School" studied the role of entrepreneurship and focused on entrepreneurs as economic agents who deploy resources in new uses and therefore face challenges of incomplete knowledge about the returns from the resources in their new deployment. See J.A. Schumpeter, 'The Theory of Economic Development" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1934), 64-83; and L. von Mises, "Human Action: A Treatise on Economies" (San Francisco: Fox & Wilkes, 1996), 252-256.
-
(1934)
The Theory of Economic Development
, pp. 64-83
-
-
Schumpeter, J.A.1
-
10
-
-
0004069543
-
-
San Francisco: Fox & Wilkes
-
Economic theory linking entrepreneurship with the management of uncertainty has a long and distinguished pedigree. The first definition of an entrepreneur, made by Richard de Cantillon in the 1750s, defined the entrepreneur's role in terms of bearing the uncertainty inherent in a new undertaking. See R. de Cantillon, "Essay on the Nature of Commerce in General" (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers, 2001). More recently, the economists collectively known as 'The Austrian School" studied the role of entrepreneurship and focused on entrepreneurs as economic agents who deploy resources in new uses and therefore face challenges of incomplete knowledge about the returns from the resources in their new deployment. See J.A. Schumpeter, 'The Theory of Economic Development" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1934), 64-83; and L. von Mises, "Human Action: A Treatise on Economies" (San Francisco: Fox & Wilkes, 1996), 252-256.
-
(1996)
Human Action: A Treatise on Economies
, pp. 252-256
-
-
Von Mises, L.1
-
11
-
-
0004192228
-
-
Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall
-
A large body of academic research assumes that managers generally avoid risk through a variety of mechanisms including "uncertainty avoidance strategies." See R.M. Cyert and J.G. March, "A Behavioral Theory of the Firm" (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1963): 167. On "routinization," see R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1982). On "buffering" a firm's technical core against uncertainty, see J.D. Thompson, "Organizations in Action" (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967). On accumulating slack resources as a hedge, see J. Pfeffer and G.R. Salancik, "The External Control of Organizations: Resource Dependence Perspective" (New York: Harper & Row, 1978). On imitation of organizations perceived as successful, see P.J. DiMaggio and W.W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 (1983): 147-160.
-
(1963)
A Behavioral Theory of the Firm
, pp. 167
-
-
Cyert, R.M.1
March, J.G.2
-
12
-
-
0003831870
-
-
Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press
-
A large body of academic research assumes that managers generally avoid risk through a variety of mechanisms including "uncertainty avoidance strategies." See R.M. Cyert and J.G. March, "A Behavioral Theory of the Firm" (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1963): 167. On "routinization," see R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1982). On "buffering" a firm's technical core against uncertainty, see J.D. Thompson, "Organizations in Action" (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967). On accumulating slack resources as a hedge, see J. Pfeffer and G.R. Salancik, "The External Control of Organizations: Resource Dependence Perspective" (New York: Harper & Row, 1978). On imitation of organizations perceived as successful, see P.J. DiMaggio and W.W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 (1983): 147-160.
-
(1982)
An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change
-
-
Nelson, R.R.1
Winter, S.G.2
-
13
-
-
0003806911
-
-
New York: McGraw-Hill
-
A large body of academic research assumes that managers generally avoid risk through a variety of mechanisms including "uncertainty avoidance strategies." See R.M. Cyert and J.G. March, "A Behavioral Theory of the Firm" (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1963): 167. On "routinization," see R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1982). On "buffering" a firm's technical core against uncertainty, see J.D. Thompson, "Organizations in Action" (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967). On accumulating slack resources as a hedge, see J. Pfeffer and G.R. Salancik, "The External Control of Organizations: Resource Dependence Perspective" (New York: Harper & Row, 1978). On imitation of organizations perceived as successful, see P.J. DiMaggio and W.W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 (1983): 147-160.
-
(1967)
Organizations in Action
-
-
Thompson, J.D.1
-
14
-
-
0003447274
-
-
New York: Harper & Row
-
A large body of academic research assumes that managers generally avoid risk through a variety of mechanisms including "uncertainty avoidance strategies." See R.M. Cyert and J.G. March, "A Behavioral Theory of the Firm" (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1963): 167. On "routinization," see R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1982). On "buffering" a firm's technical core against uncertainty, see J.D. Thompson, "Organizations in Action" (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967). On accumulating slack resources as a hedge, see J. Pfeffer and G.R. Salancik, "The External Control of Organizations: Resource Dependence Perspective" (New York: Harper & Row, 1978). On imitation of organizations perceived as successful, see P.J. DiMaggio and W.W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 (1983): 147-160.
-
(1978)
The External Control of Organizations: Resource Dependence Perspective
-
-
Pfeffer, J.1
Salancik, G.R.2
-
15
-
-
0000953669
-
The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields
-
A large body of academic research assumes that managers generally avoid risk through a variety of mechanisms including "uncertainty avoidance strategies." See R.M. Cyert and J.G. March, "A Behavioral Theory of the Firm" (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1963): 167. On "routinization," see R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1982). On "buffering" a firm's technical core against uncertainty, see J.D. Thompson, "Organizations in Action" (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967). On accumulating slack resources as a hedge, see J. Pfeffer and G.R. Salancik, "The External Control of Organizations: Resource Dependence Perspective" (New York: Harper & Row, 1978). On imitation of organizations perceived as successful, see P.J. DiMaggio and W.W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 (1983): 147-160.
-
(1983)
American Sociological Review
, vol.48
, pp. 147-160
-
-
Dimaggio, P.J.1
Powell, W.W.2
-
16
-
-
0003432081
-
-
London: Routledge and Kegan Paul
-
The philosopher Karl Popper conceptualized science as an iterative process of identifying an anomaly between existing theory and empirical data, forming a tentative hypothesis to explain the anomaly and then eliminating errors in the hypothesis by submitting it to logical scrutiny and empirical testing. This process creates new knowledge that the scientist uses to refine his understanding of the anomaly, which in turn stimulates further logical analysis and experimentation. For an in-depth description of Popper's thought, see K.R. Popper, "Conjectures and Refutations: The Growth of Scientific Knowledge" (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1963). For an accessible summary see, K.R. Popper, "Unended Quest: An Intellectual Autobiography," vol. 1 in "The Philosophy of Karl Popper," ed. P.A. Schilpp (La Salle, Illinois: Open Court Publishing, 1974); and B. Magee, "Philosophy and the Real World: An Introduction to Karl Popper" (London: Fontana, 1973). While Popper's model provides insight into the entrepreneurial process, it requires adaptation to fit business. The stimulus for the process is not an anomaly between theory and empirical data, but rather a gap in the market that could potentially be filled at a profit by a novel combination of resources. It is also necessary to add a step in which the entrepreneur assembles resources to test a hypothesis.
-
(1963)
Conjectures and Refutations: the Growth of Scientific Knowledge
-
-
Popper, K.R.1
-
17
-
-
0007262567
-
Unended quest: An intellectual autobiography
-
ed. P.A. Schilpp La Salle, Illinois: Open Court Publishing
-
The philosopher Karl Popper conceptualized science as an iterative process of identifying an anomaly between existing theory and empirical data, forming a tentative hypothesis to explain the anomaly and then eliminating errors in the hypothesis by submitting it to logical scrutiny and empirical testing. This process creates new knowledge that the scientist uses to refine his understanding of the anomaly, which in turn stimulates further logical analysis and experimentation. For an in-depth description of Popper's thought, see K.R. Popper, "Conjectures and Refutations: The Growth of Scientific Knowledge" (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1963). For an accessible summary see, K.R. Popper, "Unended Quest: An Intellectual Autobiography," vol. 1 in "The Philosophy of Karl Popper," ed. P.A. Schilpp (La Salle, Illinois: Open Court Publishing, 1974); and B. Magee, "Philosophy and the Real World: An Introduction to Karl Popper" (London: Fontana, 1973). While Popper's model provides insight into the entrepreneurial process, it requires adaptation to fit business. The stimulus for the process is not an anomaly between theory and empirical data, but rather a gap in the market that could potentially be filled at a profit by a novel combination of resources. It is also necessary to add a step in which the entrepreneur assembles resources to test a hypothesis.
-
(1974)
The Philosophy of Karl Popper
, vol.1
-
-
Popper, K.R.1
-
18
-
-
1542772397
-
-
London: Fontana
-
The philosopher Karl Popper conceptualized science as an iterative process of identifying an anomaly between existing theory and empirical data, forming a tentative hypothesis to explain the anomaly and then eliminating errors in the hypothesis by submitting it to logical scrutiny and empirical testing. This process creates new knowledge that the scientist uses to refine his understanding of the anomaly, which in turn stimulates further logical analysis and experimentation. For an in-depth description of Popper's thought, see K.R. Popper, "Conjectures and Refutations: The Growth of Scientific Knowledge" (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1963). For an accessible summary see, K.R. Popper, "Unended Quest: An Intellectual Autobiography," vol. 1 in "The Philosophy of Karl Popper," ed. P.A. Schilpp (La Salle, Illinois: Open Court Publishing, 1974); and B. Magee, "Philosophy and the Real World: An Introduction to Karl Popper" (London: Fontana, 1973). While Popper's model provides insight into the entrepreneurial process, it requires adaptation to fit business. The stimulus for the process is not an anomaly between theory and empirical data, but rather a gap in the market that could potentially be filled at a profit by a novel combination of resources. It is also necessary to add a step in which the entrepreneur assembles resources to test a hypothesis.
-
(1973)
Philosophy and the Real World: An Introduction to Karl Popper
-
-
-
20
-
-
0001939189
-
Discovery-driven planning
-
July
-
For an accessible and useful process to surface and test assumptions, see R.G. McGrath and I.C. MacMillan, "Discovery-Driven Planning," Harvard Business Review 73 (July 1995): 44-54.
-
(1995)
Harvard Business Review
, vol.73
, pp. 44-54
-
-
McGrath, R.G.1
MacMillan, I.C.2
-
21
-
-
9344249763
-
The financial perspective: What should entrepreneurs know?
-
eds. W.A. Sahlman, H.H. Stevenson, M.J. Roberts and A.V. Bhide Boston: Harvard Business School Press
-
For an in-depth and practical discussion of financial issues facing entrepreneurs, see W.A. Sahlman, 'The Financial Perspective: What Should Entrepreneurs Know?" in "Entrepreneurial Venture," eds. W.A. Sahlman, H.H. Stevenson, M.J. Roberts and A.V. Bhide (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1999), 238-261.
-
(1999)
Entrepreneurial Venture
, pp. 238-261
-
-
Sahlman, W.A.1
-
22
-
-
0004066308
-
-
Knight argued that the selection of managers is the single most important means of managing uncertainty because individuals vary in their propensity to bear and ability to manage them. See Knight, "Risk, Uncertainty and Profit," 291-298. Recent research has focused on the team, rather than the individual entrepreneur, as a mechanism for managing uncertainty. See, for example, K.M. Eisenhardt and C.B. Schoonhoven, "Organizational Growth: Linking Founding Team, Strategy, Environment and Growth Among U.S. Semiconductor Ventures, 1978-1988," Administrative Science Quarterly 35, no. 3 (September 1990): 504-529.
-
Risk, Uncertainty and Profit
, pp. 291-298
-
-
Knight1
-
23
-
-
84935500926
-
Organizational growth: Linking founding team, strategy, environment and growth among U.S. semiconductor ventures, 1978-1988
-
September
-
Knight argued that the selection of managers is the single most important means of managing uncertainty because individuals vary in their propensity to bear and ability to manage them. See Knight, "Risk, Uncertainty and Profit," 291-298. Recent research has focused on the team, rather than the individual entrepreneur, as a mechanism for managing uncertainty. See, for example, K.M. Eisenhardt and C.B. Schoonhoven, "Organizational Growth: Linking Founding Team, Strategy, Environment and Growth Among U.S. Semiconductor Ventures, 1978-1988," Administrative Science Quarterly 35, no. 3 (September 1990): 504-529.
-
(1990)
Administrative Science Quarterly
, vol.35
, Issue.3
, pp. 504-529
-
-
Eisenhardt, K.M.1
Schoonhoven, C.B.2
|