메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 45, Issue 3, 1991, Pages 343-368

German trade policy in Eastern Europe, 1890-1990: Preconditions for applying international trade leverage

(1)  Spaulding, Robert Mark a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84976156028     PISSN: 00208183     EISSN: 15315088     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0020818300033130     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (24)

References (75)
  • 1
    • 0004193947 scopus 로고
    • In this article, I use a means-oriented definition of “trade leverage” that emphasizes the use of merchandise trade flows as a means of pursuing nontrade related foreign policy goals. Of course, the conceptually less challenging use of trade policy as a means of influencing other states’ trade policies also constitutes trade leverage. terms “economic statecraft” and “economic diplomacy,” I also refer to “trade-based economic diplomacy” and use that term interchangeably with “trade leverage,” distinguishing where necessary between trade-based economic diplomacy and forms of diplomatic pressure with other bases, Princeton, N.J.; Princeton University Press
    • In this article, I use a means-oriented definition of “trade leverage” that emphasizes the use of merchandise trade flows as a means of pursuing nontrade related foreign policy goals. Of course, the conceptually less challenging use of trade policy as a means of influencing other states’ trade policies also constitutes trade leverage. Employing Baldwin'S terms “economic statecraft” and “economic diplomacy,” I also refer to “trade-based economic diplomacy” and use that term interchangeably with “trade leverage,” distinguishing where necessary between trade-based economic diplomacy and forms of diplomatic pressure with other bases. See David A. Baldwin, Economic Statecraft (Princeton, N.J.; Princeton University Press, 1985), pp. 35 and 39–40.
    • (1985) Economic Statecraft
    • Baldwin, D.A.1
  • 3
    • 84972392228 scopus 로고
    • Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games
    • Putnam has developed the concept of “two-level  games” to describe the dual frameworks in which policymakers of sovereign yet interdependent countries must respond to both domestic and international constraints and pressures, Summer
    • Putnam has developed the concept of “two-level  games” to describe the dual frameworks in which policymakers of sovereign yet interdependent countries must respond to both domestic and international constraints and pressures. See Robert Putnam, “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games,” International Organization 42 (Summer 1988), pp. 427–60.
    • (1988) International Organization , vol.42 , pp. 427-460
    • Putnam, R.1
  • 4
    • 84972234897 scopus 로고
    • International Economics and International Politics: A Framework for Analysis
    • Winter
    • See, for example, C. Fred Bergsten, Robert O. Keohane, and Joseph S. Nye, “International Economics and International Politics: A Framework for Analysis,” International Organization 29 (Winter 1975), pp. 3-36.
    • (1975) International Organization , vol.29 , pp. 3-36
    • Bergsten, C.F.1    Keohane, R.O.2    Nye, J.S.3
  • 6
    • 84976115240 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of International Trade
    • Spring
    • Benjamin J. Cohen, “The Political Economy of International Trade,” International Organization 44 (Spring 1990), pp. 261–81.
    • (1990) International Organization , vol.44 , pp. 261-281
    • Cohen, B.J.1
  • 7
    • 84928837664 scopus 로고
    • International Security Studies: A Report of a Conference on the State of the Field
    • As long as the “inadequacy of basic theoretical work” and the “lack of attention to history” remain two of the “major lacunae in the intellectual development” of security studies, historically based case studies with theoretical implications should be an especially valued type of contribution to the entire field of international relations
    • As long as the “inadequacy of basic theoretical work” and the “lack of attention to history” remain two of the “major lacunae in the intellectual development” of security studies, historically based case studies with theoretical implications should be an especially valued type of contribution to the entire field of international relations. See Joseph S. Nye, Jr., and Sean Lynn-Jones, “International Security Studies: A Report of a Conference on the State of the Field,” International Security 12 (Spring 1988), pp. 5–27.
    • (1988) International Security , vol.12 , pp. 5-27
    • Nye, J.S.1    Lynn-Jones, S.2
  • 8
    • 84976002021 scopus 로고
    • See Kaiserliches statistisches Amt, Statistics of the German Reich, new series, Berlin: Puttkammer und Mühlbrecht, The volume also contains a useful commentary on the deficiencies of Russian trade statistics prior to 1914.
    • See Kaiserliches statistisches Amt, Statistik des deutschen Reiches (Statistics of the German Reich), new series, vol. 271, part 5 (Berlin: Puttkammer und Mühlbrecht, 1914), pp. 1–2. The volume also contains a useful commentary on the deficiencies of Russian trade statistics prior to 1914.
    • (1914) Statistik des deutschen Reiches , vol.271 , pp. 1-2
  • 9
    • 84975987774 scopus 로고
    • In 1929, German exports to Poland were 339 million marks, or 2.5 percent of total German exports (13,482 million); imports from Poland were 343 million marks, or 2.6 percent of total German imports (13,434 million), Monthly record of German foreign trade—Supplement: German foreign trade by continent and country, 1929, Berlin: Reimar und Hobing
    • In 1929, German exports to Poland were 339 million marks, or 2.5 percent of total German exports (13,482 million); imports from Poland were 343 million marks, or 2.6 percent of total German imports (13,434 million). See Statistisches Reichsamt, Monatliche Nachweise über den Aussenhandel Deutschlands—Ergänzungsheft: Der deutsche Aussenhandel nach Erdteilen und Landem, 1929 (Monthly record of German foreign trade—Supplement: German foreign trade by continent and country, 1929) (Berlin: Reimar und Hobing, 1930), p. 5.
    • (1930) Monatliche Nachweise über den Aussenhandel Deutschlands—Ergänzungsheft: Der deutsche Aussenhandel nach Erdteilen und Landem, 1929 , pp. 5
    • Reichsamt, S.1
  • 10
    • 0004248181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the other side, Polish exports to Germany were 877 million zloty, or 31 percent of total Polish exports (2,813 million); imports from Germany were 850 million zloty, or 27 percent of total Polish imports (3,111 million), New York: Macmillan
    • On the other side, Polish exports to Germany were 877 million zloty, or 31 percent of total Polish exports (2,813 million); imports from Germany were 850 million zloty, or 27 percent of total Polish imports (3,111 million). See B. R. Mitchell, European Historical Statistics, 1750–1970 (New York: Macmillan, 1975), pp. 496 and 547.
    • (1975) European Historical Statistics, 1750–1970 , pp. 496-547
    • Mitchell, B.R.1
  • 11
    • 0004248181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In 1929, Czechoslovak exports to Germany were 4,691 million koruna (with total Czechoslovak exports equal to 20,499 million); imports from Germany were 7,675 million koruna (with total imports equal to 19,998 million)
    • In 1929, Czechoslovak exports to Germany were 4,691 million koruna (with total Czechoslovak exports equal to 20,499 million); imports from Germany were 7,675 million koruna (with total imports equal to 19,998 million). See Mitchell, European Historical Statistics, pp. 493 and 513.
    • European Historical Statistics , pp. 493-513
    • Mitchell1
  • 12
    • 84975948451 scopus 로고
    • German exports to Czechoslovakia were 658 million marks; imports from Czechoslovakia were 480 million marks
    • German exports to Czechoslovakia were 658 million marks; imports from Czechoslovakia were 480 million marks. See Statistisches Reichsamt, Monatliche Nachweise—Ergänzungsheft: 1929, p. 5.
    • (1929) Monatliche Nachweise—Ergänzungsheft , pp. 5
    • Reichsamt, S.1
  • 13
    • 0003674988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Weimar Republic'S economic potential for applying trade leverage is captured, “index of preference for [trade with] small countries. By this measure, Germany under the Weimar regime concentrated its trade on smaller countries to a greater degree than did either Britain or France. In 1925, this index of concentration stood at 126 for German imports and 158 for German exports, well above both Britain (111 for imports and 114 for exports) and France (93 and 93), Berkeley: University of California Press, Table 1
    • The Weimar Republic'S economic potential for applying trade leverage is captured in Hirschman'S “index of preference for [trade with] small countries.” By this measure, Germany under the Weimar regime concentrated its trade on smaller countries to a greater degree than did either Britain or France. In 1925, this index of concentration stood at 126 for German imports and 158 for German exports, well above both Britain (111 for imports and 114 for exports) and France (93 and 93). See Albert O. Hirschman, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980), Table 1, pp. 92–93.
    • (1980) National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade , pp. 92-93
    • Hirschman, A.O.1
  • 14
    • 84976175924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Economics and International Politics
    • The international trade regime can be defined as the web of “institutions, fundamental assumptions, and rules of the game” governing trade practices and trade relations between states, according to Bergsten, Keohane, and Nye in “International Economics and International Politics,” p. 5.
    • Bergsten1    Keohane2    Nye3
  • 15
    • 0009238734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Transformation of Trade: The Sources and Effects of Regime Changes
    • refers to “rules, norms, principles, procedures, [and] expectations” when discussing trade regimes in, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, See also Krasner'S own contributions in the same volume.
    • Charles Lipson refers to “rules, norms, principles, procedures, [and] expectations” when discussing trade regimes in “The Transformation of Trade: The Sources and Effects of Regime Changes,” in Stephen Krasner, ed., International Regimes (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983), pp. 233–71. See also Krasner'S own contributions in the same volume.
    • (1983) International Regimes , pp. 233-271
    • Lipson, C.1    Krasner, S.2
  • 16
    • 84911088274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of International Trade
    • While Lipson, Krasner, and others have turned their attention in part to the question of how international regimes are constructed, this study takes the international trade regime as exogenous and offers explanations of how existing regimes influence national trade policies. For a discussion of the benefits and drawbacks of “upward-looking” and “downward-looking” analyses of system management
    • While Lipson, Krasner, and others have turned their attention in part to the question of how international regimes are constructed, this study takes the international trade regime as exogenous and offers explanations of how existing regimes influence national trade policies. For a discussion of the benefits and drawbacks of “upward-looking” and “downward-looking” analyses of system management, see Cohen, “The Political Economy of International Trade.”
    • Cohen1
  • 17
    • 84967541820 scopus 로고
    • Despite recent challenges to the hegemonic model, it continues to dominate explanations of economic regime change and stability. See, for example, Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Despite recent challenges to the hegemonic model, it continues to dominate explanations of economic regime change and stability. See, for example, Charles Kindleberger, The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1974).
    • (1974) The World in Depression, 1929–1939
    • Kindleberger, C.1
  • 18
    • 0010198898 scopus 로고
    • Introduction: Domestic and International Forces and Strategies of Foreign Economic Policy
    • Madison: University of of Wisconsin Press
    • Peter Katzenstein, “Introduction: Domestic and International Forces and Strategies of Foreign Economic Policy,” in Peter Katzenstein, ed., Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States (Madison: University of of Wisconsin Press, 1978), pp. 3-22.
    • (1978) Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States , pp. 3-22
    • Katzenstein, P.1
  • 19
    • 0038946242 scopus 로고
    • Economic Interdependence and National Security in Historical Perspective
    • Lawrence: Regents Press of Kansas
    • Robert Gilpin, “Economic Interdependence and National Security in Historical Perspective,” in Klaus Knorr and Frank Trager, eds., Economic Issues and National Security (Lawrence: Regents Press of Kansas, 1977), pp. 19–66.
    • (1977) Economic Issues and National Security , pp. 19-66
    • Gilpin, R.1    Knorr, K.2
  • 21
    • 84972091498 scopus 로고
    • State Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade
    • April
    • Stephen Krasner, “State Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade,” World Politics 28 (April 1976), pp. 317-47.
    • (1976) World Politics , vol.28 , pp. 317-347
    • Krasner, S.1
  • 23
    • 84974081599 scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory
    • Autumn
    • Duncan Snidal, “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory,” International Organization 39 (Autumn 1985), pp. 579–614.
    • (1985) International Organization , vol.39 , pp. 579-614
    • Snidal, D.1
  • 24
    • 84974189030 scopus 로고
    • Theories of International Regimes
    • For a critical review of the structural, game-theoretic, functional, and cognitive approaches to regime analysis,Summer
    • For a critical review of the structural, game-theoretic, functional, and cognitive approaches to regime analysis, see Stephan Haggard and Beth A. Simmons, “Theories of International Regimes,” International Organization 41 (Summer 1987), pp. 491–517.
    • (1987) International Organization , vol.41 , pp. 491-517
    • Haggard, S.1    Simmons, B.A.2
  • 25
    • 0009902543 scopus 로고
    • The Internationalization of History
    • For thoughts on how an international economic regime corresponds to the international political power system in a given period, February
    • For thoughts on how an international economic regime corresponds to the international political power system in a given period, see Akira Irye, “The Internationalization of History,” American Historical Review 94 (February 1989), pp. 1–10.
    • (1989) American Historical Review , vol.94 , pp. 1-10
    • Irye, A.1
  • 26
    • 0009238734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Transformation of Trade
    • Lipson, “The Transformation of Trade,” p. 241.
    • Lipson1
  • 27
    • 6244272130 scopus 로고
    • Domestic factors such as the late unification, the federal structure of the Reich, and the almost exclusively aristocratic character of the upper levels of the civil service also played important roles in the noteworthy underdevelopment of the central Reich bureaucracy before 1914, Economy and state: The development of state economic administration in Germany from the 17th century to 1945) (Boppard: Harald Verlag
    • Domestic factors such as the late unification, the federal structure of the Reich, and the almost exclusively aristocratic character of the upper levels of the civil service also played important roles in the noteworthy underdevelopment of the central Reich bureaucracy before 1914. See Friedrich Facius, Wirtschaft und Staat: Die Entwicklung der staatlichen Wirtschaftsverwaltung in Deutschland vom 17. Jahrhundert bis 1945 (Economy and state: The development of state economic administration in Germany from the 17th century to 1945) (Boppard: Harald Verlag, 1959).
    • (1959) Wirtschaft und Staat: Die Entwicklung der staatlichen Wirtschaftsverwaltung in Deutschland vom 17. Jahrhundert bis 1945
    • Facius, F.1
  • 28
    • 84975948409 scopus 로고
    • of A History of East-Central Europe (Seattle: University of Washington Press
    • Joseph Rothschild, East-Central Europe Between the Wars, vol. 9 of A History of East-Central Europe (Seattle: University of Washington Press, 1974), p. 22.
    • (1974) East-Central Europe Between the Wars , vol.9 , pp. 22
    • Rothschild, J.1
  • 30
    • 0004956125 scopus 로고
    • One line of this thinking culminates in the questions surrounding the costs and benefits of conquest versus trade. An early discussion of this issue can be found in Benjamin Constant'S De l’esprit de conquête et de l’usurpation dans leurs rapports avec la civilisation europeenne, part 1, chap. 2, as cited in Hirschman, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade, p. 14, For more recent thoughts on this question, Oxford: Clarendon Press, especially chap. 1
    • One line of this thinking culminates in the questions surrounding the costs and benefits of conquest versus trade. An early discussion of this issue can be found in Benjamin Constant'S De l’esprit de conquête et de l’usurpation dans leurs rapports avec la civilisation europeenne, part 1, chap. 2, as cited in Hirschman, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade, p. 14. For more recent thoughts on this question, see Alan Milward, The New Order and the French Economy (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1970), especially chap. 1.
    • (1970) The New Order and the French Economy
    • Milward, A.1
  • 32
    • 84975953690 scopus 로고
    • separatist
    • view was not unique to Bismarck; it can be traced back through the first U.S. president at least to Machiavelli. In his farewell address, Washington declared that “the great rule of conduct for us, in regard to foreign nations, is, in extending our commercial relations, to have with them as little political connection as possible.” Machiavelli offered the following argument: “Fortune has decreed that as I do not know how to reason … about profits and losses, it befits me to reason about the state.” For further discussion, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • This “separatist” view was not unique to Bismarck; it can be traced back through the first U.S. president at least to Machiavelli. In his farewell address, Washington declared that “the great rule of conduct for us, in regard to foreign nations, is, in extending our commercial relations, to have with them as little political connection as possible.” Machiavelli offered the following argument: “Fortune has decreed that as I do not know how to reason … about profits and losses, it befits me to reason about the state.” For further discussion, see Felix Gilbert, To the Farewell Address: Ideas in Early American Foreign Policy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1961).
    • (1961) To the Farewell Address: Ideas in Early American Foreign Policy
    • Gilbert, F.1
  • 35
    • 84975953696 scopus 로고
    • foreign, and in particular export trade… as an end in itself and not as a means to political penetration and economic subjugation
    • Hirschman notes that before 1914 even those contemporary scholars who warned specifically about the dangerous growth of German exports—such as, author of, London: Heinemann
    • Hirschman notes that before 1914 even those contemporary scholars who warned specifically about the dangerous growth of German exports—such as E. E. Williams, author of Made in Germany (London: Heinemann, 1896)—saw “foreign, and in particular export trade… as an end in itself and not as a means to political penetration and economic subjugation.”
    • (1896) Made in Germany
    • Williams, E.E.1
  • 36
    • 84976146671 scopus 로고
    • Stenographic report of the German Reichstag, 27 February, Assessing the success of Caprivi'S reversal of Bismarckian practice is complicated by the asymmetry between Caprivi'S use of trade treaties as foreign policy incentives (“carrots”) and Bismarck'S policy of withholding treaties as disincentives (“sticks”).
    • See Stenographische Berichte des deutschen Reichstages (Stenographic report of the German Reichstag), 27 February 1894, p. 1451. Assessing the success of Caprivi'S reversal of Bismarckian practice is complicated by the asymmetry between Caprivi'S use of trade treaties as foreign policy incentives (“carrots”) and Bismarck'S policy of withholding treaties as disincentives (“sticks”).
    • (1894) Stenographische Berichte des deutschen Reichstages , pp. 1451
  • 37
    • 84975995172 scopus 로고
    • speech to the Central Committee of the Deutsche Volkspartei, 22 November
    • Stresemann, speech to the Central Committee of the Deutsche Volkspartei, 22 November 1925.
    • (1925)
    • Stresemann1
  • 38
    • 84975995164 scopus 로고
    • Hans Posse, the influential undersecretary in the Economics Ministry, privately arrived at the same conclusions, as indicated in his unpublished manuscript of 1924–25, “Denkschrift zur Politik der Regierung” (Memorandum on government policy), Bundesarchiv Koblenz, Nachlass Posse/2.
    • reprinted by Henry Turner in Vierteljahrshefte fur Zeitgeschichte 15 (October 1967), pp. 412–36. Hans Posse, the influential undersecretary in the Economics Ministry, privately arrived at the same conclusions, as indicated in his unpublished manuscript of 1924–25, “Denkschrift zur Politik der Regierung” (Memorandum on government policy), Bundesarchiv Koblenz, Nachlass Posse/2.
    • (1967) Vierteljahrshefte fur Zeitgeschichte , pp. 412-436
    • Turner, H.1
  • 39
    • 84924121284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Domestic Constraints on International Economic Leverage
    • An early exploration of these issues can be found, Knorr and Trager
    • An early exploration of these issues can be found in Stephen Krasner'S “Domestic Constraints on International Economic Leverage,” in Knorr and Trager, Economic Issues and National Security, pp. 160–81.
    • Economic Issues and National Security , pp. 160-181
    • Krasner, S.1
  • 40
    • 0008362659 scopus 로고
    • Structural Constraints on Economic Leverage: Market-Type Systems
    • Gilpin touches on this issue in a discussion of the costs of negative economic sanctions, New York: Praeger
    • Gilpin touches on this issue in a discussion of the costs of negative economic sanctions. See Robert Gilpin, “Structural Constraints on Economic Leverage: Market-Type Systems,” in Gordon H. McCormick and Richard Bissel, eds., Strategic Dimensions of Economic Behavior (New York: Praeger, 1984), pp. 105–28.
    • (1984) Strategic Dimensions of Economic Behavior , pp. 105-128
    • Gilpin, R.1    McCormick, G.H.2    Bissel, R.3
  • 45
    • 84926359637 scopus 로고
    • Still the Century of Corporatism?
    • On social corporatism, January
    • On social corporatism, see Phillippe Schmitter, “Still the Century of Corporatism?” Review of Politics 36 (January 1974), pp. 85–131.
    • (1974) Review of Politics , vol.36 , pp. 85-131
    • Schmitter, P.1
  • 46
    • 0012578276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For recent Marxist theory, New York: Oxford University Press
    • For recent Marxist theory, see Ralph Miliband, Marxism and Politics (New York: Oxford University Press, 1977).
    • Marxism and Politics
    • Miliband, R.1
  • 48
    • 0004084605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • coalition-based interpretation of foreign economic policy has been a valuable recent addition to societal actor explanations, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • Gourevitch'S coalition-based interpretation of foreign economic policy has been a valuable recent addition to societal actor explanations. See Peter Gourevitch, Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986).
    • (1986) Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises
    • Gourevitch, P.1
  • 49
    • 0004181643 scopus 로고
    • Liberal and Marxist theorists of democracy deny that the state has the ability to act autonomously from society. Even when expanded to include the role played by the “intermediate agents” (the interest groups and political parties) of private economic actors, the liberal and Marxist frameworks still do not allow a role for the state in which state agents themselves habitually act as autonomous forces in the process of formulating policy, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
    • Liberal and Marxist theorists of democracy deny that the state has the ability to act autonomously from society. Even when expanded to include the role played by the “intermediate agents” (the interest groups and political parties) of private economic actors, the liberal and Marxist frameworks still do not allow a role for the state in which state agents themselves habitually act as autonomous forces in the process of formulating policy. See Eric Nordlinger, On the Autonomy of the Democratic State (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1981).
    • (1981) On the Autonomy of the Democratic State
    • Nordlinger, E.1
  • 50
    • 0022834874 scopus 로고
    • The Autonomous Power of the State: Its Origins, Mechanisms, and Results
    • New York: Basil Blackwell
    • Michael Mann, “The Autonomous Power of the State: Its Origins, Mechanisms, and Results,” in John A. Hall, ed., States in History (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1987), pp. 109–36.
    • (1987) States in History , pp. 109-136
    • Mann, M.1    Hall, J.A.2
  • 51
    • 0041004922 scopus 로고
    • The literature on state-society relations, particularly on the role of private sector interest groups (Verbände), in these four German regimes is voluminous. For good coverage of the entire period, German administrative history, Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlagsanstalt
    • The literature on state-society relations, particularly on the role of private sector interest groups (Verbände), in these four German regimes is voluminous. For good coverage of the entire period, see Kurt Jeserich et al., Deutsche Verwaltungsgeschichte (German administrative history), vols. 3–5 (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlagsanstalt, 1983–88).
    • (1983) Deutsche Verwaltungsgeschichte , vol.3-5
    • Jeserich, K.1
  • 52
    • 84925037340 scopus 로고
    • Interessenverbände und Parteien in Deutschland vor dem ersten Weltkrieg
    • For valuable individual studies, Interest groups and parties in Germany before the First World War, September
    • For valuable individual studies, see Thomas Nipperdey, “Interessenverbände und Parteien in Deutschland vor dem ersten Weltkrieg” (Interest groups and parties in Germany before the First World War), Politische Vierteljahresschrift 2 (September 1961), pp. 262-80.
    • (1961) Politische Vierteljahresschrift , vol.2 , pp. 262-280
    • Nipperdey, T.1
  • 53
    • 77958462621 scopus 로고
    • Parlament, Parteien, und Interessenverbände, 1890–1914
    • Parliament, parties, and interest groups, 1890–1914), in M. Stürmer, Imperial Germany) (Dusseldorf: Droste
    • H.-J. Pühle, “Parlament, Parteien, und Interessenverbände, 1890–1914” (Parliament, parties, and interest groups, 1890–1914), in M. Stürmer, ed., Das kaiserliche Deutschland (Imperial Germany) (Dusseldorf: Droste, 1970), pp. 340-77.
    • (1970) Das kaiserliche Deutschland , pp. 340-377
    • Pühle, H.-J.1
  • 55
    • 60949972734 scopus 로고
    • The Primacy of Politics: Politics and Economics in National Socialist Germany
    • New York: New Viewpoints
    • T. W. Mason, “The Primacy of Politics: Politics and Economics in National Socialist Germany,” in H. A. Turner, ed., Nazism and the Third Reich (New York: New Viewpoints, 1972), pp. 175-200.
    • (1972) Nazism and the Third Reich , pp. 175-200
    • Mason, T.W.1    Turner, H.A.2
  • 57
    • 30244462513 scopus 로고
    • Dominion of the interest groups?) (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlagsanstalt
    • Theodor Eschenburg, Herrschaft der Verbände? (Dominion of the interest groups?) (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlagsanstalt, 1955).
    • (1955) Herrschaft der Verbände?
    • Eschenburg, T.1
  • 59
    • 0004094597 scopus 로고
    • For an illustrated notion of “nonexistent, weak, moderate, strong, and dominant” levels of state power, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • For an illustrated notion of “nonexistent, weak, moderate, strong, and dominant” levels of state power, see Stephen D. Krasner, Defending the National Interest: Raw Materials Investments and U.S. Foreign Policy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978), p. 57.
    • (1978) Defending the National Interest: Raw Materials Investments and U.S. Foreign Policy , pp. 57
    • Krasner, S.D.1
  • 62
    • 84976002606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geschichte des Vereins deutscher Eisen- und Stahlindustrieller, 1874–1934
    • On the frustrations of two leading interest groups, the Central Association of German Industrialists and the Union of German Iron and Steel Industrialists, see the Union'S own unpublished history, History of the Union of German Iron and Steel Industrialists), Bundesarchiv Koblenz, Union of German Iron and Steel Industrialists (R 13 I), files 12 and 13.
    • On the frustrations of two leading interest groups, the Central Association of German Industrialists and the Union of German Iron and Steel Industrialists, see the Union'S own unpublished history by C. Klein, “Geschichte des Vereins deutscher Eisen- und Stahlindustrieller, 1874–1934” (History of the Union of German Iron and Steel Industrialists), Bundesarchiv Koblenz, Union of German Iron and Steel Industrialists (R 13 I), files 12 and 13.
    • Klein, C.1
  • 63
    • 0004349315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Diplomacy and Domestic Politics
    • The U.S. Congress granted the executive branch similar powers in the Trade Expansion Act of 1974 and in the “fast  track” legislation for the Uruguay Round of GATT negotiations. In exchange for diminished legislative control, Congress established a network of private sector committees to communicate directly with U.S. negotiators before and during treaty negotiations. In the case of Imperial Germany'S system, however, there were no analogous networks. For a detailed discussion of ratification procedures and international negotiations
    • The U.S. Congress granted the executive branch similar powers in the Trade Expansion Act of 1974 and in the “fast  track” legislation for the Uruguay Round of GATT negotiations. In exchange for diminished legislative control, Congress established a network of private sector committees to communicate directly with U.S. negotiators before and during treaty negotiations. In the case of Imperial Germany'S system, however, there were no analogous networks. For a detailed discussion of ratification procedures and international negotiations, see Putnam, “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics.”
    • Putnam1
  • 65
    • 84975995138 scopus 로고
    • Economic crisis and foreign trade) (Berlin: Deutschen Hochschule für Politik
    • Ernst Trendelenburg, Weltwirtschaftskrise und Aussenhandel (Economic crisis and foreign trade) (Berlin: Deutschen Hochschule für Politik, 1921).
    • (1921) Weltwirtschaftskrise und Aussenhandel
    • Trendelenburg, E.1
  • 66
    • 84976114604 scopus 로고
    • Bonn Maps Controls on Arms Exports
    • The Federal Republic currently employs over 200 trained professionals in the upper level of its principle export control agency and 2,350 “export controllers” in its customs service, 16 February
    • The Federal Republic currently employs over 200 trained professionals in the upper level of its principle export control agency and 2,350 “export controllers” in its customs service. See “Bonn Maps Controls on Arms Exports,” Boston Globe, 16 February 1989, p. 6.
    • (1989) Boston Globe , pp. 6
  • 67
    • 84975997524 scopus 로고
    • Bonn verschärft Exportkontrollen
    • Bonn sharpens export controls, 8 February
    • “Bonn verschärft Exportkontrollen” (Bonn sharpens export controls), Deutschland Nachrichten, 8 February 1991, P.1.
    • (1991) Deutschland Nachrichten , pp. 1
  • 69
    • 0003703636 scopus 로고
    • David Kaiser explained how changes in the international trade regime after 1931 allowed for the German penetration of Eastern Europe. However, in view of the agricultural obstructionism that plagued the Weimar regime, any explanation of Nazi success must also include an account of the policies and developments that solved the problems of domestic opposition. One of the best treatments of Nazi economic activity in the Balkans can be found, Bloomington: Indiana University Press
    • David Kaiser explained how changes in the international trade regime after 1931 allowed for the German penetration of Eastern Europe. However, in view of the agricultural obstructionism that plagued the Weimar regime, any explanation of Nazi success must also include an account of the policies and developments that solved the problems of domestic opposition. One of the best treatments of Nazi economic activity in the Balkans can be found in John R. Lampe and Marvin R. Jackson'S Balkan Economic History, 1550-1950: From Imperial Borderlands to Developing Nations (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1982).
    • (1982) Balkan Economic History, 1550-1950: From Imperial Borderlands to Developing Nations
    • Lampe, J.R.1    Jackson, M.R.2
  • 70
    • 84863326005 scopus 로고
    • For a study that views Nazi economic expansion as serving capitalism as much as the state, London: Cambridge University Press
    • For a study that views Nazi economic expansion as serving capitalism as much as the state, see Alice Teichova, An Economic Background to Munich (London: Cambridge University Press, 1974).
    • (1974) An Economic Background to Munich
    • Teichova, A.1
  • 72
    • 84976146653 scopus 로고
    • The Hitler-Stalin pact, 1939-1941: A contribution to the method of Soviet foreign policy) (Darmstadt: Fundus Verlag
    • Philipp Fabry, Der Hitler-Stalin Pakt, 1939-1941: Ein Beitrag zur Methode sowjetischer Aussenpolitik (The Hitler-Stalin pact, 1939-1941: A contribution to the method of Soviet foreign policy) (Darmstadt: Fundus Verlag, 1962), pp. 190–94.
    • (1962) Der Hitler-Stalin Pakt, 1939-1941: Ein Beitrag zur Methode sowjetischer Aussenpolitik , pp. 190-194
    • Fabry, P.1
  • 73
    • 84975931295 scopus 로고
    • Genscher: Rasche Hilfe für Polen
    • Genscher: Quick aid for Poland, 10 May
    • See “Genscher: Rasche Hilfe für Polen” (Genscher: Quick aid for Poland), Deutschland Nachrichten, 10 May 1989, p. 2.
    • (1989) Deutschland Nachrichten , pp. 2
  • 74
    • 84976158633 scopus 로고
    • Genscher: Rasche Hilfe für Polen
    • We should also recall the detente version of this reform-seeking use of commercial policy, which was summarized in the Social Democrats’ slogan, change through rapprochement, both the United States and the West European nations sought to expose Eastern societies to the “Western life-style” and the productive powers of the West by exposing them to Western products. In this way, they hoped to encourage Eastern regimes and elites to recognize the need for greater concern to their own consumers and to soften their domestic structures.
    • See “Genscher: Rasche Hilfe für Polen.” We should also recall the detente version of this reform-seeking use of commercial policy, which was summarized in the Social Democrats’ slogan “Wandel durch Annäherung” (change through rapprochement). After 1970, both the United States and the West European nations sought to expose Eastern societies to the “Western life-style” and the productive powers of the West by exposing them to Western products. In this way, they hoped to encourage Eastern regimes and elites to recognize the need for greater concern to their own consumers and to soften their domestic structures.
    • (1970) Wandel durch Annäherung
  • 75
    • 84976186592 scopus 로고
    • Deutsche und EG-Hilfsmassnahmen für Polen und Ungarn
    • German and EC aid measures for Poland and Hungary, 28 September
    • See “Deutsche und EG-Hilfsmassnahmen für Polen und Ungarn” (German and EC aid measures for Poland and Hungary), Deutschland Nachrichten, 28 September 1989, p. 2.
    • (1989) Deutschland Nachrichten , pp. 2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.