메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 45, Issue 4, 1991, Pages 495-538

Why are some international agreements informal?

(1)  Lipson, Charles a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84976128766     PISSN: 00208183     EISSN: 15315088     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0020818300033191     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (358)

References (144)
  • 2
    • 0038176829 scopus 로고
    • (London: Routledge), Kenen reproduces key portions of the Plaza Communique (22 September 1985) and the Louvre Accord (22 February 1987) on
    • Peter B. Kenen, Managing Exchange Rates (London: Routledge, 1988). Kenen reproduces key portions of the Plaza Communique (22 September 1985) and the Louvre Accord (22 February 1987) on p. 50.
    • (1988) Managing Exchange Rates , pp. 50
    • Kenen, P.B.1
  • 6
    • 0007646442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, In 1972, as the strategic arms limitation talks (SALT I) were concluded, Nixon and Brezhnev signed the Basic Principles Agreement. It sought to specify some key elements of the superpowers’ relationship and thereby facilitate the development of detente. The product was vague and ambiguous. Worse, it seemed to indicate—wrongly—U.S. agreement with the Soviet position on peaceful coexistence and competition in other regions. Alexander George calls these elements “a pseudoagreement.” For the text of the agreement, see Department of State Bulletin, 26 June 1972
    • See Paul Keal, Unspoken Rules and Superpower Dominance (London: Macmillan, 1983). Some diplomatic efforts were made to articulate the rules, but they did little in themselves to clarify expectations. In 1972, as the strategic arms limitation talks (SALT I) were concluded, Nixon and Brezhnev signed the Basic Principles Agreement. It sought to specify some key elements of the superpowers’ relationship and thereby facilitate the development of detente. The product was vague and ambiguous. Worse, it seemed to indicate—wrongly—U.S. agreement with the Soviet position on peaceful coexistence and competition in other regions. Alexander George calls these elements “a pseudoagreement.” For the text of the agreement, see Department of State Bulletin, 26 June 1972, pp. 898-99.
    • (1983) Unspoken Rules and Superpower Dominance , pp. 898-899
    • Keal, P.1
  • 7
    • 0010715121 scopus 로고
    • The Basic Principles Agreement of 1972
    • For an analysis, see, in Alexander L. George, ed., (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press)
    • For an analysis, see Alexander George, “The Basic Principles Agreement of 1972,” in Alexander L. George, ed., Managing U.S.-Soviet Rivalry: Problems of Crisis Prevention (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1983), pp. 107-18.
    • (1983) Managing U.S.-Soviet Rivalry: Problems of Crisis Prevention , pp. 107-118
    • George, A.1
  • 8
    • 84976080198 scopus 로고
    • The State Department announced its position in a brief public statement on 4 March 1981. The administration continued to debate its arms control policy, and Reagan continued to criticize Carter's SALT II agreement. In early May 1982, he told a press conference that the agreement “simply legitimizes an arms race” and added that “now the parts [of the agreement] that we’re observing… have to do with the monitoring of each other's weaponry, and so both sides are doing that.” In late May 1982, on the eve of the strategic arms reduction talks (START), Reagan finally stated that the United States “would not undercut” the SALT II agreement. He continued to criticize it, however, and left uncertain which portions of the agreement the United States would observe. See the Department of State announcement of 4 March 1981, cited by, in, (New York: Vintage Books)
    • The State Department announced its position in a brief public statement on 4 March 1981. The administration continued to debate its arms control policy, and Reagan continued to criticize Carter's SALT II agreement. In early May 1982, he told a press conference that the agreement “simply legitimizes an arms race” and added that “now the parts [of the agreement] that we’re observing… have to do with the monitoring of each other's weaponry, and so both sides are doing that.” In late May 1982, on the eve of the strategic arms reduction talks (START), Reagan finally stated that the United States “would not undercut” the SALT II agreement. He continued to criticize it, however, and left uncertain which portions of the agreement the United States would observe. See the Department of State announcement of 4 March 1981, cited by Strobe Talbott in Deadly Gambits: The Reagan Administration and the Stalemate in Nuclear Arms Control (New York: Vintage Books, 1985), p. 225.
    • (1985) Deadly Gambits: The Reagan Administration and the Stalemate in Nuclear Arms Control , pp. 225
    • Talbott, S.1
  • 9
    • 84975969327 scopus 로고
    • The President's press conference statement of 13 May 1982, quoted in, 17 May
    • The President's press conference statement of 13 May 1982, quoted in Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents, vol. 18, no. 19, 17 May 1982, p. 635.
    • (1982) Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents , vol.18 , Issue.19 , pp. 635
  • 10
    • 84976081490 scopus 로고
    • The President's, delivered on 31 May 1982 and included in, book 1 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office)
    • The President's “Remarks at Memorial Day Ceremonies at Arlington National Cemetery,” delivered on 31 May 1982 and included in Public Papers of the President of the United States: Ronald Reagan, 1982, book 1 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1983), p. 709.
    • (1983) Public Papers of the President of the United States: Ronald Reagan, 1982 , pp. 709
  • 11
    • 84976149931 scopus 로고
    • In 1984, in a confidential report to Congress, President Reagan cited in detail Soviet noncompliance with numerous arms control agreements. Reagan's accompanying message stated that “violations and probable violations have occurred with respect to a number of Soviet legal obligations and political commitments in the arms control field.” SALT II violations were included, and the reference to “political commitments” alludes to them. These criticisms were expanded in another report, issued in 1985. The Soviets rejected these charges and made counterclaims regarding U.S. violations. Relevant documents are cited by, in, (Dordrecht, Netherlands: Martinus Nijhoff)
    • In 1984, in a confidential report to Congress, President Reagan cited in detail Soviet noncompliance with numerous arms control agreements. Reagan's accompanying message stated that “violations and probable violations have occurred with respect to a number of Soviet legal obligations and political commitments in the arms control field.” SALT II violations were included, and the reference to “political commitments” alludes to them. These criticisms were expanded in another report, issued in 1985. The Soviets rejected these charges and made counterclaims regarding U.S. violations. Relevant documents are cited by Notburga K. Calvo-Goller and Michael A. Calvo in The SALT Agreements: Content-Application-Verification (Dordrecht, Netherlands: Martinus Nijhoff, 1987), pp. 318 and 326 ff.
    • (1987) The SALT Agreements: Content-Application-Verification
    • Calvo-Goller, N.K.1    Calvo, M.A.2
  • 12
    • 84925608633 scopus 로고
    • President Reagan did restate the U.S. commitment not to undercut SALT II in June 1985, some six months before the unratified treaty would have expired. U.S. policy, however, was always contingent on reciprocal Soviet adherence. On that point, Reagan was sharply critical: “The United States has not taken any actions which would undercut existing arms control agreements. The United States has fully kept its part of the bargain; however, the Soviets have not…. Certain Soviet violations are, by their very nature, irreversible. Such is the case with respect to the Soviet Union's flight-testing and steps toward deployment of the SS-X-25 missile, a second new type of ICBM [intercontinental ballistic missile] prohibited by the unratified SALT II agreement. Since the noncompliance associated with the development of this missile cannot be corrected by the Soviet Union, the United States reserves the right to respond in a proportionate manner at the appropriate time.” See the President's statement of 10 June 1985, quoted in, 17 June
    • President Reagan did restate the U.S. commitment not to undercut SALT II in June 1985, some six months before the unratified treaty would have expired. U.S. policy, however, was always contingent on reciprocal Soviet adherence. On that point, Reagan was sharply critical: “The United States has not taken any actions which would undercut existing arms control agreements. The United States has fully kept its part of the bargain; however, the Soviets have not…. Certain Soviet violations are, by their very nature, irreversible. Such is the case with respect to the Soviet Union's flight-testing and steps toward deployment of the SS-X-25 missile, a second new type of ICBM [intercontinental ballistic missile] prohibited by the unratified SALT II agreement. Since the noncompliance associated with the development of this missile cannot be corrected by the Soviet Union, the United States reserves the right to respond in a proportionate manner at the appropriate time.” See the President's statement of 10 June 1985, quoted in Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents, vol. 21, no. 24, 17 June 1985, pp. 770-71.
    • (1985) Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents , vol.21 , Issue.24 , pp. 770-771
  • 13
    • 3042590015 scopus 로고
    • Tacit and oral agreements, by their very nature, do not specify promises in great detail and rarely spell out contingencies or remedies. Consider, for example, the informal cooperation between friendly intelligence agencies such as the U.S. Central Intelligence Agency and Israel's Mossad. Besides exchanging information, both sides engage in unacknowledged spying on each other. But what are the limits? What violates the informal agreement, and what differentiates serious violations from “normal cheating”? To clarify these issues and to encourage regular cooperation, the United States and Israel have signed informal accords, beginning with a secret agreement in 1951. Even so, such agreements are necessarily incomplete, sometimes making it difficult to differentiate cheating from permissible activity. According to Blitzer, “U.S. law enforcement officials … long suspected that Israel was playing fast and loose with the long-standing U.S-Israeli understanding barring covert operations against each other. Yes, there is always some spying going on, even among very close friends and allies. But that is a far cry from actually planting a ‘mole’ in a friendly country's intelligence community. Thus, there is a huge difference between unobtrusive intelligence-gathering operations, on the one hand, and the actual running of paid spies in each other's country, on the other.” Over time, actors can use sanctions and exhortation to specify these contingent obligations and to signal the limits of their tolerance. But ambiguities will surely remain. See, (New York: Harper & Row)
    • Tacit and oral agreements, by their very nature, do not specify promises in great detail and rarely spell out contingencies or remedies. Consider, for example, the informal cooperation between friendly intelligence agencies such as the U.S. Central Intelligence Agency and Israel's Mossad. Besides exchanging information, both sides engage in unacknowledged spying on each other. But what are the limits? What violates the informal agreement, and what differentiates serious violations from “normal cheating”? To clarify these issues and to encourage regular cooperation, the United States and Israel have signed informal accords, beginning with a secret agreement in 1951. Even so, such agreements are necessarily incomplete, sometimes making it difficult to differentiate cheating from permissible activity. According to Blitzer, “U.S. law enforcement officials … long suspected that Israel was playing fast and loose with the long-standing U.S-Israeli understanding barring covert operations against each other. Yes, there is always some spying going on, even among very close friends and allies. But that is a far cry from actually planting a ‘mole’ in a friendly country's intelligence community. Thus, there is a huge difference between unobtrusive intelligence-gathering operations, on the one hand, and the actual running of paid spies in each other's country, on the other.” Over time, actors can use sanctions and exhortation to specify these contingent obligations and to signal the limits of their tolerance. But ambiguities will surely remain. See Wolf Blitzer, Territory of Lies: The Exclusive Story of Jonathan Jay Pollard—The American Who Spied on His Country for Israel and How He Was Betrayed (New York: Harper & Row, 1989), p. 163.
    • (1989) Territory of Lies: The Exclusive Story of Jonathan Jay Pollard—The American Who Spied on His Country for Israel and How He Was Betrayed , pp. 163
    • Blitzer, W.1
  • 15
    • 84972457369 scopus 로고
    • Tacit Bargaining and Arms Control
    • According to Downs and Rocke, “A state bargains tacitly with another state when it attempts to manipulate the latter's policy choices through its behavior rather than by relying on formal or informal diplomatic exchange.” Actions, not diplomatic words, are the crucial form of communications, and their aim is joint, voluntary cooperation rather than outright coercion. Downs and, contribution is to show how imperfect information affects states’ strategic choices and may produce inadvertent arms races. Their focus is on uncertain estimates of others’ strategies, preferences, and specific actions (either completed or intended), and not on the ambiguous meaning of tacit agreements and other informal bargains. See the following works of, (April)
    • According to Downs and Rocke, “A state bargains tacitly with another state when it attempts to manipulate the latter's policy choices through its behavior rather than by relying on formal or informal diplomatic exchange.” Actions, not diplomatic words, are the crucial form of communications, and their aim is joint, voluntary cooperation rather than outright coercion. Downs and Rocke's contribution is to show how imperfect information affects states’ strategic choices and may produce inadvertent arms races. Their focus is on uncertain estimates of others’ strategies, preferences, and specific actions (either completed or intended), and not on the ambiguous meaning of tacit agreements and other informal bargains. See the following works of George W. Downs and David M. Rocke: “Tacit Bargaining and Arms Control,” World Politics 39 (April 1987), p. 297.
    • (1987) World Politics , vol.39 , pp. 297
    • Downs, G.W.1    Rocke, D.M.2
  • 17
    • 84925682512 scopus 로고
    • the two problems of social order
    • See, discussion of, in, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), chap. 1. Elster's key distinction is between regular behavior patterns and cooperation. He distinguishes five main varieties of cooperation: helping others, voluntarily bearing costs of externalities, physical collaboration in joint ventures, mutual agreements to transfer rights (private orderings), and conventional equilibria (in which no party can improve its outcome by unilaterally deviating). In this article, my discussion of international cooperation focuses only on reciprocal contractual exchanges, which involve future performance and where the possibility of profitable defection might arise
    • See Jon Elster's discussion of “the two problems of social order,” in The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 1. Elster's key distinction is between regular behavior patterns and cooperation. He distinguishes five main varieties of cooperation: helping others, voluntarily bearing costs of externalities, physical collaboration in joint ventures, mutual agreements to transfer rights (private orderings), and conventional equilibria (in which no party can improve its outcome by unilaterally deviating). In this article, my discussion of international cooperation focuses only on reciprocal contractual exchanges, which involve future performance and where the possibility of profitable defection might arise.
    • (1989) The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order
    • Elster's, J.1
  • 18
    • 84976003024 scopus 로고
    • The Theory and Practice of Informal International Instruments
    • (October)
    • Anthony Aust, “The Theory and Practice of Informal International Instruments,” International and Comparative Law Quarterly 35 (October 1986), p. 791.
    • (1986) International and Comparative Law Quarterly , vol.35 , pp. 791
    • Aust, A.1
  • 19
    • 0039777888 scopus 로고
    • The Twilight Existence of Nonbinding International Agreements
    • See, for example, (April)
    • See, for example, Oscar Schachter, “The Twilight Existence of Nonbinding International Agreements,” American Journal of International Law 71 (April 1977), pp. 296-304.
    • (1977) American Journal of International Law , vol.71 , pp. 296-304
    • Schachter, O.1
  • 20
    • 0041749198 scopus 로고
    • The Senate Role in Treaty Ratification
    • (April)
    • Michael J. Glennon, “The Senate Role in Treaty Ratification,” American Journal of International Law 77 (April 1983), pp. 257-80.
    • (1983) American Journal of International Law , vol.77 , pp. 257-280
    • Glennon, M.J.1
  • 21
    • 84925583540 scopus 로고
    • Non-Binding Agreements
    • (Amsterdam: North-Holland), The one general (and quite valuable) legal treatment of informal agreements is “The Theory and Practice of Informal International Instruments” by Anthony Aust, a practitioner in the British Foreign Office
    • Fritz Munch, “Non-Binding Agreements,” in The Encyclopedia of Public International Law, vol. 7 (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1984), pp. 353-57. The one general (and quite valuable) legal treatment of informal agreements is “The Theory and Practice of Informal International Instruments” by Anthony Aust, a practitioner in the British Foreign Office.
    • (1984) The Encyclopedia of Public International Law , vol.7 , pp. 353-357
    • Munch, F.1
  • 22
    • 0003854361 scopus 로고
    • See, for example, (Oxford: Clarendon Press)
    • See, for example, Lord McNair, The Law of Treaties (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1961).
    • (1961) The Law of Treaties
    • McNair, L.1
  • 23
    • 84911908502 scopus 로고
    • (Dobbs Ferry, N.Y.: Oceana Publications)
    • Taslim Elias, The Modem Law of Treaties (Dobbs Ferry, N.Y.: Oceana Publications, 1974).
    • (1974) The Modem Law of Treaties
    • Elias, T.1
  • 24
    • 84972202580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’
    • Incomplete domestic agreements can be filled in by court decisions. Incomplete international agreements remain incomplete. They are beyond the reach of international court decisions, much less enforcement. For an astute discussion of the weakness of treaties that contemplate further, detailed negotiations, see, (October), In these general treaties, Baxter says, the individual provisions “are pacta de contrahendo, which cannot be enforced if the parties do not reach agreement. There is no way in which an agreement can be forced upon them and there is likewise no way in which they can be compelled to negotiate. The assertion that the duty to negotiate or to conclude an agreement implies a duty to negotiate in good faith is an empty one…. In the relations of States, a complaint that negotiations have not been carried on in good faith is mere rhetoric.”
    • Incomplete domestic agreements can be filled in by court decisions. Incomplete international agreements remain incomplete. They are beyond the reach of international court decisions, much less enforcement. For an astute discussion of the weakness of treaties that contemplate further, detailed negotiations, see Richard Baxter, “International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’” International and Comparative Law Quarterly 29 (October 1980), p. 552. In these general treaties, Baxter says, the individual provisions “are pacta de contrahendo, which cannot be enforced if the parties do not reach agreement. There is no way in which an agreement can be forced upon them and there is likewise no way in which they can be compelled to negotiate. The assertion that the duty to negotiate or to conclude an agreement implies a duty to negotiate in good faith is an empty one…. In the relations of States, a complaint that negotiations have not been carried on in good faith is mere rhetoric.”
    • (1980) International and Comparative Law Quarterly , vol.29 , pp. 552
    • Baxter, R.1
  • 25
    • 30044443471 scopus 로고
    • For an account of the purchase and the litigation, see, (New York: Putnam)
    • For an account of the purchase and the litigation, see Thomas Petzinger, Jr., Oil and Honor: The Texaco-Pennzoil Wars (New York: Putnam, 1987).
    • (1987) Oil and Honor: The Texaco-Pennzoil Wars
    • Petzinger, T.1
  • 26
    • 0001853672 scopus 로고
    • The Costs of Conflict Resolution and Financial Distress: Evidence from the Texaco-Pennzoil Litigation
    • In the dispute over Getty Oil, compliance issues were complicated by the possible size of any judgment against Texaco. Courts often require bonds to be posted covering any final awards. In this case, a bond of unprecedented size—well beyond the capacity of a bonding agency—was required. The unprecedented scale of Texaco's bond was an important element in the appeals process and the ultimate out-of-court settlement. The dispute also illustrates the high transactions costs that can accompany major litigation—costs that discourage litigation and encourage the establishment of institutions for the private governance of contractual relationships. Besides the direct costs of litigation, the dispute raised uncertainties about Texaco's continuing operations, thus reducing the company's stock price significantly (without adding commensurately to Pennzoil's price). One study indicates that the legal dispute reduced the combined wealth of Texaco and Pennzoil by some $3 billion. Approximately two-thirds of this sum was regained after the final settlement. See
    • In the dispute over Getty Oil, compliance issues were complicated by the possible size of any judgment against Texaco. Courts often require bonds to be posted covering any final awards. In this case, a bond of unprecedented size—well beyond the capacity of a bonding agency—was required. The unprecedented scale of Texaco's bond was an important element in the appeals process and the ultimate out-of-court settlement. The dispute also illustrates the high transactions costs that can accompany major litigation—costs that discourage litigation and encourage the establishment of institutions for the private governance of contractual relationships. Besides the direct costs of litigation, the dispute raised uncertainties about Texaco's continuing operations, thus reducing the company's stock price significantly (without adding commensurately to Pennzoil's price). One study indicates that the legal dispute reduced the combined wealth of Texaco and Pennzoil by some $3 billion. Approximately two-thirds of this sum was regained after the final settlement. See David M. Cutler and Lawrence H. Summers, “The Costs of Conflict Resolution and Financial Distress: Evidence from the Texaco-Pennzoil Litigation,” Rand Journal of Economics 19 (Summer 1988), pp. 157-72.
    • (1988) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.19 , pp. 157-172
    • Cutler, D.M.1    Summers, L.H.2
  • 27
    • 0004111838 scopus 로고
    • Fried and Atiyah represent opposite poles in this debate. Fried argues that the common law of contracts is based on the moral institution of promising, rather than on commercial exchange. To sustain this institution, the recipients of broken promises should be awarded their expectations of profit. Atiyah argues that court decisions have moved away from this strict emphasis, which arose in the nineteenth century, and returned to an older notion of commercial practice, which limits awards to the costs incurred in relying on broken promises. See, (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press)
    • Fried and Atiyah represent opposite poles in this debate. Fried argues that the common law of contracts is based on the moral institution of promising, rather than on commercial exchange. To sustain this institution, the recipients of broken promises should be awarded their expectations of profit. Atiyah argues that court decisions have moved away from this strict emphasis, which arose in the nineteenth century, and returned to an older notion of commercial practice, which limits awards to the costs incurred in relying on broken promises. See Charles Fried, Contract as Promise: A Theory of Contractual Obligation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1981).
    • (1981) Contract as Promise: A Theory of Contractual Obligation
    • Fried, C.1
  • 30
    • 0041557629 scopus 로고
    • The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages
    • For the classic statement, see, parts 1 and 2
    • For the classic statement, see Lon L. Fuller and William R. Perdue, “The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages,” parts 1 and 2, Yale Law Review, vol. 46,1936, pp. 52-96 and 373-420.
    • (1936) Yale Law Review , vol.46
    • Fuller, L.L.1    Perdue, W.R.2
  • 31
    • 30244518112 scopus 로고
    • This is usually a monetary award. Occasionally, it is a requirement to perform the specific promises in the contract. See, (London: Fontana), and Fried, Contract as Promise
    • This is usually a monetary award. Occasionally, it is a requirement to perform the specific promises in the contract. See John Adams and Roger Brownsword, Understanding Contract Law (London: Fontana, 1987), p. 144; and Fried, Contract as Promise.
    • (1987) Understanding Contract Law , pp. 144
    • Adams, J.1    Brownsword, R.2
  • 32
    • 0013419984 scopus 로고
    • The courts themselves require some efforts at self-protection. Once a contract has been breached, for instance, the “innocent” party is expected to take reasonable actions to minimize the damages and cannot win awards that cover a failure to do so. For the efficiency implications of this legal doctrine, see
    • The courts themselves require some efforts at self-protection. Once a contract has been breached, for instance, the “innocent” party is expected to take reasonable actions to minimize the damages and cannot win awards that cover a failure to do so. For the efficiency implications of this legal doctrine, see Anthony Kronman and Richard Posner, The Economics of Contract Law (Boston: Little, Brown, 1979), pp. 160-61.
    • (1979) The Economics of Contract Law , pp. 160-161
    • Kronman, A.1    Posner, R.2
  • 33
    • 0000565909 scopus 로고
    • Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: The Case of Divorce
    • See, (April), Mnookin and Kornhauser also conclude that the impact of differing legal arrangements on divorce settlements cannot be specified with precision. They attribute that to a more general theoretical gap: a limited understanding of how alternative institutional arrangements can affect bargaining outcomes
    • See Robert H. Mnookin and Lewis Kornhauser, “Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: The Case of Divorce,” Yale Law Journal 88 (April 1979), pp. 950-97. Mnookin and Kornhauser also conclude that the impact of differing legal arrangements on divorce settlements cannot be specified with precision. They attribute that to a more general theoretical gap: a limited understanding of how alternative institutional arrangements can affect bargaining outcomes.
    • (1979) Yale Law Journal , vol.88 , pp. 950-997
    • Mnookin, R.H.1    Kornhauser, L.2
  • 34
    • 0010161681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These are often ad hoc procedures designed for a specific agreement. Their powers may be quasi-judicial, as in the dispute mechanisms of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), or merely consultative, as in the procedures of the U.S.—Soviet Standing Consultative Commission, established in SALT I and SALT II. The presence of quasi-judicial bodies attached to specific agreements indicates, once again, the limits of international adjudication. And it points to the ad hoc means devised to manage the risks of international cooperation. See, (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press)
    • These are often ad hoc procedures designed for a specific agreement. Their powers may be quasi-judicial, as in the dispute mechanisms of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), or merely consultative, as in the procedures of the U.S.—Soviet Standing Consultative Commission, established in SALT I and SALT II. The presence of quasi-judicial bodies attached to specific agreements indicates, once again, the limits of international adjudication. And it points to the ad hoc means devised to manage the risks of international cooperation. See Richard B. Bilder, Managing the Risks of International Agreement (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1981), pp. 56-61.
    • (1981) Managing the Risks of International Agreement , pp. 56-61
    • Bilder, R.B.1
  • 35
    • 80655147292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A signatory always has the practical option of withdrawal, whether it is included as a legal option in the treaty or not. For legal analyses, see, (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press)
    • A signatory always has the practical option of withdrawal, whether it is included as a legal option in the treaty or not. For legal analyses, see Arie E. David, The Strategy of Treaty Termination: Lawful Breaches and Retaliations (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1975), pp. 203-16.
    • (1975) The Strategy of Treaty Termination: Lawful Breaches and Retaliations , pp. 203-216
    • David, A.E.1
  • 36
    • 84882616648 scopus 로고
    • Unilateral Denunciation of Treaties: The Vienna Convention and the International Court of Justice
    • (January)
    • Herbert W. Briggs, “Unilateral Denunciation of Treaties: The Vienna Convention and the International Court of Justice,” American Journal of International Law 68 (January 1974), pp. 51-68.
    • (1974) American Journal of International Law , vol.68 , pp. 51-68
    • Briggs, H.W.1
  • 37
    • 0003375133 scopus 로고
    • Law Enforcement, Malfeasance and Compensation of Enforcers
    • There have been proposals, based on efficiency grounds or libertarian principles, that private agents play a much larger role in enforcing domestic laws and contracts and that they be compensated by bounties, paid either by violators or the state. These proposals cannot be applied to international agreements without significant modification, since they ultimately envision authoritative judicial interpretation and enforcement. See, (January)
    • There have been proposals, based on efficiency grounds or libertarian principles, that private agents play a much larger role in enforcing domestic laws and contracts and that they be compensated by bounties, paid either by violators or the state. These proposals cannot be applied to international agreements without significant modification, since they ultimately envision authoritative judicial interpretation and enforcement. See Gary S. Becker and George J. Stigler, “Law Enforcement, Malfeasance and Compensation of Enforcers,” Journal of Legal Studies 3 (January 1974), pp. 1-18.
    • (1974) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.3 , pp. 1-18
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 38
    • 0000787258 scopus 로고
    • Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach
    • (March—April)
    • Gary S. Becker, “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political Economy 76 (March—April 1968), pp. 169-217.
    • (1968) Journal of Political Economy , vol.76 , pp. 169-217
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 39
    • 0000975826 scopus 로고
    • The Optimum Enforcement of Laws
    • (May—June)
    • George J. Stigler, “The Optimum Enforcement of Laws” Journal of Political Economy 78 (May—June 1970), pp. 526-36.
    • (1970) Journal of Political Economy , vol.78 , pp. 526-536
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 40
    • 0346185695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law
    • As Mnookin and Kornhauser point out in their study of divorce laws, “A legal system might allow varying degrees of private ordering upon dissolution of the marriage. Until recently, divorce law attempted to restrict private ordering severely.” See
    • As Mnookin and Kornhauser point out in their study of divorce laws, “A legal system might allow varying degrees of private ordering upon dissolution of the marriage. Until recently, divorce law attempted to restrict private ordering severely.” See Mnookin and Kornhauser, “Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law,” pp. 952-53.
    • Mnookin1    Kornhauser2
  • 41
    • 0011310835 scopus 로고
    • Consideration and Form
    • Three standard reasons are given for the legal requirement that contracts be put in writing. First, it should impart caution before an agreement is completed. Second, it should make clear to the parties that they have undertaken specific obligations. Third, if disagreements later arise, it should provide better evidence for courts. See the classic analysis by
    • Three standard reasons are given for the legal requirement that contracts be put in writing. First, it should impart caution before an agreement is completed. Second, it should make clear to the parties that they have undertaken specific obligations. Third, if disagreements later arise, it should provide better evidence for courts. See the classic analysis by Lon L. Fuller: “Consideration and Form,” Columbia Law Review, vol. 41, 1941, pp. 799-824.
    • (1941) Columbia Law Review , vol.41 , pp. 799-824
    • Fuller, L.L.1
  • 42
    • 84967118830 scopus 로고
    • (New York: Praeger)
    • Anatomy of Law (New York: Praeger, 1968), pp. 36-37
    • (1968) Anatomy of Law , pp. 36-37
  • 43
    • 0003728580 scopus 로고
    • Criminal organizations such as the Mafia can be understood partly as an institutional response to the problems of providing criminal services when the bargains themselves are illegal. For a fascinating economic study of such institutional arrangements, see, (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press)
    • Criminal organizations such as the Mafia can be understood partly as an institutional response to the problems of providing criminal services when the bargains themselves are illegal. For a fascinating economic study of such institutional arrangements, see Peter Reuter, Disorganized Crime: Illegal Markets and the Mafia (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1983).
    • (1983) Disorganized Crime: Illegal Markets and the Mafia
    • Reuter, P.1
  • 45
    • 84975985303 scopus 로고
    • Of course, commitments may be cast aside, no matter how formal, as Saddam Hussein did when he declared Iraq's border agreement with Iran “null and void” in 1981. The agreement, reached in 1975 in Algiers, stated that “land and river frontiers shall be inviolable, permanent and final.” There is a cost to discarding such an agreement unilaterally, even if that cost seems remote at the time. It virtually rules out the ability to conclude useful agreements on other border disputes. See United Nations, (New York: United Nations)
    • Of course, commitments may be cast aside, no matter how formal, as Saddam Hussein did when he declared Iraq's border agreement with Iran “null and void” in 1981. The agreement, reached in 1975 in Algiers, stated that “land and river frontiers shall be inviolable, permanent and final.” There is a cost to discarding such an agreement unilaterally, even if that cost seems remote at the time. It virtually rules out the ability to conclude useful agreements on other border disputes. See United Nations, Yearbook of the United Nations, 1981, vol. 35 (New York: United Nations, 1985), pp. 238-39.
    • (1985) Yearbook of the United Nations , vol.35 , pp. 238-239
  • 46
    • 84975950300 scopus 로고
    • See also Iran, Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Legal Department, (Tehran: Ministry of Foreign Affairs), including the text of the 1975 treaty, the treaty addendum, and Iran's interpretation
    • See also Iran, Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Legal Department, A Review of the Imposed War (Tehran: Ministry of Foreign Affairs, 1983), including the text of the 1975 treaty, the treaty addendum, and Iran's interpretation.
    • (1983) A Review of the Imposed War
  • 47
    • 0003758853 scopus 로고
    • In other words, if the future is highly valued, there can be an equilibrium in which the (current discounted) value of a reputation exceeds any short-run gains from taking advantage of it. If the prospective gains from reputation are sufficiently large, then it also pays to invest in reputation. See, (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press)
    • In other words, if the future is highly valued, there can be an equilibrium in which the (current discounted) value of a reputation exceeds any short-run gains from taking advantage of it. If the prospective gains from reputation are sufficiently large, then it also pays to invest in reputation. See David M. Kreps, A Course in Microeconomic Theory (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990), p. 532.
    • (1990) A Course in Microeconomic Theory , pp. 532
    • Kreps, D.M.1
  • 48
    • 0012989765 scopus 로고
    • Legal Rules in Repeated Deals: Banking in the Shadow of Defection in Japan
    • (January)
    • J. Mark Ramseyer, “Legal Rules in Repeated Deals: Banking in the Shadow of Defection in Japan,” Journal of Legal Studies 20 (January 1991), p. 96.
    • (1991) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.20 , pp. 96
    • Ramseyer, J.M.1
  • 49
    • 84975950292 scopus 로고
    • Elsewhere, I have shown that sovereign debtors in the nineteenth century moved to settle their old defaults when they contemplated seeking new loans. Creditors had the greatest bargaining leverage at precisely these moments. See, (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press)
    • Elsewhere, I have shown that sovereign debtors in the nineteenth century moved to settle their old defaults when they contemplated seeking new loans. Creditors had the greatest bargaining leverage at precisely these moments. See Charles Lipson, Standing Guard: Protecting Foreign Capital in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1985), p. 47.
    • (1985) Standing Guard: Protecting Foreign Capital in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries , pp. 47
    • Lipson, C.1
  • 51
    • 84976047999 scopus 로고
    • The United States made such an investment in reputation in the late 1970s, after its credibility as leader of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) was damaged by the neutron bomb affair. The problem arose after the Carter administration first supported and then opposed NATO's deployment of new antitank weapons, equipped with enhanced radiation warheads or neutron bombs. Key European leaders had already declared their support publicly, at considerable political cost, and now they had to reverse course. After the crisis died down, the Carter administration proposed another approach to nuclear modernization: Pershing II missiles. The administration then held fast (as did the Reagan administration) in support of its new plan. It did so despite a rising tide of public protest abroad and wavering support from European leaders, especially the Germans, who had initially proposed the modernization. According to Garthoff, “The principal effect of the neutron weapon affair was to reduce Western confidence in American leadership in the alliance, and later to lead the United States to seek to undo that effect by another new arms initiative for NATO…. The Carter administration itself felt it needed to compensate for its handling of the neutron decision. It sought to do so by responding boldly to a perceived European concern through exercising vigorous leadership…. Doubts about the military necessity or even desirability of deploying new [long-range tactical nuclear force] systems were overwhelmed by a perceived political necessity within the alliance.” See, (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution)
    • The United States made such an investment in reputation in the late 1970s, after its credibility as leader of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) was damaged by the neutron bomb affair. The problem arose after the Carter administration first supported and then opposed NATO's deployment of new antitank weapons, equipped with enhanced radiation warheads or neutron bombs. Key European leaders had already declared their support publicly, at considerable political cost, and now they had to reverse course. After the crisis died down, the Carter administration proposed another approach to nuclear modernization: Pershing II missiles. The administration then held fast (as did the Reagan administration) in support of its new plan. It did so despite a rising tide of public protest abroad and wavering support from European leaders, especially the Germans, who had initially proposed the modernization. According to Garthoff, “The principal effect of the neutron weapon affair was to reduce Western confidence in American leadership in the alliance, and later to lead the United States to seek to undo that effect by another new arms initiative for NATO…. The Carter administration itself felt it needed to compensate for its handling of the neutron decision. It sought to do so by responding boldly to a perceived European concern through exercising vigorous leadership…. Doubts about the military necessity or even desirability of deploying new [long-range tactical nuclear force] systems were overwhelmed by a perceived political necessity within the alliance.” See Raymond L. Garthoff, Detente and Confrontation: American—Soviet Relations from Nixon to Reagan (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1985), pp. 853 and 859.
    • (1985) Detente and Confrontation: American—Soviet Relations from Nixon to Reagan , pp. 853-859
    • Garthoff, R.L.1
  • 52
    • 84925639408 scopus 로고
    • Firms can guarantee quality by offering warranties. But what guarantees the warranty? The answer for expensive items may be the threat of litigation. But for less expensive items, it is simply the firm's reputation. “The hostage for performance,” according to Rubin, “must be in the familiar form of a quasirent stream [either of profits or return on capital]. In either case, the price of the product must be above marginal cost, and the difference must be high enough so that cheating by the firm does not pay.” See, (New York: Free Press)
    • Firms can guarantee quality by offering warranties. But what guarantees the warranty? The answer for expensive items may be the threat of litigation. But for less expensive items, it is simply the firm's reputation. “The hostage for performance,” according to Rubin, “must be in the familiar form of a quasirent stream [either of profits or return on capital]. In either case, the price of the product must be above marginal cost, and the difference must be high enough so that cheating by the firm does not pay.” See Paul Rubin, Managing Business Transactions: Controlling the Cost of Coordinating, Communicating, and Decision Making (New York: Free Press, 1990), p. 147.
    • (1990) Managing Business Transactions: Controlling the Cost of Coordinating, Communicating, and Decision Making , pp. 147
    • Rubin, P.1
  • 53
    • 0002963088 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements
    • (January)
    • L. G. Telser, “A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements,” Journal of Business 53 (January 1980), pp. 27-28.
    • (1980) Journal of Business , vol.53 , pp. 27-28
    • Telser, L.G.1
  • 54
    • 0002734011 scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Information
    • “Reputation commands a price (or exacts a penalty),” Stigler once observed, “because it economizes on search.” When that search must cover unknown future behavior, such as a partner's likelihood of complying with an agreement, then reputations are particularly valuable. See, (June)
    • “Reputation commands a price (or exacts a penalty),” Stigler once observed, “because it economizes on search.” When that search must cover unknown future behavior, such as a partner's likelihood of complying with an agreement, then reputations are particularly valuable. See George Stigler, “The Economics of Information,” Journal of Political Economy 69 (June 1961), p. 224.
    • (1961) Journal of Political Economy , pp. 224
    • Stigler, G.1
  • 55
    • 84971972397 scopus 로고
    • Repudiations and Confiscations by the Medieval State
    • This logic should apply to all agreements lacking effective third-party enforcement, from modern warfare to premodern commerce. For an application of this approach to medieval economic history, see, (March)
    • This logic should apply to all agreements lacking effective third-party enforcement, from modern warfare to premodern commerce. For an application of this approach to medieval economic history, see John M. Veitch, “Repudiations and Confiscations by the Medieval State,” Journal of Economic History 46 (March 1986), pp. 31-36.
    • (1986) Journal of Economic History , vol.46 , pp. 31-36
    • Veitch, J.M.1
  • 56
    • 84975942033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’
    • See
    • See Baxter, “International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’” p. 550.
    • Baxter1
  • 57
    • 26844525812 scopus 로고
    • International Economic Soft Law
    • (Collected Courses of the Hague Academy of International Law)
    • Ignaz Seidl-Hohenfeldern, “International Economic Soft Law,” Recueil de cours (Collected Courses of the Hague Academy of International Law), vol. 163, 1979, pp. 169-246.
    • (1979) Recueil de cours , vol.163 , pp. 169-246
    • Seidl-Hohenfeldern, I.1
  • 58
    • 84975942033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’
    • See, Baxter refers to alliances and statements of broad political intent (such as the Yalta Agreement) as “political treaties.” He does not define the term further or distinguish it from other kinds of treaties.
    • See Baxter, “International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’” p. 551. Baxter refers to alliances and statements of broad political intent (such as the Yalta Agreement) as “political treaties.” He does not define the term further or distinguish it from other kinds of treaties.
    • Baxter1
  • 59
    • 84935995217 scopus 로고
    • Realists consider cooperation important in only one sphere: military alliances. “In anarchy, states form alliances to protect themselves,” says Walt. “Their conduct is determined by the threats they perceive.” Although such alliances are important, they are simply considered the by-products of a world fundamentally characterized by conflict and the contest for relative gains. As Grieco bluntly puts it, “States are predisposed toward conflict and competition, and they often fail to cooperate even when they have common interests.” See, (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press)
    • Realists consider cooperation important in only one sphere: military alliances. “In anarchy, states form alliances to protect themselves,” says Walt. “Their conduct is determined by the threats they perceive.” Although such alliances are important, they are simply considered the by-products of a world fundamentally characterized by conflict and the contest for relative gains. As Grieco bluntly puts it, “States are predisposed toward conflict and competition, and they often fail to cooperate even when they have common interests.” See Stephen M. Walt, The Origins of Alliances (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987), p. x.
    • (1987) The Origins of Alliances , pp. x
    • Walt, S.M.1
  • 61
    • 84926282169 scopus 로고
    • Arms Control With and Without Agreements
    • Adelman emphasizes the slowness of negotiating formal agreements, especially major agreements with the Soviets. The Limited Test Ban Treaty (1963) took eight years to complete; the Non-Proliferation Treaty (1968) took more than three years; and the SALT I agreement (1972) took more than two years. The SALT II agreement (1979) took seven years and still failed to win Senate ratification. See, (Winter, -85)
    • Adelman emphasizes the slowness of negotiating formal agreements, especially major agreements with the Soviets. The Limited Test Ban Treaty (1963) took eight years to complete; the Non-Proliferation Treaty (1968) took more than three years; and the SALT I agreement (1972) took more than two years. The SALT II agreement (1979) took seven years and still failed to win Senate ratification. See Kenneth Adelman, “Arms Control With and Without Agreements,” Foreign Affairs 63 (Winter 1984-85), pp. 240-63.
    • (1984) Foreign Affairs , vol.63 , pp. 240-263
    • Adelman, K.1
  • 62
    • 84965478361 scopus 로고
    • The slowness and difficulty of ratifying complex agreements and the problems of adapting to meet changing circumstances often lead states to choose less formal mechanisms. The United States and European Community (EC) have made exactly that choice to deal with their conflicts over “competition policy” and antitrust. The two sides “have abandoned the idea of drawing up a special treaty on competition issues,” such as mergers and acquisitions, according to the Financial Times, “because it would be too complicated, and would involve obtaining the approval of both the U.S. congress and EC member states. Instead, they discussed more flexible arrangements providing for a better exchange of information, regular meetings and discussions on current cases, and a means of settling disputes.” See, 17 January
    • The slowness and difficulty of ratifying complex agreements and the problems of adapting to meet changing circumstances often lead states to choose less formal mechanisms. The United States and European Community (EC) have made exactly that choice to deal with their conflicts over “competition policy” and antitrust. The two sides “have abandoned the idea of drawing up a special treaty on competition issues,” such as mergers and acquisitions, according to the Financial Times, “because it would be too complicated, and would involve obtaining the approval of both the U.S. congress and EC member states. Instead, they discussed more flexible arrangements providing for a better exchange of information, regular meetings and discussions on current cases, and a means of settling disputes.” See Financial Times, 17 January 1991, p. 6.
    • (1991) Financial Times , pp. 6
  • 63
    • 0039730359 scopus 로고
    • One reason U.S. diplomats favored the Panama Canal treaties was that Latin American states were so uniformly opposed to continued U.S. ownership of the waterway. The disposition of this issue was crucial to America's role in the hemisphere. A number of Latin American leaders were involved in the negotiations, and some eighteen heads of state attended the final signing ceremony. The whole episode clearly demonstrates how “third parties” can have a direct stake in bilateral treaty arrangements and how these diplomatic relationships can be enhanced or, more likely, embarrassed by frank disclosures during the public ratification process. See, (New York: Knopf)
    • One reason U.S. diplomats favored the Panama Canal treaties was that Latin American states were so uniformly opposed to continued U.S. ownership of the waterway. The disposition of this issue was crucial to America's role in the hemisphere. A number of Latin American leaders were involved in the negotiations, and some eighteen heads of state attended the final signing ceremony. The whole episode clearly demonstrates how “third parties” can have a direct stake in bilateral treaty arrangements and how these diplomatic relationships can be enhanced or, more likely, embarrassed by frank disclosures during the public ratification process. See Robert A. Pastor and Jorge G. Castatieda, Limits to Friendship: The United States and Mexico (New York: Knopf, 1988), pp. 159-61.
    • (1988) Limits to Friendship: The United States and Mexico , pp. 159-161
    • Pastor, R.A.1    Castatieda, J.G.2
  • 65
    • 84976096797 scopus 로고
    • Climax: Senate Ratification, 1977-1978
    • This key treaty won ratification by a single vote, and only then after intense presidential lobbying and some significant amendments. The Carter administration's political dilemma was nicely summarized by the Republican leader in the Senate, Howard Baker: “The Canal has a constituency and the treaty has no constituency.” See, in G. Harvey Summ and Tom Kelly, eds., (Athens: Ohio University Center for International Studies)
    • This key treaty won ratification by a single vote, and only then after intense presidential lobbying and some significant amendments. The Carter administration's political dilemma was nicely summarized by the Republican leader in the Senate, Howard Baker: “The Canal has a constituency and the treaty has no constituency.” See Timothy Stater, “Climax: Senate Ratification, 1977-1978,” in G. Harvey Summ and Tom Kelly, eds., The Good Neighbors: America, Panama, and the 1977 Canal Treaties (Athens: Ohio University Center for International Studies, 1988), pp. 90-91.
    • (1988) The Good Neighbors: America, Panama, and the 1977 Canal Treaties , pp. 90-91
    • Stater, T.1
  • 67
    • 84925654972 scopus 로고
    • See “Treaty on Extradition and Mutual Assistance in Criminal Matters Between the United States of America and the Republic of Turkey, with Appendix, Signed June 7,1979, Entered into Force January 1,1981,” in, (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office)
    • See “Treaty on Extradition and Mutual Assistance in Criminal Matters Between the United States of America and the Republic of Turkey, with Appendix, Signed June 7,1979, Entered into Force January 1,1981,” in United States Treaties and Other International Agreements, vol. 32, part 3 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1986), pp. 3111 ff.
    • (1986) United States Treaties and Other International Agreements , vol.32 , pp. 3111 ff
  • 69
    • 84925643101 scopus 로고
    • Just what agreements must be submitted as treaties remains ambiguous. It is a constitutional question, of course, but also a question of the political balance of power between the Congress and the President. At one point, President Carter's chief of staff, Hamilton Jordan, announced that Carter would decide whether the Panama Canal agreements were treaties or not. He “could present [the accords] to the Congress as a treaty, or as an agreement, and at the proper time he’ll make that decision.” Interview on “Face the Nation,” CBS News, cited by, in, (New York: New York University Press)
    • Just what agreements must be submitted as treaties remains ambiguous. It is a constitutional question, of course, but also a question of the political balance of power between the Congress and the President. At one point, President Carter's chief of staff, Hamilton Jordan, announced that Carter would decide whether the Panama Canal agreements were treaties or not. He “could present [the accords] to the Congress as a treaty, or as an agreement, and at the proper time he’ll make that decision.” Interview on “Face the Nation,” CBS News, cited by Loch K. Johnson in The Making of International Agreements: Congress Confronts the Executive (New York: New York University Press, 1984), p. 141.
    • (1984) The Making of International Agreements: Congress Confronts the Executive , pp. 141
    • Johnson, L.K.1
  • 71
    • 0007718506 scopus 로고
    • The U.S. Constitution, Article II, Section 2, provides that the President “shall have power, by and with the Advice and Consent of the Senate, to make treaties, provided two-thirds of the Senators present concur.” For a detailed study of the constitutional issues, see, (Mineola, N.Y.: Foundation Press)
    • The U.S. Constitution, Article II, Section 2, provides that the President “shall have power, by and with the Advice and Consent of the Senate, to make treaties, provided two-thirds of the Senators present concur.” For a detailed study of the constitutional issues, see Louis Henkin, Foreign Affairs and the Constitution (Mineola, N.Y.: Foundation Press, 1972).
    • (1972) Foreign Affairs and the Constitution
    • Henkin, L.1
  • 72
    • 84894313059 scopus 로고
    • See the War Powers Resolution
    • See the War Powers Resolution, 87 Stat. 555, 1973.
    • (1973) Stat. , vol.87 , pp. 555
  • 74
    • 84975942033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’
    • See
    • See Baxter, “International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’” pp. 554-55.
    • Baxter1
  • 76
    • 84976182456 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Foreign Relations, Senate Report no. 92-591,92d Congress, 2d sess
    • U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Foreign Relations, Transmittal of Executive Agreements to Congress, Senate Report no. 92-591,92d Congress, 2d sess., 1972, pp. 3-4.
    • (1972) Transmittal of Executive Agreements to Congress , pp. 3-4
  • 77
    • 84976081425 scopus 로고
    • The Case Act passed the Senate and House overwhelmingly in 1972 and has been amended several times since then. The State Department finally issued implementation regulations in 1981. The original act was Public Law 92-403. For the amended version, see 1
    • The Case Act passed the Senate and House overwhelmingly in 1972 and has been amended several times since then. The State Department finally issued implementation regulations in 1981. The original act was Public Law 92-403. For the amended version, see 1 United States Code 112b, 1988.
    • (1988) United States Code , pp. 112b
  • 78
    • 14844287510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For implementing regulations, see 22
    • For implementing regulations, see 22 Code of Federal Regulations, part 181.
    • Code of Federal Regulations
  • 79
    • 0003668102 scopus 로고
    • and 46, 13 July
    • and 46 Federal Register, 13 July 1981, pp. 35917 ff.
    • (1981) Federal Register , pp. 35917 ff
  • 80
    • 0003938439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For one model of how technical innovations could complicate treaty maintenance, see, chap. 5
    • For one model of how technical innovations could complicate treaty maintenance, see Downs and Rocke, Tacit Bargaining, Arms Races, and Arms Control, chap. 5.
    • Tacit Bargaining, Arms Races, and Arms Control
    • Downs1    Rocke2
  • 83
    • 33747600516 scopus 로고
    • The Safeguard Issue in the Uruguay Round: A Comprehensive Approach
    • (October)
    • Peter Kleen, “The Safeguard Issue in the Uruguay Round: A Comprehensive Approach,” Journal of World Trade 25 (October 1989), pp. 73-92.
    • (1989) Journal of World Trade , vol.25 , pp. 73-92
    • Kleen, P.1
  • 84
    • 84976091363 scopus 로고
    • Typical was the communiqué issued in late 1983 at the conclusion of OPEC's sixty-ninth conference. It restated OPEC's production ceiling of 17.5 million barrels per day and its marker price of $29. See, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
    • Typical was the communiqué issued in late 1983 at the conclusion of OPEC's sixty-ninth conference. It restated OPEC's production ceiling of 17.5 million barrels per day and its marker price of $29. See Ian Skeet, OPEC: Twenty-Five Years of Prices and Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988), p. 196.
    • (1988) OPEC: Twenty-Five Years of Prices and Politics , pp. 196
    • Skeet, I.1
  • 85
    • 84976091364 scopus 로고
    • OPEC Peace May Be Short-Lived as Debate Looms on New Quotas
    • See, European edition, 12 June
    • See James Tanner and Allanna Sullivan, “OPEC Peace May Be Short-Lived as Debate Looms on New Quotas,” Wall Street Journal, European edition, 12 June 1989, pp. 1 and 10.
    • (1989) Wall Street Journal , pp. 1-10
    • Tanner, J.1    Sullivan, A.2
  • 86
    • 84976069043 scopus 로고
    • A Confederacy of Cheats
    • 10 June
    • “A Confederacy of Cheats,” Economist, 10 June 1989, p. 88.
    • (1989) Economist , pp. 88
  • 87
    • 84976069082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OPEC's founders had hoped to create an operating international institution, not merely a negotiating forum. In the original organization, there was even an enforcement section. The section was effectively dropped by 1964 and disappeared formally in 1966. This transformation amounted to an “implicit admission … that OPEC and its Secretary General would not act, as had been visualized at its creation, as an operating arm of its members.” See
    • OPEC's founders had hoped to create an operating international institution, not merely a negotiating forum. In the original organization, there was even an enforcement section. The section was effectively dropped by 1964 and disappeared formally in 1966. This transformation amounted to an “implicit admission … that OPEC and its Secretary General would not act, as had been visualized at its creation, as an operating arm of its members.” See Skeet, OPEC: Twenty-Five Years of Prices and Politics, p. 237.
    • OPEC: Twenty-Five Years of Prices and Politics , pp. 237
    • Skeet1
  • 88
    • 84959626707 scopus 로고
    • International Cooperation in Economic and Security Affairs
    • On the importance of surprise for cooperation in security affairs, see, (October)
    • On the importance of surprise for cooperation in security affairs, see Charles Lipson, “International Cooperation in Economic and Security Affairs,” World Politics 37 (October 1984), pp. 1-23.
    • (1984) World Politics , vol.37 , pp. 1-23
    • Lipson, C.1
  • 89
    • 84975950195 scopus 로고
    • Public statement issued by U.S. Department of State on 4 March, and cited by Talbott in
    • Public statement issued by U.S. Department of State on 4 March 1981 and cited by Talbott in Deadly Gambits, p. 225.
    • (1981) Deadly Gambits , pp. 225
  • 90
    • 84975950194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remarks at Memorial Day Ceremonies at Arlington National Cemetery
    • In his, President Reagan made the following statement: “As for existing strategic arms agreements, we will refrain from actions which undercut them so long as the Soviet Union shows equal restraint.”
    • In his “Remarks at Memorial Day Ceremonies at Arlington National Cemetery,” p. 709, President Reagan made the following statement: “As for existing strategic arms agreements, we will refrain from actions which undercut them so long as the Soviet Union shows equal restraint.”
  • 91
    • 84975969327 scopus 로고
    • Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents
    • Presidential response to a question on 13 May 1982, quoted in, 17 May
    • Presidential response to a question on 13 May 1982, quoted in Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents, vol. 18, no. 19, 17 May 1982, p. 635.
    • (1982) , vol.18 , Issue.19 , pp. 635
  • 92
    • 84976069906 scopus 로고
    • President Carter declared that the United States would continue to observe the terms of the interim SALT II agreement after its expiration and was roundly criticized for exceeding his legal powers. His successor, who had campaigned against SALT II, declined to make any “parallel unilateral policy declarations.” The Congress was not so inhibited. In the 1984 Defense Authorization Act, it declared that the United States should not undermine existing international agreements on offensive strategic arms, at least until the SALT II agreement expired in December, provided the Soviet Union did the same. President Reagan made a similar statement but added that the Soviets must also pursue a new agreement on strategic arms (the START talks). In December 1986, the United States exceeded the aggregate SALT limits on strategic weapons when it put a new B-52, equipped with cruise missiles, into service. Even then, one year after the original expiration date of the SALT II agreement, the United States defended its actions as a sanction for Soviet violations. See
    • President Carter declared that the United States would continue to observe the terms of the interim SALT II agreement after its expiration and was roundly criticized for exceeding his legal powers. His successor, who had campaigned against SALT II, declined to make any “parallel unilateral policy declarations.” The Congress was not so inhibited. In the 1984 Defense Authorization Act, it declared that the United States should not undermine existing international agreements on offensive strategic arms, at least until the SALT II agreement expired in December 1985, provided the Soviet Union did the same. President Reagan made a similar statement but added that the Soviets must also pursue a new agreement on strategic arms (the START talks). In December 1986, the United States exceeded the aggregate SALT limits on strategic weapons when it put a new B-52, equipped with cruise missiles, into service. Even then, one year after the original expiration date of the SALT II agreement, the United States defended its actions as a sanction for Soviet violations. See Calvo-Goller and Calvo, The SALT Agreements, p. 330.
    • (1985) The SALT Agreements , pp. 330
    • Calvo-Goller1    Calvo2
  • 94
    • 0004057628 scopus 로고
    • Raymond Vernon, writing on foreign investments, has shown the dangers of violating this approach. Even if an agreement provides significant benefits to both sides, it may provide those benefits to one side immediately and to the other much later. Such agreements are vulnerable to noncompliance in midstream, after one side has already received its benefits. This is one element of, “obsolescing bargain.” It is a variant of Hobbes's critique of covenants, in which one side performs its side of the bargain first. See, (New York: Basic Books)
    • Raymond Vernon, writing on foreign investments, has shown the dangers of violating this approach. Even if an agreement provides significant benefits to both sides, it may provide those benefits to one side immediately and to the other much later. Such agreements are vulnerable to noncompliance in midstream, after one side has already received its benefits. This is one element of Vernon's “obsolescing bargain.” It is a variant of Hobbes's critique of covenants, in which one side performs its side of the bargain first. See Raymond Vernon, Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of U.S. Enterprises (New York: Basic Books, 1971).
    • (1971) Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of U.S. Enterprises
    • Vernon, R.1
  • 95
    • 84925609217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements
    • On the general logic of self-sustaining agreements, see
    • On the general logic of self-sustaining agreements, see Telser, “A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements,” pp. 27-44.
    • Telser1
  • 96
    • 84976076212 scopus 로고
    • Limitation of Anti-Ballistic Missile Systems, Signed May 26, 1972, with Agreed Interpretations, Common Understandings, and Unilateral Statements
    • See, in, (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office)
    • See “Limitation of Anti-Ballistic Missile Systems, Signed May 26, 1972, with Agreed Interpretations, Common Understandings, and Unilateral Statements,” in United States Treaties and Other International Agreements, vol. 23, part 4 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1973), pp. 3435-61.
    • (1973) United States Treaties and Other International Agreements , vol.23 , pp. 3435-3461
  • 97
    • 0242583442 scopus 로고
    • These issues are the subject of an extensive literature. See, for example, ed., (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press)
    • These issues are the subject of an extensive literature. See, for example, Stephen J. Cimbala, ed., The Technology, Strategy and Politics of SDI (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1987).
    • (1987) The Technology, Strategy and Politics of SDI
    • Cimbala, S.J.1
  • 98
    • 84971788167 scopus 로고
    • revised ed. (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution)
    • Raymond L. Garthoff, Reflections on the Cuban Missile Crisis, revised ed. (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1989), pp. 86-87.
    • (1989) Reflections on the Cuban Missile Crisis , pp. 86-87
    • Garthoff, R.L.1
  • 101
    • 0004075376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is sometimes argued that the Turkish and Italian missiles were not part of any deal, since the United States would soon have removed them even if the Soviets had not raised the issue. The counterargument, which I find more convincing, is that the Soviets sought their removal as part of the bargaining on Cuba and the United States did, in effect, agree that it “expected” to remove them. The American decision was timed and disclosed specifically to encourage Soviet acceptance of the larger deal. Garthoff calls this decision “an additional sweetener” that “certainly made it easier for Khrushchev to accept the basic over-the-table settlement.” See, see also pp. 88 and 94-95. Given the high stakes in Cuba, Soviet behavior was probably little changed by the Turkish side-payment. We will never know with certainty. From the U.S. viewpoint, however, it was wise to make the concessions part of the bargaining: they were minor, secret, and potentially quite rewarding. When information is imperfect, as it was in this case, clever negotiators can “bargain away” concessions that would have been undertaken anyway. The tactic is to make them appear contingent, with the goal of extracting additional concessions and sealing the final bargain. That is exactly what the United States did with the aging Turkish and Italian missiles, while minimizing the reputational costs of any apparent concessions
    • It is sometimes argued that the Turkish and Italian missiles were not part of any deal, since the United States would soon have removed them even if the Soviets had not raised the issue. The counterargument, which I find more convincing, is that the Soviets sought their removal as part of the bargaining on Cuba and the United States did, in effect, agree that it “expected” to remove them. The American decision was timed and disclosed specifically to encourage Soviet acceptance of the larger deal. Garthoff calls this decision “an additional sweetener” that “certainly made it easier for Khrushchev to accept the basic over-the-table settlement.” See Garthoff, Reflections on the Cuban Missile Crisis, p. 87; see also pp. 88 and 94-95. Given the high stakes in Cuba, Soviet behavior was probably little changed by the Turkish side-payment. We will never know with certainty. From the U.S. viewpoint, however, it was wise to make the concessions part of the bargaining: they were minor, secret, and potentially quite rewarding. When information is imperfect, as it was in this case, clever negotiators can “bargain away” concessions that would have been undertaken anyway. The tactic is to make them appear contingent, with the goal of extracting additional concessions and sealing the final bargain. That is exactly what the United States did with the aging Turkish and Italian missiles, while minimizing the reputational costs of any apparent concessions.
    • Reflections on the Cuban Missile Crisis , pp. 87
    • Garthoff1
  • 102
    • 84925631125 scopus 로고
    • In 1906, the British Foreign Minister, Sir Edward Grey, discussed the dilemmas posed by these expectations. The entente agreements, signed by a previous British government, “created in France a belief that we shall support [the French] in war…. If this expectation is disappointed, the French will never forgive us. There would also I think be a general feeling that we had behaved badly and left France in the lurch…. On the other hand the prospect of a European war and of our being involved in it is horrible,” See document no. 299, in, eds., (London: His Majesty's Stationery Office)
    • In 1906, the British Foreign Minister, Sir Edward Grey, discussed the dilemmas posed by these expectations. The entente agreements, signed by a previous British government, “created in France a belief that we shall support [the French] in war…. If this expectation is disappointed, the French will never forgive us. There would also I think be a general feeling that we had behaved badly and left France in the lurch…. On the other hand the prospect of a European war and of our being involved in it is horrible,” See document no. 299, in G. P. Gooch and Harold Temperley, eds., British Documents on the Origin of the 1898-1914, vol. 3 (London: His Majesty's Stationery Office, 1928), p. 266.
    • (1928) British Documents on the Origin of the 1898-1914 , vol.3 , pp. 266
    • Gooch, G.P.1    Temperley, H.2
  • 103
    • 84975995604 scopus 로고
    • Although the State Department did try to persuade Congress that Western Europe was aiding the embargo, its efforts were in vain. Quiet reassurances from the State Department were distrusted by a hard-line, anticommunist Congress, which saw them as self-serving maneuvers to preserve diplomatic ties. See Michael Mastanduno, “Trade as a Strategic Weapon: American and Alliance Export Control Policy in the Early Postwar Period,” in, eds., (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press)
    • Although the State Department did try to persuade Congress that Western Europe was aiding the embargo, its efforts were in vain. Quiet reassurances from the State Department were distrusted by a hard-line, anticommunist Congress, which saw them as self-serving maneuvers to preserve diplomatic ties. See Michael Mastanduno, “Trade as a Strategic Weapon: American and Alliance Export Control Policy in the Early Postwar Period,” in G. John Ikenberry, David A. Lake, and Michael Mastanduno, eds., The State and American Foreign Economic Policy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1988), p. 136.
    • (1988) The State and American Foreign Economic Policy , pp. 136
    • Ikenberry, G.J.1    Lake, D.A.2    Mastanduno, M.3
  • 104
    • 84938036108 scopus 로고
    • These figures, which were reported in, are based on data from the Ministry of Economic Affairs in Taiwan and the government in Hong Kong and include trade and investment routed through Hong Kong companies to avoid Taiwanese restrictions
    • These figures, which were reported in The New York Times, 14 April 1990, p. 17, are based on data from the Ministry of Economic Affairs in Taiwan and the government in Hong Kong and include trade and investment routed through Hong Kong companies to avoid Taiwanese restrictions.
    • (1990) The New York Times , pp. 17
  • 106
    • 84925602652 scopus 로고
    • This definition is based on the second meaning of “tacit” in, 2d ed., (Oxford: Clarendon Press)
    • This definition is based on the second meaning of “tacit” in The Oxford English Dictionary, 2d ed., vol. 17 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1989), p. 527.
    • (1989) The Oxford English Dictionary , vol.17 , pp. 527
  • 108
    • 0004142397 scopus 로고
    • (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), chap. 3
    • Friedrich Kratochwil, Rules, Norms and Decisions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 3.
    • (1989) Rules, Norms and Decisions
    • Kratochwil, F.1
  • 109
    • 84925599862 scopus 로고
    • A few international lawyers argued that the Yalta and Potsdam agreements were binding treaty commitments. The U.S. State Department did publish the Yalta Agreement in the Executive Agreements Series (no. 498) and in U.S. Treaties in Force (1963). In 1948, Sir Hersch Lauterpacht said that they “incorporated definite rules of conduct which may be regarded as legally binding on the States in question.” The British and American governments explicitly rejected that view. In 1956, in an aide-memoire to the Japanese government, the State Department declared that “the United States regards the so-called Yalta Agreement as simply a statement of common purposes by the heads of the participating governments and … not as of any legal effect in transferring territories.” See, cited by Schachter in “The Twilight Existence of Nonbinding International Agreements,” p. 298 n.
    • A few international lawyers argued that the Yalta and Potsdam agreements were binding treaty commitments. The U.S. State Department did publish the Yalta Agreement in the Executive Agreements Series (no. 498) and in U.S. Treaties in Force (1963). In 1948, Sir Hersch Lauterpacht said that they “incorporated definite rules of conduct which may be regarded as legally binding on the States in question.” The British and American governments explicitly rejected that view. In 1956, in an aide-memoire to the Japanese government, the State Department declared that “the United States regards the so-called Yalta Agreement as simply a statement of common purposes by the heads of the participating governments and … not as of any legal effect in transferring territories.” See Department of State Bulletin, vol. 35, 1956, p. 484, cited by Schachter in “The Twilight Existence of Nonbinding International Agreements,” p. 298 n.
    • (1956) Department of State Bulletin , vol.35 , pp. 484
  • 110
    • 0007676456 scopus 로고
    • Peace, of H. Lauterpacht, ed., 7th ed. (London: Longmans, Green), section 487
    • L. P. L. Oppenheim, Peace, vol. 1 of H. Lauterpacht, ed., International Law: A Treatise, 7th ed. (London: Longmans, Green, 1948), p. 788, section 487.
    • (1948) International Law: A Treatise , pp. 788
    • Oppenheim, L.P.L.1
  • 111
    • 0041442241 scopus 로고
    • Origins of the Cold War
    • (Autumn)
    • Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., “Origins of the Cold War,” Foreign Affairs 46 (Autumn 1967), pp. 22-52.
    • (1967) Foreign Affairs , vol.46 , pp. 22-52
    • Schlesinger, A.M.1
  • 112
    • 1842863945 scopus 로고
    • Reciprocal Measures for Arms Stabilization
    • See, (Fall)
    • See Thomas C. Schelling, “Reciprocal Measures for Arms Stabilization,” Daedalus 89 (Fall 1960), pp. 892-914.
    • (1960) Daedalus , vol.89 , pp. 892-914
    • Schelling, T.C.1
  • 113
    • 84936271476 scopus 로고
    • What Went Wrong with Arms Control?
    • (Winter -86)
    • Thomas C. Schelling, “What Went Wrong with Arms Control?” Foreign Affairs 64 (Winter 1985-86), pp. 219-33.
    • (1985) Foreign Affairs , vol.64 , pp. 219-233
    • Schelling, T.C.1
  • 114
    • 0004199322 scopus 로고
    • 2d ed. (Washington, D.C.: Pergamon-Brassey), Schelling's point is strongly endorsed by Adelman in “Arms Control With and Without Agreements.”
    • Thomas C. Schelling and Morton H. Halperin, Strategy and Arms Control, 2d ed. (Washington, D.C.: Pergamon-Brassey, 1985), pp. 77-90. Schelling's point is strongly endorsed by Adelman in “Arms Control With and Without Agreements.”.
    • (1985) Strategy and Arms Control , pp. 77-90
    • Schelling, T.C.1    Halperin, M.H.2
  • 118
    • 84976076122 scopus 로고
    • See Garthoff, Detente and Confrontation, chap. 27. Until the Afghanistan invasion, there had been a sharp debate within the Carter administration over the implied terms of detente. The problem with implied terms, after all, is that they may well be ambiguous and differently understood by different actors, across states and within them. The eventual winner was National Security Adviser Zbigniew Brzezinski, who clearly stated his position early in the Carter administration while discussing the Horn of Africa. In March 1978, he wrote to President Carter that “the Soviets must be made to realize that detente, to be enduring, has to be both comprehensive and reciprocal. If the Soviets are allowed to feel that they can use military force in one part of the world—and yet maintain cooperative relations in other areas—then they have no incentive to exercise any restraint.” See, (New York: Farrar, Straus, Giroux)
    • See Garthoff, Detente and Confrontation, chap. 27. Until the Afghanistan invasion, there had been a sharp debate within the Carter administration over the implied terms of detente. The problem with implied terms, after all, is that they may well be ambiguous and differently understood by different actors, across states and within them. The eventual winner was National Security Adviser Zbigniew Brzezinski, who clearly stated his position early in the Carter administration while discussing the Horn of Africa. In March 1978, he wrote to President Carter that “the Soviets must be made to realize that detente, to be enduring, has to be both comprehensive and reciprocal. If the Soviets are allowed to feel that they can use military force in one part of the world—and yet maintain cooperative relations in other areas—then they have no incentive to exercise any restraint.” See Zbigniew Brzezinski, Power and Principle: Memoirs of the National Security Adviser, 1977-1981 (New York: Farrar, Straus, Giroux, 1983), p. 186.
    • (1983) Power and Principle: Memoirs of the National Security Adviser, 1977-1981 , pp. 186
    • Brzezinski, Z.1
  • 120
    • 84975985425 scopus 로고
    • “The Soviet occupation of Afghanistan and the American response led to a sharp break from the whole course of U.S.-Soviet relations over the preceding decade,” according to Garthoff. “It gave the coup de grace to the already seriously eroded and weakened mutual policy of detente established in May 1972…. In many ways January 1980 was a sharper turning point than January, when Ronald Reagan was inaugurated and repudiated detente.” See
    • “The Soviet occupation of Afghanistan and the American response led to a sharp break from the whole course of U.S.-Soviet relations over the preceding decade,” according to Garthoff. “It gave the coup de grace to the already seriously eroded and weakened mutual policy of detente established in May 1972…. In many ways January 1980 was a sharper turning point than January 1981, when Ronald Reagan was inaugurated and repudiated detente.” See Garthoff, Detente and Confrontation, p. 967.
    • (1981) Detente and Confrontation , pp. 967
    • Garthoff1
  • 122
    • 84976056327 scopus 로고
    • Review of Bowker and Williams' Superpower Detente
    • Garthoff, in his review of this book, points to the contradictory and self-limiting assumptions that supported detente in the United States and Soviet Union: “Detente [according to Bowker and Williams] was not a cause of America's apparent weakness in the 1970s, but a hard-headed strategy devised by Kissinger and Nixon for coping with an adverse situation by managing the emergence of Soviet power. For the Soviet leaders, on the other hand, detente represented an expected opportunity to neutralize superpower relations and exercise Soviet power in a more active way in the Third World. When they did this, however, in Angola, Ethiopia and Afghanistan, the result was to undercut support for detente in the United States and lead to its collapse.” Garthoff, himself a notable student of superpower relations, sees Soviet policies in Africa and Asia as opportunistic rather than strategic. The results, however, were the same for U.S.-Soviet relations. There was a “costly failure of Soviet leaders to appreciate the adverse consequences of their involvements in the Third World on detente with the United States.” See
    • Garthoff, in his review of this book, points to the contradictory and self-limiting assumptions that supported detente in the United States and Soviet Union: “Detente [according to Bowker and Williams] was not a cause of America's apparent weakness in the 1970s, but a hard-headed strategy devised by Kissinger and Nixon for coping with an adverse situation by managing the emergence of Soviet power. For the Soviet leaders, on the other hand, detente represented an expected opportunity to neutralize superpower relations and exercise Soviet power in a more active way in the Third World. When they did this, however, in Angola, Ethiopia and Afghanistan, the result was to undercut support for detente in the United States and lead to its collapse.” Garthoff, himself a notable student of superpower relations, sees Soviet policies in Africa and Asia as opportunistic rather than strategic. The results, however, were the same for U.S.-Soviet relations. There was a “costly failure of Soviet leaders to appreciate the adverse consequences of their involvements in the Third World on detente with the United States.” See Raymond L. Garthoff, “Review of Bowker and Williams' Superpower Detente,” International Affairs 65 (Spring 1989), p. 311.
    • (1989) International Affairs , vol.65 , pp. 311
    • Garthoff, R.L.1
  • 124
    • 0039777888 scopus 로고
    • The Twilight Existence of Nonbinding International Agreements
    • The Helsinki Final Act, formally known as the Final Act of the Conference on Security and Cooperation in Europe, was concluded in, and signed by thirty-five states. On the one hand, the states declared their “determination to act in accordance with the provisions contained” in the text. On the other hand, these were not to be the binding commitments of a treaty. The text plainly said that it was not eligible for registration with the United Nations, as a treaty would be. Several democratic states, led by the United States, declared at the time that this document was not a treaty. “There does not appear to be any evidence that the other signatory states disagreed with this understanding,” according to Schachter. The result is a curious contradiction: a nonbinding bargain. It juxtaposes elaborate “commitments” with a claim that they are not to be registered, as a treaty would be. The point, clearly, is to exempt the provisions from the legally binding status of treaty commitments. For an interesting analysis of the Helsinki agreement and its ambiguous status in international law, see
    • The Helsinki Final Act, formally known as the Final Act of the Conference on Security and Cooperation in Europe, was concluded in 1975 and signed by thirty-five states. On the one hand, the states declared their “determination to act in accordance with the provisions contained” in the text. On the other hand, these were not to be the binding commitments of a treaty. The text plainly said that it was not eligible for registration with the United Nations, as a treaty would be. Several democratic states, led by the United States, declared at the time that this document was not a treaty. “There does not appear to be any evidence that the other signatory states disagreed with this understanding,” according to Schachter. The result is a curious contradiction: a nonbinding bargain. It juxtaposes elaborate “commitments” with a claim that they are not to be registered, as a treaty would be. The point, clearly, is to exempt the provisions from the legally binding status of treaty commitments. For an interesting analysis of the Helsinki agreement and its ambiguous status in international law, see Schachter, “The Twilight Existence of Nonbinding International Agreements,” p. 296.
    • (1975) , pp. 296
    • Schachter1
  • 125
    • 84925663326 scopus 로고
    • The text of the Helsinki Final Act can be found in
    • The text of the Helsinki Final Act can be found in International Legal Materials, vol. 14, 1975, pp. 1293 ff.
    • (1975) International Legal Materials , vol.14 , pp. 1293 ff
  • 126
    • 84976010420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Agreement Regulations
    • This translation of oral agreements into writing is required by the U.S. State Department's regulations implementing the Case Act. See, 22
    • This translation of oral agreements into writing is required by the U.S. State Department's regulations implementing the Case Act. See “International Agreement Regulations,” 22 Code of Federal Regulations, part 181.
    • Code of Federal Regulations
  • 127
    • 0003668102 scopus 로고
    • and 46, 13 July
    • and 46 Federal Register, 13 July 1981, pp. 35917 ff.
    • (1981) Federal Register , pp. 35917 ff
  • 128
    • 84976099892 scopus 로고
    • There is a nice irony here. Goldwyn's disparaging comments about oral agreements are themselves probably apocryphal. He regularly mangled the English language, and quotes like this were often attributed to him, whether he said them or not. The murky origins of this quotation underscore a fundamental problem with oral bargains. How can third parties ever ascertain who really promised what to whom? Goldwyn himself gave one answer to that question: “Two words: im possible.” See, (New York: William Morrow)
    • There is a nice irony here. Goldwyn's disparaging comments about oral agreements are themselves probably apocryphal. He regularly mangled the English language, and quotes like this were often attributed to him, whether he said them or not. The murky origins of this quotation underscore a fundamental problem with oral bargains. How can third parties ever ascertain who really promised what to whom? Goldwyn himself gave one answer to that question: “Two words: im possible.” See Carol Easton, The Search for Sarn Goldwyn (New York: William Morrow, 1976), pp. 150-51.
    • (1976) The Search for Sarn Goldwyn , pp. 150-151
    • Easton, C.1
  • 130
    • 84898295294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • States on the borders of a guerrilla war are vital allies to the protagonists. They offer a secure launching pad for military operations and a secure site for communications and resupply. If their role becomes too open and prominent, however, the bordering states could be brought directly into the fighting as protagonists themselves. This is clearly a delicate relationship. It is best managed by informal agreements, usually secret ones, such as those reached by the United States and Laos during the Vietnam War. See
    • States on the borders of a guerrilla war are vital allies to the protagonists. They offer a secure launching pad for military operations and a secure site for communications and resupply. If their role becomes too open and prominent, however, the bordering states could be brought directly into the fighting as protagonists themselves. This is clearly a delicate relationship. It is best managed by informal agreements, usually secret ones, such as those reached by the United States and Laos during the Vietnam War. See Johnson, The Making of International Agreements, p. 68.
    • The Making of International Agreements , pp. 68
    • Johnson1
  • 131
    • 84890780964 scopus 로고
    • The importance of secret treaties in European diplomacy was underscored when Woodrow Wilson tried to abolish the practice after World War I. Clemenceau and Lloyd George “said emphatically that they could not agree never to make a private or secret diplomatic agreement of any kind. Such understandings were the foundation of European diplomacy, and everyone knew that to abandon secret negotiations would be to invite chaos. To this [Colonel] House replied … that there was no intention to prohibit confidential talks on delicate matters, but only to require that treaties resulting from such conversations should become ‘part of the public law of the world.’” Quoted by, in, (New York: Norton)
    • The importance of secret treaties in European diplomacy was underscored when Woodrow Wilson tried to abolish the practice after World War I. Clemenceau and Lloyd George “said emphatically that they could not agree never to make a private or secret diplomatic agreement of any kind. Such understandings were the foundation of European diplomacy, and everyone knew that to abandon secret negotiations would be to invite chaos. To this [Colonel] House replied … that there was no intention to prohibit confidential talks on delicate matters, but only to require that treaties resulting from such conversations should become ‘part of the public law of the world.’” Quoted by Arthur Walworth in America's Moment: 1918—American Diplomacy at the End of World War I (New York: Norton, 1977), p. 56.
    • (1977) America's Moment: 1918—American Diplomacy at the End of World War I , pp. 56
    • Walworth, A.1
  • 132
    • 84976130344 scopus 로고
    • See “Treaty of Non-Aggression Between Germany and the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics, August 23, 1939, Signed by Ribbentrop and Molotov,” document no. 228 in United Kingdom, Foreign Office, The Last Days of Peace, August 9—September 3, 1939, series D, of, (London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office)
    • See “Treaty of Non-Aggression Between Germany and the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics, August 23, 1939, Signed by Ribbentrop and Molotov,” document no. 228 in United Kingdom, Foreign Office, The Last Days of Peace, August 9—September 3, 1939, series D, vol. 7 of Documents on German Foreign Policy, 1918-1945 (London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office, 1956), pp. 245-46. The volume provides official translations of documents from captured archives of the German Foreign Ministry and the Reich Chancellery.
    • (1956) Documents on German Foreign Policy, 1918-1945 , vol.7 , pp. 245-246
  • 134
    • 84975942157 scopus 로고
    • See “Secret Additional Protocol, September 28, 1939, Between the Government of the USSR and the Government of the German Reich,” document no. 159 in United Kingdom, Foreign Office, The War Years, September 4, 1939—March 18, 1940, series D, (London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office), The document, which was signed in Moscow by Ribbentrop and Molotov, stated the following: “The Secret Additional Protocol, signed August 23, 1939, shall be amended in item 1 to the effect that the territory of the Lithuanian states falls to the sphere of influence of the USSR, while, on the other hand, the province of Lublin and parts of the province of Warsaw fall to the sphere of influence of Germany (cf. the map attached to the Boundary and Friendship Treaty signed today).”
    • See “Secret Additional Protocol, September 28, 1939, Between the Government of the USSR and the Government of the German Reich,” document no. 159 in United Kingdom, Foreign Office, The War Years, September 4, 1939—March 18, 1940, series D, vol. 8 of Documents on German Foreign Policy, 1918-1945 (London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office, 1954), p. 166. The document, which was signed in Moscow by Ribbentrop and Molotov, stated the following: “The Secret Additional Protocol, signed August 23, 1939, shall be amended in item 1 to the effect that the territory of the Lithuanian states falls to the sphere of influence of the USSR, while, on the other hand, the province of Lublin and parts of the province of Warsaw fall to the sphere of influence of Germany (cf. the map attached to the Boundary and Friendship Treaty signed today).”
    • (1954) Documents on German Foreign Policy, 1918-1945 , vol.8 , pp. 166
  • 135
    • 84976158357 scopus 로고
    • Bonn Has Documents Soviets Don't Want Very Much to Find
    • The relevant maps and microfilms are held in the Federal Republic's Foreign Ministry. The captured documents have all been published, in the original and in translation. The Soviets long claimed that they could not find their copies and that the West German microfilms were forgeries. They held to this formulaic answer through 1989, when Baltic nationalism became a serious political challenge. The nationalists, of course, emphasized the illegitimacy of the protocols and actually published their texts as part of their rising protest of Soviet rule. In August 1989, a senior Soviet official finally acknowledged that the Soviets and Nazis had secretly divided Eastern Europe, but he insisted that the secret agreement had no bearing on the current boundaries of the Soviet Union. See, European edition, 23-24 June
    • The relevant maps and microfilms are held in the Federal Republic's Foreign Ministry. The captured documents have all been published, in the original and in translation. The Soviets long claimed that they could not find their copies and that the West German microfilms were forgeries. They held to this formulaic answer through 1989, when Baltic nationalism became a serious political challenge. The nationalists, of course, emphasized the illegitimacy of the protocols and actually published their texts as part of their rising protest of Soviet rule. In August 1989, a senior Soviet official finally acknowledged that the Soviets and Nazis had secretly divided Eastern Europe, but he insisted that the secret agreement had no bearing on the current boundaries of the Soviet Union. See Peter Gumbel, “Bonn Has Documents Soviets Don't Want Very Much to Find,” Wall Street Journal, European edition, 23-24 June 1989, pp. 1 and 10.
    • (1989) Wall Street Journal , pp. 1-10
    • Gumbel, P.1
  • 136
    • 84976069135 scopus 로고
    • Soviets Confirm Nazi Pacts Dividing Europe
    • 19 August
    • Esther B. Fein, “Soviets Confirm Nazi Pacts Dividing Europe,” The New York Times, 19 August 1989, pp. 1 and 5.
    • (1989) The New York Times , pp. 1-5
    • Fein, E.B.1
  • 137
    • 84976069135 scopus 로고
    • Soviet Congress Condemns '39 Pact That Led to Annexation of Baltics
    • 25 December
    • Esther B. Fein, “Soviet Congress Condemns '39 Pact That Led to Annexation of Baltics,” The New York Times, 25 December 1989, pp. 1 and 15.
    • (1989) The New York Times , pp. 1-15
    • Fein, E.B.1
  • 138
    • 84925624258 scopus 로고
    • Trotsky's release of the secret documents was shrewd and effective. There was a strong, sustained reaction against secret diplomacy, mainly in the Anglo-Saxon countries. Wilson himself was politically embarrassed. Either his wartime allies had not told him of their earlier bargains or they had told him and he had kept the secret, despite his principled attacks on secret diplomacy. See, of The History of Treaties and International Politics (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press)
    • Trotsky's release of the secret documents was shrewd and effective. There was a strong, sustained reaction against secret diplomacy, mainly in the Anglo-Saxon countries. Wilson himself was politically embarrassed. Either his wartime allies had not told him of their earlier bargains or they had told him and he had kept the secret, despite his principled attacks on secret diplomacy. See Mario Toscano, An Introduction to the History of Treaties and International Politics, vol. 1 of The History of Treaties and International Politics (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1966), pp. 42 and 215.
    • (1966) An Introduction to the History of Treaties and International Politics , vol.1 , pp. 42-215
    • Toscano, M.1
  • 139
    • 0039847290 scopus 로고
    • 2d ed., (Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin Books)
    • James Joll, Europe Since 1870, 2d ed. (Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin Books, 1976), p. 233.
    • (1976) Europe Since 1870 , pp. 233
    • Joll, J.1
  • 140
    • 84925656894 scopus 로고
    • Wilson's war aims were stated to a joint session of Congress on 8 January 1918. When European leaders later challenged this commitment to open covenants, Wilson announced that he would never compromise the “essentially American terms in the program,” including Point One. See, ed. by Charles Seymour (London: Ernest Benn)
    • Wilson's war aims were stated to a joint session of Congress on 8 January 1918. When European leaders later challenged this commitment to open covenants, Wilson announced that he would never compromise the “essentially American terms in the program,” including Point One. See Edward M. House, The Intimate Papers of Colonel House, vol. 4, ed. by Charles Seymour (London: Ernest Benn, 1928), pp. 182-83.
    • (1928) The Intimate Papers of Colonel House , vol.4 , pp. 182-183
    • House, E.M.1
  • 141
    • 84972202580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’
    • Baxter, “International Law in ‘Her Infinite Variety,’” p. 549.
    • Baxter1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.