메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 3, Issue 4, 1997, Pages 347-378

Fair use, efficiency, and corrective justice

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 85007318995     PISSN: 13523252     EISSN: 14698048     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S1352325200000847     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (8)

References (132)
  • 1
    • 85022802376 scopus 로고
    • Inc., 104 F.2d 661, 662 (2d Cir. 1939). See also Robert C. Ellickson, ORDER WITHOUT LAW, HOW NEIGHBORS SETTLE DISPUTES, 258 (1991) (describing the fair use doctrine as “a murky area of law”); and Lloyd L. Weinreb, Fair's Fair A Comment on tlie Fair Use Doctrine, 103 HARV. L. REV. 1137, 1137-38 [hereinafter Weinreb].
    • Dellar v. Samuel Goldwyn, Inc., 104 F.2d 661, 662 (2d Cir. 1939). See also Robert C. Ellickson, ORDER WITHOUT LAW, HOW NEIGHBORS SETTLE DISPUTES, 258 (1991) (describing the fair use doctrine as “a murky area of law”); and Lloyd L. Weinreb, Fair's Fair A Comment on tlie Fair Use Doctrine, 103 HARV. L. REV. 1137, 1137-38 (1990) [hereinafter Weinreb].
    • (1990) Dellar v. Samuel Goldwyn
  • 2
    • 0040316390 scopus 로고
    • 103 HARV. L. REV. 1105, 1105-6 [hereinafter: Leval].
    • See generally Pierre N. Leval, Toward a Fair Use Standard, 103 HARV. L. REV. 1105, 1105-6 (1990) [hereinafter: Leval].
    • (1990) Toward a Fair Use Standard
    • Leval, P.N.1
  • 4
    • 85022878983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1106.
  • 5
    • 85022812291 scopus 로고
    • LAW AND PRACTICE, § 10.1 at 10:1-10:2 (2nd ed. ) [hereinafter Goldstein, Copyright: Principles].
    • See, e.g., Paul Goldstein, COPYRIGHT: PRINCIPLES, LAW AND PRACTICE, § 10.1 at 10:1-10:2 (2nd ed. 1995) [hereinafter Goldstein, Copyright: Principles].
    • (1995) COPYRIGHT: PRINCIPLES
    • Goldstein, P.1
  • 6
    • 85022859375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • COPYRIGHT: PRINCIPLES note 2, at 1106 (“Judges do not share a consensus on the meaning of fair use. Earlier decisions provide little basis for predicting later ones”).
    • Leval, COPYRIGHT: PRINCIPLES note 2, at 1106 (“Judges do not share a consensus on the meaning of fair use. Earlier decisions provide little basis for predicting later ones”).
    • Leval
  • 7
    • 85022902781 scopus 로고
    • In Rosemont Enterprises, Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 256 F. Supp. 55 (S.D.N.Y), mrV/366 F.2d 303 (2d. Cir. 1966), cert, denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967) the Second Circuit reversed an injunction issued by the district court In Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F. Supp. 429 (CD. Cal. 1979), rev'd, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir. 1981), rev'd 464 U.S. 417 (1984) the Ninth Circuit reversed the district court's finding of fair use and then was reversed by the Supreme Court's holding for the defendant. In Harper & Row Publishers Inc. v. Nation Enterprises, 557 F. Supp. 1067 (S.D.N.Y), modified, 723 F.2d 195 (2d Cir. 1983), rev'd471 U.S. 539 (1985) the decision of the district court to award damages to the plaintiff was reversed by the Second Circuit, which in turn was reversed by the Supreme Court. In Salinger v. Random House, Inc., 650 F. Supp. 413 (S.D.N.Y. 1986), rev'd, 811 F.2d 90 (2d. Cir.). cert, denied ASA U.S. 890 (1987), the Second Circuit reversed the district court's finding of fair use. In New Era Publications International v. Henry Holt & Co., 695 F. Supp. 1493 (S.D.N.Y. 1988), affdon other grounds, 873 F.2d 576 (2d. Cir. 1989) the district court's finding of fair use was reversed on appeal. Finally, in Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 754 F. Supp. 1150 (M.D. Tenn. 1991), rev'd972 F.2d 1429 (6th Cir. 1992), rev'd 510 U.S. 569 1164, the district court's finding of fair use was reversed by the Sixth Circuit and then reversed again by the Supreme Court.
    • Six recent prominent cases were reversed at every stage of review. In Rosemont Enterprises, Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 256 F. Supp. 55 (S.D.N.Y), mrV/366 F.2d 303 (2d. Cir. 1966), cert, denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967) the Second Circuit reversed an injunction issued by the district court In Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F. Supp. 429 (CD. Cal. 1979), rev'd, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir. 1981), rev'd 464 U.S. 417 (1984) the Ninth Circuit reversed the district court's finding of fair use and then was reversed by the Supreme Court's holding for the defendant. In Harper & Row Publishers Inc. v. Nation Enterprises, 557 F. Supp. 1067 (S.D.N.Y), modified, 723 F.2d 195 (2d Cir. 1983), rev'd471 U.S. 539 (1985) the decision of the district court to award damages to the plaintiff was reversed by the Second Circuit, which in turn was reversed by the Supreme Court. In Salinger v. Random House, Inc., 650 F. Supp. 413 (S.D.N.Y. 1986), rev'd, 811 F.2d 90 (2d. Cir.). cert, denied ASA U.S. 890 (1987), the Second Circuit reversed the district court's finding of fair use. In New Era Publications International v. Henry Holt & Co., 695 F. Supp. 1493 (S.D.N.Y. 1988), affdon other grounds, 873 F.2d 576 (2d. Cir. 1989) the district court's finding of fair use was reversed on appeal. Finally, in Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 754 F. Supp. 1150 (M.D. Tenn. 1991), rev'd972 F.2d 1429 (6th Cir. 1992), rev'd 510 U.S. 569 1164 (1994), the district court's finding of fair use was reversed by the Sixth Circuit and then reversed again by the Supreme Court.
    • (1994) Six recent prominent cases were reversed at every stage of review.
  • 8
    • 85022862401 scopus 로고
    • See Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 420 U.S. 376 (1975); Columbia Broadcasting Sys. v. Lowe's, Inc., 356 U.S. 43. The Sony case was decided by a 5-4 majority; see Sony, 464 U.S. 417; the Harper & Rmo case was decided by a 6-3 majority, see Harper & ROTH, 471 U.S.
    • In the first two cases that reached the Supreme Court it split 4-4 and thus in both cases no opinion was issued. See Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 420 U.S. 376 (1975); Columbia Broadcasting Sys. v. Lowe's, Inc., 356 U.S. 43 (1958). The Sony case was decided by a 5-4 majority; see Sony, 464 U.S. 417; the Harper & Rmo case was decided by a 6-3 majority, see Harper & ROTH, 471 U.S. 539.
    • (1958) the first two cases that reached the Supreme Court it split 4-4 and thus in both cases no opinion was issued. , pp. 539
  • 9
    • 85022774432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5M/ra note 1, at
    • Weinreb, 5M/ra note 1, at 1138.
    • Weinreb , pp. 1138
  • 10
    • 85022811009 scopus 로고
    • 82 COLUM. L. REV. 1600 (1982) [hereinafter Gordon, Fair Use] and William F. Fisher, Reconstructing the Fair Use Doctrine, 101 HARV. L. REV. 1659 [hereinafter Fisher].
    • See, e.g., Wendy J. Gordon, Fair Use as Market Failure: A Structural and Economic Analysis of the Jletamax Case and Its fredecessor, 82 COLUM. L. REV. 1600 (1982) [hereinafter Gordon, Fair Use] and William F. Fisher, Reconstructing the Fair Use Doctrine, 101 HARV. L. REV. 1659 (1988) [hereinafter Fisher].
    • (1988) Fair Use as Market Failure: A Structural and Economic Analysis of the Jletamax Case and Its fredecessor
    • Gordon, W.J.1
  • 13
    • 85022742935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 548.
  • 15
    • 85022754387 scopus 로고
    • (App.) 672, 680 (1752); also Mawan v. Tegg 2 Russ. (Ch.)
    • See, e.g., Tonsow v. Walker 3 Swans. (App.) 672, 680 (1752); also Mawan v. Tegg 2 Russ. (Ch.) 385, 390-91 (1826).
    • (1826) Tonsow v. Walker 3 Swans. , vol.385 , pp. 390-391
  • 16
    • 85022781252 scopus 로고
    • (Ch.) 422 (1810);dtedmBramwellv.Holcomb3My.&Cr. (Ch.)
    • Wilkinsv.Aikin 17Ves. (Ch.) 422 (1810);dtedmBramwellv.Holcomb3My.&Cr. (Ch.) 737,738(1836).
    • (1836) Wilkinsv.Aikin 17Ves. , vol.737 , pp. 738
  • 17
    • 85022753811 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Cary v. Kearsley 4 Esp. 168,170-71 (1803).
    • (1803) Cary v. Kearsley 4 Esp. , vol.168 , pp. 170-171
  • 18
    • 85022905999 scopus 로고
    • (K.B. ); also Patry, Cary v. Kearsley 4 Esp. note 3, at 11 n. 22 and the sources cited therein. As Patry points out, the absence of aminus furandi did not operate as a legal defense, but its presence operated “to deprive the appropriator of the privilege of fair use.” Id.
    • See, e.g., Roworth v. Wilkes 1 Camp. 94 (K.B. 1807); also Patry, Cary v. Kearsley 4 Esp. note 3, at 11 n. 22 and the sources cited therein. As Patry points out, the absence of aminus furandi did not operate as a legal defense, but its presence operated “to deprive the appropriator of the privilege of fair use.” Id.
    • (1807) Roworth v. Wilkes 1 Camp. 94
  • 19
    • 85022774570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 403,405 (1761) (No. 212). (The court must take notice of the springs flowing from trade; and though they cannot regard customs of trade as binding, yet will consider the consequences of them”).
    • Dodsley v. KinnersleyAmb. 403,405 (1761) (No. 212). (The court must take notice of the springs flowing from trade; and though they cannot regard customs of trade as binding, yet will consider the consequences of them”).
    • Dodsley v. KinnersleyAmb.
  • 20
    • 85022759109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (App.) 672, 680 (1752). (“Arguments from public utility maybe urged on both sides; but if this were more doubtful still it is clear that injunction ought to be granted, because the notes were colourably abridged or taken… and only twenty-eight were added.…”)
    • Tonson v. Walker 3 Swans. (App.) 672, 680 (1752). (“Arguments from public utility maybe urged on both sides; but if this were more doubtful still it is clear that injunction ought to be granted, because the notes were colourably abridged or taken… and only twenty-eight were added.…”)
    • Tonson v. Walker 3 Swans.
  • 21
    • 85022812980 scopus 로고
    • (C.C.D. Mass. ) (No. 4,091).
    • F. Cas. 342 (C.C.D. Mass. 1841) (No. 4,091).
    • (1841) F. Cas. 342
  • 22
    • 85022902978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 344-45.
  • 23
    • 85022856972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 24
    • 85022791966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 23 (The error in modem fair use litigation-avoided in Folsom u Marsh-is to start with precisely the “public interest” inquiry, which may be expressed in the question, “Does the public interest favor enforcing plaintiffs copyright?” Justice Story did not make the error of balancing the interests of the author and the public, but instead examined whether “defendant's use qualified as fair use with the full burden of making out an affirmative defense properly resting on the defendant'” [emphasis in the original]).
    • See Patry, Id. note 3, at 23 (The error in modem fair use litigation-avoided in Folsom u Marsh-is to start with precisely the “public interest” inquiry, which may be expressed in the question, “Does the public interest favor enforcing plaintiffs copyright?” Justice Story did not make the error of balancing the interests of the author and the public, but instead examined whether “defendant's use qualified as fair use with the full burden of making out an affirmative defense properly resting on the defendant'” [emphasis in the original]).
    • Id. note 3
    • Patry1
  • 25
    • 85022859721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They did not copy any of the narrative parts. The defendant's book contained 866 pages and was written in the form of an autobiography. The original work consisted of twelve volumes.
    • More specifically, the defendants copied 319 letters of President Washington that were included in the original work. They did not copy any of the narrative parts. The defendant's book contained 866 pages and was written in the form of an autobiography. The original work consisted of twelve volumes.
    • More specifically, the defendants copied 319 letters of President Washington that were included in the original work.
  • 26
    • 85022906430 scopus 로고
    • (2d Cir. 1966) quoting Berlin v. E. C. Publications Inc., 329 F.2d 541, 544 (2nd Cir. ).
    • F.2d 303 (2d Cir. 1966) quoting Berlin v. E. C. Publications Inc., 329 F.2d 541, 544 (2nd Cir. 1964).
    • (1964) F.2d 303
  • 30
    • 85022773154 scopus 로고
    • Jay Dratler Jr., Distilling the Witches’ Brew of Fair Use in Copyright'IMW, 45 U. MIAMI L. REV. 233 [hereinafter. Dratler]; also Weinreb, COPYRIGHT FOR THE NINETIES. note 1 note
    • See, e.g., Fisher, COPYRIGHT FOR THE NINETIES. note 1 note 10; Jay Dratler Jr., Distilling the Witches’ Brew of Fair Use in Copyright'IMW, 45 U. MIAMI L. REV. 233 (1988) [hereinafter. Dratler]; also Weinreb, COPYRIGHT FOR THE NINETIES. note 1 note 1.
    • (1988) COPYRIGHT FOR THE NINETIES. note 1 note 10 , pp. 1
    • Fisher1
  • 31
    • 85022751833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 464 U.S. at 451. A year later in Harper & /towjustice O'Connor writing for the majority branded the fourth factor-the effect of the second use on the potential market for the original work-as “the single most important element of fair use.” 471 U.S. at
    • In Sony, Justice Stevens writing for the majority stated that ever)’ commercial use is to he presumed unfair. 464 U.S. at 451. A year later in Harper & /towjustice O'Connor writing for the majority branded the fourth factor-the effect of the second use on the potential market for the original work-as “the single most important element of fair use.” 471 U.S. at 556.
    • Justice Stevens writing for the majority stated that ever)’ commercial use is to he presumed unfair. , pp. 556
    • Sony1
  • 32
    • 84885973260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 510 U.S. at
    • Campbell, 510 U.S. at 579.
    • Campbell , pp. 579
  • 33
    • 85022891768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 471 U.S. at 562-63. See also Fisher, Campbell note 10, at
    • Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 562-63. See also Fisher, Campbell note 10, at 1679-82.
    • Row, H.1
  • 35
    • 85022887405 scopus 로고
    • The term “wealth” in “wealth maximization” is defined as “the sum of all tangible and intangible goods and services weighted by prices of two sorts: offer prices (what people are willing to pay for goods they do not already own); and asking prices (what people demand to sell what they own).* Id. at
    • Richard A. Posner, THE PROMXMS OF JURISPRUDENCE 3fi2 (1990). The term “wealth” in “wealth maximization” is defined as “the sum of all tangible and intangible goods and services weighted by prices of two sorts: offer prices (what people are willing to pay for goods they do not already own); and asking prices (what people demand to sell what they own).* Id. at 356.
    • (1990) THE PROMXMS OF JURISPRUDENCE 3fi2 , pp. 356
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 36
    • 0004305328 scopus 로고
    • (Thomas K. Abott trans., 1919). For a discussion of this principle, see generally Jettric G. Murphy & Jules L.Coleman,PlHLOSOPHVOF LAW 77-81 (revised ed. ) [hereinafter Murphy and Coleman].
    • See Immanuel Kant, FUNDAMENTAL PRINCIPLES OFTHE METAPH\SIC OF MORALS 46 (Thomas K. Abott trans., 1919). For a discussion of this principle, see generally Jettric G. Murphy & Jules L.Coleman,PlHLOSOPHVOF LAW 77-81 (revised ed. 1990) [hereinafter Murphy and Coleman].
    • (1990) FUNDAMENTAL PRINCIPLES OFTHE METAPH\SIC OF MORALS 46
    • Kant, I.1
  • 37
    • 85022788449 scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter: Goldstein, Copyright's Highway].
    • See generally, Paul Goldstein, COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196 (1994) [hereinafter: Goldstein, Copyright's Highway].
    • (1994) COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196
    • Goldstein, P.1
  • 38
    • 85022835519 scopus 로고
    • COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196 note 2; Fisher, COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196 note 10; and Gordon, Fair Use, COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196 note 10. However, Jeremy Waldron observes that it seems psychologically unavoidable that rights grounded in utility will be taken as ends in themselves: too much emphasis on the utilitarian character of the premises can undermine people's sense that it is a right (as opposed, say, to some defeasible presumption or rule of thumb) that is grounded in this way. “Jeremy Waldron, From Authors to Copiers: Individual Rights and Social Values in Intellectual Ihoperty, 68 Cm.-KENT L. REV.
    • See, e.g., Leval, COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196 note 2; Fisher, COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196 note 10; and Gordon, Fair Use, COPYRIGHTS HIGHWAY 165-196 note 10. However, Jeremy Waldron observes that it seems psychologically unavoidable that rights grounded in utility will be taken as ends in themselves: too much emphasis on the utilitarian character of the premises can undermine people's sense that it is a right (as opposed, say, to some defeasible presumption or rule of thumb) that is grounded in this way. “Jeremy Waldron, From Authors to Copiers: Individual Rights and Social Values in Intellectual Ihoperty, 68 Cm.-KENT L. REV. 842,851 (1993).
    • (1993) Leval , vol.842 , pp. 851
  • 40
    • 85022841225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leval nolc 1 note 2, at
    • Leval, Leval nolc 1 note 2, at 1111.
    • Leval , pp. 1111
  • 41
    • 85022900422 scopus 로고
    • 293 F. Supp. 130 (S.D.N.Y. ), where the public interest in having as much information as possible on the assassination of President Kennedy weighed heavily in favor of allowing the incorporation of unique pictures of the murder in a book on that subject; also Wcinreb, Leval note 1, at
    • See, e.g. Time Inc. v. Bernard Geis Associates, 293 F. Supp. 130 (S.D.N.Y. 1968), where the public interest in having as much information as possible on the assassination of President Kennedy weighed heavily in favor of allowing the incorporation of unique pictures of the murder in a book on that subject; also Wcinreb, Leval note 1, at 1143.
    • (1968) Time Inc. v. Bernard Geis Associates , pp. 1143
  • 42
    • 85022832957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Time Inc. v. Bernard Geis Associates note 10, at
    • Gordon, Fair Use, Time Inc. v. Bernard Geis Associates note 10, at 1601.
    • Fair Use , pp. 1601
    • Gordon1
  • 43
    • 85022764401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1605-6.
  • 44
    • 85022779524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at
    • Id at 1607,1616.
    • , vol.1607 , pp. 1616
  • 45
    • 85022873885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1613.
  • 46
    • 85022745743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1614.
  • 48
    • 85022832957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This applies with equal vigor to Fisher's account that will be discussed below; note 10, at
    • Gordon, Fair Use, This applies with equal vigor to Fisher's account that will be discussed below; note 10, at 1627-35.
    • Fair Use , pp. 1627-1635
    • Gordon1
  • 49
    • 85022751816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1632-33.
  • 50
    • 85022741590 scopus 로고
    • For a more elaborate discussion of the problem of externalities see Richard Corncs & Todd Sandier, THE THEORY OF EXTERNALITIES, PUBLIC Goons AND CLUB Goons 29-66 [hereinafter: Comes and Sandier].
    • Externalities arc the effects of one's activities on others’ activities and entitlements. For a more elaborate discussion of the problem of externalities see Richard Corncs & Todd Sandier, THE THEORY OF EXTERNALITIES, PUBLIC Goons AND CLUB Goons 29-66 (1986) [hereinafter: Comes and Sandier].
    • (1986) Externalities arc the effects of one's activities on others’ activities and entitlements.
  • 51
    • 85022774993 scopus 로고
    • ” For an illuminating discussion of the subject see Jules Coleman & Arthur Ripstein, Mischief and Misfortune (Annual McGilt Lecture in furispniaVnce and Public Policy), 41 McGlLL L. J. 91 [hereinafter Coleman and Ripstein].
    • To determine whether copyright protection generates external costs and external benefits, we first have to clearly define the terms “cost” and “benefit.” For an illuminating discussion of the subject see Jules Coleman & Arthur Ripstein, Mischief and Misfortune (Annual McGilt Lecture in furispniaVnce and Public Policy), 41 McGlLL L. J. 91 (1995) [hereinafter Coleman and Ripstein].
    • (1995) To determine whether copyright protection generates external costs and external benefits, we first have to clearly define the terms “cost” and “benefit.
  • 52
    • 85022768019 scopus 로고
    • 13 J. L. & ECON. 49,70 (1970) (concluding that “[t]he concept of “externality” is vague because classification and theories [thereof] are varied, arbitrary and ad hoc. For these reasons, theories generated by the concept of “externality” are not liable to be helpful”); also, James M. Buchanan & Wm. Craig Stubblebine, teternality, 29 ECONOMICS
    • See, e.g., Steven N. S. Cheung, The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Resource, 13 J. L. & ECON. 49,70 (1970) (concluding that “[t]he concept of “externality” is vague because classification and theories [thereof] are varied, arbitrary and ad hoc. For these reasons, theories generated by the concept of “externality” are not liable to be helpful”); also, James M. Buchanan & Wm. Craig Stubblebine, teternality, 29 ECONOMICS 371 (1962).
    • (1962) The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Resource , pp. 371
    • Cheung, S.N.S.1
  • 53
    • 85022897692 scopus 로고
    • 22 J. L. & ECON. 141,143 (“It cannot be shown with purely conceptual analysis that markets do not handle externalities: any such assertion necessitates an assumption that the government can do better”).
    • See, e.g., Carl J. Dahlman, Thelroblem of Externality, 22 J. L. & ECON. 141,143 (1979) (“It cannot be shown with purely conceptual analysis that markets do not handle externalities: any such assertion necessitates an assumption that the government can do better”).
    • (1979) Thelroblem of Externality
    • Dahlman, C.J.1
  • 55
    • 85022895811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 310-15.
  • 56
    • 85022887864 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost, 3J. L. & ECON.
    • Ronald 11. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3J. L. & ECON. 1 (1960).
    • (1960) Ronald 11. Coase , pp. 1
  • 57
    • 85022851935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 464 U.S. at 479 (Blackmun, J. dissenting).
    • See Sony, 464 U.S. at 479 (Blackmun, J. dissenting).
    • Sony1
  • 58
    • 0004274663 scopus 로고
    • Ronald 11. Coase note 39, at 223-24; see also Paul Goldstein, Copy-I right in the New Information Age, 40 CATH. U. L. R. 829, 829 [hereinafter: Goldstein, ’ Copyright in the New Information Age].
    • Goldstein, Copyright's Highway, Ronald 11. Coase note 39, at 223-24; see also Paul Goldstein, Copy-I right in the New Information Age, 40 CATH. U. L. R. 829, 829 (1991) [hereinafter: Goldstein, ’ Copyright in the New Information Age].
    • (1991) Copyright's Highway
    • Goldstein1
  • 63
    • 33645547438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is because the existence of the fair use doctrine threatens to thwart the effective operation of copyright collectives like ASCAP and CCC. note 39, at 223-24; Dratler, This is because the existence of the fair use doctrine threatens to thwart the effective operation of copyright collectives like ASCAP and CCC. note 32, at 294 (“It makes no sense to provide a fair use subsidy to a user when a license could be efficiently negotiated”); also American Geophysical Union v. Texaco Inc., 802 F. Supp. 1 (S.D.N.Y. 1992), ajfd, 37 F.3d 881 (2d Cir. ).
    • See, e.g., Goldstein, Copyright's Highway, This is because the existence of the fair use doctrine threatens to thwart the effective operation of copyright collectives like ASCAP and CCC. note 39, at 223-24; Dratler, This is because the existence of the fair use doctrine threatens to thwart the effective operation of copyright collectives like ASCAP and CCC. note 32, at 294 (“It makes no sense to provide a fair use subsidy to a user when a license could be efficiently negotiated”); also American Geophysical Union v. Texaco Inc., 802 F. Supp. 1 (S.D.N.Y. 1992), ajfd, 37 F.3d 881 (2d Cir. 1994).
    • (1994) Copyright's Highway
    • Goldstein1
  • 64
    • 85022758517 scopus 로고
    • in 8 RESEARCH IN LAW AND ECONOMICS.-THE ECONOMICSOF PATENTS AND COPYRIGHTS 21 (J. Palmer& R. Zerbe eds., 1986). Likewise, Timothy Brennan appears to be right to conclude that “[a] full economic evaluation of copyright policy is impossible because the complexity of competitive interaction and demand substitutions among cop>Tighted works is beyond the capability of economic theory or data to generate cost-benefit analyses.” TimothyJ. Brennan, Copyright, Property and tlie Right to Deny, 68 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 675, 704 n.101
    • George Priest, What Economists Can Tell Lawyers about Intellectual I*roperty, in 8 RESEARCH IN LAW AND ECONOMICS.-THE ECONOMICSOF PATENTS AND COPYRIGHTS 21 (J. Palmer& R. Zerbe eds., 1986). Likewise, Timothy Brennan appears to be right to conclude that “[a] full economic evaluation of copyright policy is impossible because the complexity of competitive interaction and demand substitutions among cop>Tighted works is beyond the capability of economic theory or data to generate cost-benefit analyses.” TimothyJ. Brennan, Copyright, Property and tlie Right to Deny, 68 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 675, 704 n.101 (1993).
    • (1993) What Economists Can Tell Lawyers about Intellectual I*roperty
    • Priest, G.1
  • 66
    • 85022816710 scopus 로고
    • wrjules L, Coleman, Efficiency, Utility and Wealth Maximization, 8 HOFSTRA L. REV. 509,549 (arguing that even if economic efficiency should he maximized it docs not follow that courts and agents should act to this effect without “a further theory of institutional competence”).
    • For a normative discussion of the institutional aspects of law and economics, wrjules L, Coleman, Efficiency, Utility and Wealth Maximization, 8 HOFSTRA L. REV. 509,549 (1980) (arguing that even if economic efficiency should he maximized it docs not follow that courts and agents should act to this effect without “a further theory of institutional competence”).
    • (1980) For a normative discussion of the institutional aspects of law and economics
  • 67
    • 85022832957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a normative discussion of the institutional aspects of law and economics note 10, at 1619 (footnotes omitted).
    • Gordon, Fair Use, For a normative discussion of the institutional aspects of law and economics note 10, at 1619 (footnotes omitted).
    • Fair Use
    • Gordon1
  • 68
    • 85022796435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 471 U.S. at 564: New Era Ihiblications, 873 F.2d at 583; Salinger, 811 F.2d at 97 (2d. Cir.).
    • Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 564: New Era Ihiblications, 873 F.2d at 583; Salinger, 811 F.2d at 97 (2d. Cir.).
    • Row, H.1
  • 70
    • 85022741372 scopus 로고
    • Twenty percent of the victims believe that no remedy can adequately redress their harms. See Rendall P. Bezanson, John Soloski & Gilbert Cranberg, LIBEL LAW AND THE PRESS MYTH AND REALITY 1-28 (1987). Alfred Yen maintains that these findings can be extended to authors whose works have been parodied or harshly reviewed. Alfred C. Yen, Wien Authors Won't Sell; Parody, Fair Use, and Efficiency in Copyright IMJV, 62 U. COLO. L. REV.
    • Empirical data in the context of libel actions suggest that the majority of libel victims believe that money damages cannot make good their injuries. Twenty percent of the victims believe that no remedy can adequately redress their harms. See Rendall P. Bezanson, John Soloski & Gilbert Cranberg, LIBEL LAW AND THE PRESS MYTH AND REALITY 1-28 (1987). Alfred Yen maintains that these findings can be extended to authors whose works have been parodied or harshly reviewed. Alfred C. Yen, Wien Authors Won't Sell; Parody, Fair Use, and Efficiency in Copyright IMJV, 62 U. COLO. L. REV. 79, 105-6 (1991).
    • (1991) Empirical data in the context of libel actions suggest that the majority of libel victims believe that money damages cannot make good their injuries. , vol.79 , pp. 105-106
  • 73
    • 85022775114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at
    • Id at 1706.
  • 74
    • 84950190693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fisher suggests that each judge, after devising an incentive/loss ratio for each putatively infringing use, should arrange the various uses on the X-axis in order of their ratios and thereafter plot a graph of the u[n]et impact on economic efficiency of forbidding each successive use.” Based on this graph, the judge has to determine the use at which the net-efficiency curve peaks and then declare all the uses to the right of this point fair, and all the uses to the left of this point unfair. For a graphical illustration of this determination, see id. at
    • Specifically, Fisher suggests that each judge, after devising an incentive/loss ratio for each putatively infringing use, should arrange the various uses on the X-axis in order of their ratios and thereafter plot a graph of the u[n]et impact on economic efficiency of forbidding each successive use.” Based on this graph, the judge has to determine the use at which the net-efficiency curve peaks and then declare all the uses to the right of this point fair, and all the uses to the left of this point unfair. For a graphical illustration of this determination, see id. at 1716.
    • Specifically , pp. 1716
  • 75
    • 85022879925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1718.
  • 76
    • 85022874197 scopus 로고
    • Under their definition, a right is protected by a property rule when a transfer of an entitlement requires the ex-ante consent of the holder thereof. Liability rules protect entitlements by granting the owner a claim for compensation whenever the value of the entitlements is diminished by the actions of other people. & Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Ihvperty RuUs, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One Vmu of the Cathedral 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089 [hereinafter: Calabresi and Melamed].
    • Under the typology of Calabresi and Melamed, the fair use doctrine constitutes a property rule, or at least a variant thereof. Under their definition, a right is protected by a property rule when a transfer of an entitlement requires the ex-ante consent of the holder thereof. Liability rules protect entitlements by granting the owner a claim for compensation whenever the value of the entitlements is diminished by the actions of other people. & Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Ihvperty RuUs, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One Vmu of the Cathedral 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089 (1972) [hereinafter: Calabresi and Melamed].
    • (1972) Under the typology of Calabresi and Melamed, the fair use doctrine constitutes a property rule, or at least a variant thereof.
  • 78
    • 85022747451 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Calabresi and Melamed, The public also suffers an indirect loss when fair use is awarded because any such award-by the lights of economic analysis-adversely impacts the incentive of the original author to create in the future. note 80; Richard A. Posner, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 57,70 (4th ed. 1992). The most recent writings in this field suggest, however, that liability rules are better suited to enhance economic efficiency than property rules under circumstances of imperfect information. See, e.g., Ian Ayres & Eric Talley, Solomonic Bargaining: Dhnding a Isgal Entitlement to Facilitate Cosean Trade, 104 YAI.E L. J. 1027 (1995): also Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Prof>erty Rules Versus Uability Rules: An Economic Analysis, 109 HARV. L. REV.
    • For many years law and economics literature has suggested that when transaction costs are high, liability rules are superior to property rules. See, e.g., Calabresi and Melamed, The public also suffers an indirect loss when fair use is awarded because any such award-by the lights of economic analysis-adversely impacts the incentive of the original author to create in the future. note 80; Richard A. Posner, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 57,70 (4th ed. 1992). The most recent writings in this field suggest, however, that liability rules are better suited to enhance economic efficiency than property rules under circumstances of imperfect information. See, e.g., Ian Ayres & Eric Talley, Solomonic Bargaining: Dhnding a Isgal Entitlement to Facilitate Cosean Trade, 104 YAI.E L. J. 1027 (1995): also Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Prof>erty Rules Versus Uability Rules: An Economic Analysis, 109 HARV. L. REV. 713 (1996).
    • (1996) For many years law and economics literature has suggested that when transaction costs are high, liability rules are superior to property rules. , pp. 713
  • 80
    • 85022902229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1587.
  • 81
    • 85022902691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1572. No inferences can be made based on these data as to what impels authors to create. The use of these data to support the argument that authors do not expect monetary rewards is highly inadequate.
    • Id. at 1572. The data Lacey offers suggest that 70 percent of the authors who published at least one book are engaged in another work other than writing. No inferences can be made based on these data as to what impels authors to create. The use of these data to support the argument that authors do not expect monetary rewards is highly inadequate.
    • The data Lacey offers suggest that 70 percent of the authors who published at least one book are engaged in another work other than writing.
  • 84
    • 85022827560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1591.
  • 85
    • 85022767332 scopus 로고
    • 12 HARV. J. L. & PUB. PoL'Y 775, 777 (1989). See also David Lyons, Utility and Rights, 24 NOMOS
    • Loren E. Lomsky, Rights without Stills, 12 HARV. J. L. & PUB. PoL'Y 775, 777 (1989). See also David Lyons, Utility and Rights, 24 NOMOS 107, 111 (1982).
    • (1982) Rights without Stills , vol.107 , pp. 111
    • Lomsky, L.E.1
  • 90
    • 85022831399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A duty in distributive justice is agent-general in the sense that every member of society is required to comply with the demands of the just allocation. Scegrnemlly Colcman and Ripstein, Rethinking the Tlieory oJUgal Rights note 89 note 54, at
    • A duty in corrective justice is agent-specific because only the wrongdoer, and no other, is obliged to make good the losses one caused. A duty in distributive justice is agent-general in the sense that every member of society is required to comply with the demands of the just allocation. Scegrnemlly Colcman and Ripstein, Rethinking the Tlieory oJUgal Rights note 89 note 54, at 91.
    • A duty in corrective justice is agent-specific because only the wrongdoer, and no other, is obliged to make good the losses one caused. , pp. 91
  • 91
    • 0003411384 scopus 로고
    • THE NICHOMACHEAN ETHICS, book V, 293-302 (W.D. Ross trans., ).
    • Aristotle, THE NICHOMACHEAN ETHICS, book V, 293-302 (W.D. Ross trans., 1925).
    • (1925) Aristotle
  • 93
    • 0004153161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Coleman points out, only seldom do the losses of victim and the gain of the injurers overlap. note 49, at
    • Coleman, Risks and Wrongs, As Coleman points out, only seldom do the losses of victim and the gain of the injurers overlap. note 49, at 352.
    • Risks and Wrongs , pp. 352
    • Coleman1
  • 94
    • 85022874453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 95
    • 85022896408 scopus 로고
    • 78 VA. L. REV. 283,287 [hereinafter: Coleman, Intellectual Property].
    • Jules L. Coleman, IntellectualI'wjvrly and Correctivejustice, 78 VA. L. REV. 283,287 (1992) [hereinafter: Coleman, Intellectual Property].
    • (1992) IntellectualI'wjvrly and Correctivejustice
    • Coleman, J.L.1
  • 96
    • 85022785575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 97
    • 0004153161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. note 49, at 329-332. See flisojules L. Coleman, Tort Liability and tfie Umits of Corrective Justice, in IN HARMS WAY 139,141 (Jules L. Coleman & Allen Buchanan eels., ) [hereinafter. Coleman, Tort Liability].
    • Coleman, Risks and Wrongs, Id. note 49, at 329-332. See flisojules L. Coleman, Tort Liability and tfie Umits of Corrective Justice, in IN HARMS WAY 139,141 (Jules L. Coleman & Allen Buchanan eels., 1994) [hereinafter. Coleman, Tort Liability].
    • (1994) Risks and Wrongs
    • Coleman1
  • 99
    • 85022811715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tort Liability, Risks and Wrongs note 102, at
    • Id. See also Coleman, Tort Liability, Risks and Wrongs note 102, at 141.
    • Id. , pp. 141
    • Coleman1
  • 100
    • 85022754533 scopus 로고
    • Lake Erie Transportation Co., 109 Minn. 456, 124 N.W. 221 (1910). In this case the defendant left his ship moored at the plaintiffs dock during a nvewlay storm. As a result the ship was battered against the dock, causing $500 in damages. The Minnesota Supreme Court held that keeping the ship moored to the plaintiffs deck was reasonable under the circumstances, but nevertheless it granted compensation to the plaintiff because the defendant availed himself of the plaintiff property. But 5/r Ploof v. Puntam, 81 VL 471, 71 A. 188 (a dock owner whose sen-ant unmoored the plaintiffs ship during a storm was held liable for the damage that was caused to the ship and its passengers).
    • The classic case of private necessity is Vincent v. Lake Erie Transportation Co., 109 Minn. 456, 124 N.W. 221 (1910). In this case the defendant left his ship moored at the plaintiffs dock during a nvewlay storm. As a result the ship was battered against the dock, causing $500 in damages. The Minnesota Supreme Court held that keeping the ship moored to the plaintiffs deck was reasonable under the circumstances, but nevertheless it granted compensation to the plaintiff because the defendant availed himself of the plaintiff property. But 5/r Ploof v. Puntam, 81 VL 471, 71 A. 188 (1908) (a dock owner whose sen-ant unmoored the plaintiffs ship during a storm was held liable for the damage that was caused to the ship and its passengers).
    • (1908) The classic case of private necessity is Vincent v.
  • 101
    • 85022741633 scopus 로고
    • The classic case of private necessity is Vincent v. note 49, at 310-41. See fl&ojoel Feinberg, Voluntary Euthanasia and the Right to Life, 7 PHIL. PUB. AFF.
    • Coleman, Risks and Wrongs, The classic case of private necessity is Vincent v. note 49, at 310-41. See fl&ojoel Feinberg, Voluntary Euthanasia and the Right to Life, 7 PHIL. PUB. AFF. 93, 102 (1978).
    • (1978) Risks and Wrongs , vol.93 , pp. 102
    • Coleman1
  • 102
    • 85022809884 scopus 로고
    • 9 F. Cas. 342, 348 (C.C.D. Mass. 1841) (No. 4,901) citing Iiramwell v. Halcomb 3 My. 8c Cr. (Ch.)
    • Folsom, Risks and Wrongs, 9 F. Cas. 342, 348 (C.C.D. Mass. 1841) (No. 4,901) citing Iiramwell v. Halcomb 3 My. 8c Cr. (Ch.) 737 (1836).
    • (1836) Risks and Wrongs , pp. 737
    • Folsom1
  • 103
    • 85022855313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 13 HARV. J. L. & PUB. POLY 108, 118 (“Except in the rarest cases, we should treat intellectual property and physical property identically in the law-which is where the broader currents are taking us in a sweep no hull protection will stop”). For a comprehensive discussion of the similarities and the difference between intangible and real property, see Gordon, An Inquiry, Risks and Wrongs note
    • See, e.g., Frank H. Eastbrook, Intellectual Ihoperty Is Still Property, 13 HARV. J. L. & PUB. POLY 108, 118 (“Except in the rarest cases, we should treat intellectual property and physical property identically in the law-which is where the broader currents are taking us in a sweep no hull protection will stop”). For a comprehensive discussion of the similarities and the difference between intangible and real property, see Gordon, An Inquiry, Risks and Wrongs note 30.
    • Intellectual Ihoperty Is Still Property , pp. 30
    • Eastbrook, F.H.1
  • 105
    • 85022813945 scopus 로고
    • see generally Colcman, Risks and Wrongs, It is a longstanding principle of American constitutional law that taking of private property cannot serve private ends. note 49, at 361-429, and Coleman, Tort Liability, It is a longstanding principle of American constitutional law that taking of private property cannot serve private ends. note 102. Richard A. Epstein, Property and Necessity, 13 HARV.J. L. & Pun. POI/Y2
    • On the relation between corrective justice and tort law, see generally Colcman, Risks and Wrongs, It is a longstanding principle of American constitutional law that taking of private property cannot serve private ends. note 49, at 361-429, and Coleman, Tort Liability, It is a longstanding principle of American constitutional law that taking of private property cannot serve private ends. note 102. Richard A. Epstein, Property and Necessity, 13 HARV.J. L. & Pun. POI/Y2 (1990).
    • (1990) On the relation between corrective justice and tort law
  • 106
    • 85022895557 scopus 로고
    • (Ch.)
    • Russ (Ch.) 385, 390-91 (1826).
    • (1826) Russ , vol.385 , pp. 390-391
  • 109
    • 0004153161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Excuses are highly irrelevant to copyright infringement cases. note 49, at
    • Coleman, Risks and Wrongs, Excuses are highly irrelevant to copyright infringement cases. note 49, at 358.
    • Risks and Wrongs , pp. 358
    • Coleman1
  • 110
    • 85022867587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 358-59; Fisher, at 1681 n.100 and the sources cited therein.
    • Id. at 358-59; Fisher, Risks and Wrongs note 10, at 1681 n.100 and the sources cited therein.
    • Risks and Wrongs note 10
  • 111
    • 85022872695 scopus 로고
    • irf. at 359-60. Seealso Richard A. Epstein, 78 VA. L. REV. 85, 86 [hereinafter: Epstein, Custom and Law] (“All persons who gain from the use of the custom generally may lose from its application in a particular case. Therefore, when a dispute arises, the outcome effectively binds the litigant, who now has every incentive to deviate from it”).
    • Coleman, irf. at 359-60. Seealso Richard A. Epstein, International News Service u Associated Press: Custom and IMIO as Sources of Ihoperty Rights in Nexvs, 78 VA. L. REV. 85, 86 (1992) [hereinafter: Epstein, Custom and Law] (“All persons who gain from the use of the custom generally may lose from its application in a particular case. Therefore, when a dispute arises, the outcome effectively binds the litigant, who now has every incentive to deviate from it”).
    • (1992) International News Service u Associated Press: Custom and IMIO as Sources of Ihoperty Rights in Nexvs
    • Coleman1
  • 112
    • 85022882420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., U.S.C. § 1-102 (providing that the aim of the Code is “to permit the continued expansion of commercial practices through custom, usage and agreement of the parties”).
    • Customs and conventions play an important role in various areas of the law. See, e.g., U.S.C. § 1-102 (providing that the aim of the Code is “to permit the continued expansion of commercial practices through custom, usage and agreement of the parties”).
    • Customs and conventions play an important role in various areas of the law.
  • 113
    • 85022806334 scopus 로고
    • A dwarf standing on the shoulders of a giant can see farther than the giant” Zechariah Chafee, lie/lections on the IMW of Copyright, 45 COLUM. L. REV.
    • As Chafee pointed out “[t]he world goes ahead because each of us builds on the work of our predecessors. A dwarf standing on the shoulders of a giant can see farther than the giant” Zechariah Chafee, lie/lections on the IMW of Copyright, 45 COLUM. L. REV. 503,511 (1945).
    • (1945) As Chafee pointed out “[t]he world goes ahead because each of us builds on the work of our predecessors. , vol.503 , pp. 511
  • 115
    • 85022846815 scopus 로고
    • When there are only a few ways to effectively express an idea, the idea and its expression merge and no copyright protection attaches. See, e.g., Baker v. Selden, 101 U.S. 99 Morrisey v. Procter & Gamble Co., 379 F.2d675(lstCir. 1967).
    • This principle is known as the “merger doctrine”: When there are only a few ways to effectively express an idea, the idea and its expression merge and no copyright protection attaches. See, e.g., Baker v. Selden, 101 U.S. 99 (1879); Morrisey v. Procter & Gamble Co., 379 F.2d675(lstCir. 1967).
    • (1879) This principle is known as the “merger doctrine
  • 116
    • 85022741142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 260. But see Princeton University Press v. Michigan Document Service Inc., 99 F. 3d 1381 (6th Cir. 1996) (en bane) cert, denied 117 S. Ct. 1336 also Basic Books, Inc. v. Kinko's Graphic Corp., 758 F. Supp. 1522 (S.D.N.Y. 1991).
    • See Ellickson, This principle is known as the “merger doctrine” note 1, at 260. But see Princeton University Press v. Michigan Document Service Inc., 99 F. 3d 1381 (6th Cir. 1996) (en bane) cert, denied 117 S. Ct. 1336 (1997); also Basic Books, Inc. v. Kinko's Graphic Corp., 758 F. Supp. 1522 (S.D.N.Y. 1991).
    • (1997) This principle is known as the “merger doctrine” note 1
    • Ellickson1
  • 117
    • 84885973260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 510 U.S. at
    • Campbell, 510 U.S. at 584.
    • Campbell , pp. 584
  • 120
    • 85022809320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 464 U.S. at
    • Sony, 464 U.S. at 451.
    • Sony1
  • 124
    • 85022879653 scopus 로고
    • Instead, it provides that “no action may be brought under this title alleging infringement of copyright.* 17 U.S.C. § 1008. According to Goldstein the distinction between “exemption against infringement and a prohibition against suing for infringement”-although fine-has a “powerful symbolic effect for copyright owners.” Id. at
    • It is important to note that the act does not state that home audiotaping for private purposes is not a copyright infringement. Instead, it provides that “no action may be brought under this title alleging infringement of copyright.* 17 U.S.C. § 1008 (1994). According to Goldstein the distinction between “exemption against infringement and a prohibition against suing for infringement”-although fine-has a “powerful symbolic effect for copyright owners.” Id. at 163.
    • (1994) It is important to note that the act does not state that home audiotaping for private purposes is not a copyright infringement. , pp. 163
  • 126
    • 85022848621 scopus 로고
    • 471 U.S. at 550 (citing A. Latman, FAIR USE OF COPYRIGHTED WORKS 15 ).
    • Harper 6 s Row, 471 U.S. at 550 (citing A. Latman, FAIR USE OF COPYRIGHTED WORKS 15 (1958)).
    • (1958) Harper 6 s Row
  • 128
    • 85022745866 scopus 로고
    • 626 F.2d 1171 (5th Cir. ). But see Fisher, Id at593 note 10, at 1680 (arguing that if courts ought to look beyond positive law they will not be able to identify the relevant conventions and standards); and Leval, Id at593 note 2, at 1126 (arguing that there is no justification for considering morality as part of the fair use inquiry).
    • For another example of resort to industry practices see Triangle Publications v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, 626 F.2d 1171 (5th Cir. 1980). But see Fisher, Id at593 note 10, at 1680 (arguing that if courts ought to look beyond positive law they will not be able to identify the relevant conventions and standards); and Leval, Id at593 note 2, at 1126 (arguing that there is no justification for considering morality as part of the fair use inquiry).
    • (1980) For another example of resort to industry practices see Triangle Publications v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers
  • 129
    • 85022892537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For another example of resort to industry practices see Triangle Publications v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers note 116, at
    • Epstein, Custom and Law, For another example of resort to industry practices see Triangle Publications v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers note 116, at 97.
    • Custom and Law , pp. 97
    • Epstein1
  • 132
    • 85022807078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (1991). such uses may isolate the author's exclusive right to prepare derivative works based on the original copyrighted work. Ilene Knable Gotts & Alan D. Rutenberg, Navigating Oie Global Information Superhighway: A liumfry Road Ues Ahead, 8 IlARV. J. L. & TECH.
    • (1991). More specifically, such uses may isolate the author's exclusive right to prepare derivative works based on the original copyrighted work. Ilene Knable Gotts & Alan D. Rutenberg, Navigating Oie Global Information Superhighway: A liumfry Road Ues Ahead, 8 IlARV. J. L. & TECH. 275,318 (1996).
    • (1996) More specifically , vol.275 , pp. 318


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.