-
1
-
-
0007029184
-
Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics
-
For an overview of these issues and the surrounding literature, see, (January)
-
For an overview of these issues and the surrounding literature, see Stephen D. Krasner, “Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics,” Comparative Politics (January 1984): 223–46.
-
(1984)
Comparative Politics
, pp. 223-246
-
-
Krasner, S.D.1
-
2
-
-
0002193787
-
Bringing the State Back In: Strategies of Analysis in Current Research
-
Peter B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
-
Theda Skocpol, “Bringing the State Back In: Strategies of Analysis in Current Research,” in Peter B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol, Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); and.
-
(1985)
Bringing the State Back In
-
-
Skocpol, T.1
-
3
-
-
84971135250
-
The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life
-
(September)
-
James G. March and Johan P. Olsen, “The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life” American Political Science Review 78 (September 1984): 734–49.
-
(1984)
American Political Science Review
, vol.78
, pp. 734-749
-
-
March, J.G.1
Olsen, J.P.2
-
6
-
-
0012832013
-
The New Institutionalism
-
March and Olsen, “The New Institutionalism.”
-
-
-
March1
Olsen2
-
8
-
-
0016103992
-
Free Riders and Collective Action: An Appendix to Theories of Economic Regulation
-
(Autumn)
-
“Free Riders and Collective Action: An Appendix to Theories of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Autumn 1974): 359–65.
-
(1974)
Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science
, pp. 359-365
-
-
-
9
-
-
0000420789
-
Toward a More General Theory of Regulation
-
Sam Peltzman, “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation,” Journal of Law and Economics 19 (1976): 211–40.
-
(1976)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.19
, pp. 211-240
-
-
Peltzman, S.1
-
10
-
-
0001618495
-
A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence
-
Gary Becker, “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (1983): 371–400, and.
-
(1983)
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, vol.98
, pp. 371-400
-
-
Becker, G.1
-
11
-
-
40949156133
-
Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Deadweight Costs
-
“Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Deadweight Costs” Journal of Public Economics 28 (1985): 329–47.
-
(1985)
Journal of Public Economics
, vol.28
, pp. 329-347
-
-
-
12
-
-
0002433588
-
Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions
-
For a thoughtful perspective on the positive theory of institutions, see, Herbert F. Weisberg, ed., (New York: Agathon Press)
-
For a thoughtful perspective on the positive theory of institutions, see Kenneth Shepsle, “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions,” in Herbert F. Weisberg, ed., Political Science: The Science of Politics (New York: Agathon Press, 1986).
-
(1986)
Political Science: The Science of Politics
-
-
Shepsle, K.1
-
13
-
-
84976128662
-
Modern Political Economy and the Study of Regulation
-
For a comparison of the economic theory of politics and the positive theory of institutions, see, (Paper presented at the NSF/CMU Conference on Regulation, Airlie, Va., September 12–14)
-
For a comparison of the economic theory of politics and the positive theory of institutions, see Thomas Romer and Howard Rosenthal, “Modern Political Economy and the Study of Regulation” (Paper presented at the NSF/CMU Conference on Regulation, Airlie, Va., September 12–14, 1985).
-
(1985)
-
-
Romer, T.1
Rosenthal, H.2
-
14
-
-
84931833250
-
Congressional Committee Members as Independent Agency Overseers
-
Seymour Scher, “Congressional Committee Members as Independent Agency Overseers,” American Political Science Review 54 (1986): 911–20.
-
(1986)
American Political Science Review
, vol.54
, pp. 911-920
-
-
Scher, S.1
-
15
-
-
0003579536
-
-
See especially, (New York: Basic Books), Wilson has been most responsible for popularizing this environmental typology, which has found its way into both the economic theory of politics and the positive theory of institutions
-
See especially James Q. Wilson, The Politics of Regulation (New York: Basic Books, 1980). Wilson has been most responsible for popularizing this environmental typology, which has found its way into both the economic theory of politics and the positive theory of institutions.
-
(1980)
The Politics of Regulation
-
-
Wilson, J.Q.1
-
16
-
-
0004124667
-
-
On the politics surrounding the creation and early years of the NLRB, see, (Albany: State University of New York Press)
-
On the politics surrounding the creation and early years of the NLRB, see James A. Gross, The Making of the National Labor Relations Board (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1974).
-
(1974)
The Making of the National Labor Relations Board
-
-
Gross, J.A.1
-
18
-
-
0004258506
-
-
(Boston: Houghton Mifflin)
-
Turbulent Years (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1970).
-
(1970)
Turbulent Years
-
-
-
21
-
-
0004060897
-
-
(Princeton: Princeton University Press)
-
Peter H. Irons, The New Deal Lawyers (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1982).
-
(1982)
The New Deal Lawyers
-
-
Irons, P.H.1
-
22
-
-
0004124667
-
-
On the politics leading up to Taft-Hartley, see especially, (Albany: State University of New York Press)
-
On the politics leading up to Taft-Hartley, see especially James A. Gross, The Reshaping of the National Labor Relations Board (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1981).
-
(1981)
The Reshaping of the National Labor Relations Board
-
-
Gross, J.A.1
-
23
-
-
84925887573
-
-
For an overview of the provisions of the Wagner and Taft-Hartley acts, as well as other aspects of the board's mandate, see, (New York: Praeger Press)
-
For an overview of the provisions of the Wagner and Taft-Hartley acts, as well as other aspects of the board's mandate, see Frank W. McCulloch and Tim Bornstein, The National Labor Relations Board (New York: Praeger Press, 1974).
-
(1974)
The National Labor Relations Board
-
-
McCulloch, F.W.1
Bornstein, T.2
-
24
-
-
84976167886
-
The National Labor Relations Board and Congress: A Study of Legislative Control of Regulatory Activity
-
Perhaps the most exhaustive account of the NLRB'S tumultuous politics in the Truman and early Eisenhower years is provided by Seymour Scher, (Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago). I draw on his account here and in the remaining paragraphs of this section
-
Perhaps the most exhaustive account of the NLRB'S tumultuous politics in the Truman and early Eisenhower years is provided by Seymour Scher, “The National Labor Relations Board and Congress: A Study of Legislative Control of Regulatory Activity” (Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago, 1956). I draw on his account here and in the remaining paragraphs of this section.
-
(1956)
-
-
-
26
-
-
84884097499
-
Are We Becoming a ‘Laboristic’ State?
-
May 16
-
Sumner H. Slichter, “Are We Becoming a ‘Laboristic’ State?” New York Times Magazine, May 16, 1948: 11ff.
-
(1948)
New York Times Magazine
, pp. 11ff
-
-
Slichter, S.H.1
-
29
-
-
1842649819
-
-
On the unions' organizational decline, see, for example, (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies)
-
On the unions' organizational decline, see, for example, Seymour Martin Lipset, ed., Unions in Transition (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies, 1986).
-
(1986)
Unions in Transition
-
-
Lipset, S.M.1
-
31
-
-
0040106637
-
The Transformation of the Industrial Relations and Personnel Function
-
On the transformation of labor relations within big business, see, Paul Osterman, ed., (Cambridge: MIT Press)
-
On the transformation of labor relations within big business, see Thomas A. Kochan and Peter Capelli, “The Transformation of the Industrial Relations and Personnel Function,” in Paul Osterman, ed., Internal Labor Markets (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1984).
-
(1984)
Internal Labor Markets
-
-
Kochan, T.A.1
Capelli, P.2
-
33
-
-
84987335958
-
Industrial Relations: Time of Change
-
(Winter)
-
George Strauss, “Industrial Relations: Time of Change,” Industrial Relations 23 (Winter 1984): 1–15.
-
(1984)
Industrial Relations
, vol.23
, pp. 1-15
-
-
Strauss, G.1
-
34
-
-
0039809396
-
Management Performance
-
Jack Steiber, Robert B. McKersie, and D. Quinn Mills, eds., (Madison, Wisc.: Industrial Relations Research Association)
-
D. Quinn Mills, “Management Performance,” in Jack Steiber, Robert B. McKersie, and D. Quinn Mills, eds., U.S. Industrial Relations 1950–1980: A Critical Assessment (Madison, Wisc.: Industrial Relations Research Association, 1981).
-
(1981)
U.S. Industrial Relations 1950–1980: A Critical Assessment
-
-
Mills, D.Q.1
-
36
-
-
84976047725
-
); and
-
A nice illustration of the political cleavage between big-business moderates and small-business extremists can be found in Scher, See also Sar, (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press
-
A nice illustration of the political cleavage between big-business moderates and small-business extremists can be found in Scher, “The National Labor Relations Board and Congress.” See also Sar A. Levitan and Martha R. Cooper, Business Lobbies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1984); and.
-
(1984)
Business Lobbies
-
-
Levitan, A.1
Cooper, M.R.2
-
38
-
-
84936824515
-
-
On the logic of cooperation among self-interested actors, see, (New York: Basic Books)
-
On the logic of cooperation among self-interested actors, see Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984).
-
(1984)
The Evolution of Cooperation
-
-
Axelrod, R.1
-
39
-
-
0003358829
-
The Politicized Presidency
-
See, (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution)
-
See Terry M. Moe, “The Politicized Presidency,” in John E. Chubb and Paul E. Peterson, The New Direction in American Politics (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1985).
-
(1985)
The New Direction in American Politics
-
-
Chubb, J.E.1
Peterson, P.E.2
-
40
-
-
0004152262
-
-
Note that the repeated-game logic of cooperation applies to the historical emergence of these norms, just as it does to the relationship between business and labor in their struggle for influence. See Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation, for discussion of its widespread applicability to politics. The literature on appointments per se, however, is not oriented by this or any other theory. The most comprehensive overview can be found in, (New York: Free Press)
-
Note that the repeated-game logic of cooperation applies to the historical emergence of these norms, just as it does to the relationship between business and labor in their struggle for influence. See Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation, for discussion of its widespread applicability to politics. The literature on appointments per se, however, is not oriented by this or any other theory. The most comprehensive overview can be found in G. Calvin Mackenzie, The Politics of Presidential Appointments (New York: Free Press, 1981).
-
(1981)
The Politics of Presidential Appointments
-
-
Mackenzie, G.C.1
-
41
-
-
84936018509
-
Control and Feedback in Economic Regulation: The Case of the NLRB
-
See
-
See Terry M. Moe, “Control and Feedback in Economic Regulation: The Case of the NLRB,” American Political Science Review 79 (1985): 1094–1116.
-
(1985)
American Political Science Review
, vol.79
, pp. 1094-1116
-
-
Moe, T.M.1
-
42
-
-
6144223444
-
The Determinants of Voting by the National Labor Relations Board on Unfair Labor Practice Cases: 1955–1975
-
Charles D. Delorme, R. C. Hill, and Norman J. Wood
-
McCulloch and Bornstein, The National Labor Relations Board; Charles D. Delorme, R. C. Hill, and Norman J. Wood, “The Determinants of Voting by the National Labor Relations Board on Unfair Labor Practice Cases: 1955–1975,” Public Choice 37 (1981): 207–18.
-
(1981)
Public Choice
, vol.37
, pp. 207-218
-
-
McCulloch, B.1
-
43
-
-
0010042301
-
Political Bias in NLRB Unfair Labor Practice Decisions
-
William N. Cooke and Frederick H. Gautschi III, “Political Bias in NLRB Unfair Labor Practice Decisions,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 35 (1982): 539–49.
-
(1982)
Industrial and Labor Relations Review
, vol.35
, pp. 539-549
-
-
Cooke, W.N.1
Frederick, H.G.2
-
44
-
-
84902390972
-
-
(Washington, D.C.: Labor Policy Association)
-
Kenneth McGuiness, The New Frontier NLRB (Washington, D.C.: Labor Policy Association, 1963).
-
(1963)
The New Frontier NLRB
-
-
McGuiness, K.1
-
45
-
-
0004124667
-
-
For accounts of NLRB personnel problems (at all levels) during the early years—along with the political problems they caused—see
-
For accounts of NLRB personnel problems (at all levels) during the early years—along with the political problems they caused—see Gross, The Reshaping of the National Labor Relations Board, and.
-
The Reshaping of the National Labor Relations Board
-
-
Gross1
-
46
-
-
84976047740
-
The National Labor Relations Board and Congress
-
Scher, “The National Labor Relations Board and Congress.”
-
-
-
Scher1
-
47
-
-
0040596909
-
-
For an account of the politics surrounding Landrum-Griffin, see, (New York: Columbia University Press)
-
For an account of the politics surrounding Landrum-Griffin, see Alan K. McAdams, Power and Politics in labor Legislation (New York: Columbia University Press, 1964).
-
(1964)
Power and Politics in labor Legislation
-
-
McAdams, A.K.1
-
48
-
-
0040750712
-
-
See, for example, (New York: Atheneum)
-
See, for example, Joseph Goulden, Meany (New York: Atheneum, 1972).
-
(1972)
Meany
-
-
Goulden, J.1
-
49
-
-
0039264978
-
-
For accounts of these turbulent years, see, for example
-
For accounts of these turbulent years, see, for example, Levitan and Cooper, Business Lobbies.
-
Business Lobbies
-
-
Levitan1
Cooper2
-
51
-
-
84976096756
-
-
The following is based largely on interviews and news accounts. For general treatments of Reagan's appointments strategy, see National Academy of Public Administration, (Washington, D.C.: National Academy of Public Administrations)
-
The following is based largely on interviews and news accounts. For general treatments of Reagan's appointments strategy, see National Academy of Public Administration, Recruiting Presidential Appointees (Washington, D.C.: National Academy of Public Administrations, 1985).
-
(1985)
Recruiting Presidential Appointees
-
-
-
53
-
-
84976136760
-
-
See, for example, August 28
-
See, for example, Congressional Quarterly, August 28, 1982, 2113–14.
-
(1982)
Congressional Quarterly
, pp. 2113-2114
-
-
-
54
-
-
84950025271
-
-
See, for example, July 6
-
See, for example, Business Week, July 6, 1981, 27–28.
-
(1981)
Business Week
, pp. 27-28
-
-
-
55
-
-
84976081388
-
The New Antiunion Crusade: How Reagan's NLRB Is Subverting Industrial Democracy
-
September
-
See, for example, Penn Kemble, “The New Antiunion Crusade: How Reagan's NLRB Is Subverting Industrial Democracy,” New Republic, September 1983, 18–20.
-
(1983)
New Republic
, pp. 18-20
-
-
Kemble, P.1
-
56
-
-
84957306426
-
-
June 11
-
Business Week, June 11, 1984, 122.
-
(1984)
Business Week
, pp. 122
-
-
-
57
-
-
84976069084
-
-
December 29
-
Congressional Quarterly, December 29, 1984, 3168.
-
(1984)
Congressional Quarterly
, pp. 3168
-
-
-
58
-
-
0004255495
-
-
See, for example, March 25
-
See, for example, Business Week, March 25, 1985, 34.
-
(1985)
Business Week
, pp. 34
-
-
-
59
-
-
84976081454
-
The New Antiunion Crusade
-
Quoted in Kemble
-
Quoted in Kemble, “The New Antiunion Crusade,” 20.
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
84975950204
-
Industrial Relations: Time of Change
-
Strauss, “Industrial Relations: Time of Change”.
-
-
-
Strauss1
-
62
-
-
0040968381
-
The Rise and Fall of American Trade Unions: The Labor Movement from FDR to RR
-
in Lipset
-
Leo Troy, “The Rise and Fall of American Trade Unions: The Labor Movement from FDR to RR,” in Lipset, Unions in Transition.
-
Unions in Transition
-
-
Troy, L.1
-
64
-
-
84965394414
-
-
(Boston: Little, Brown & Co.)
-
and Inside Bureaucracy (Boston: Little, Brown & Co., 1966).
-
(1966)
Inside Bureaucracy
-
-
-
68
-
-
84935997850
-
Constituency Interest and Congressional Voting
-
See
-
See Same Peltzman, “Constituency Interest and Congressional Voting,” Journal of Law and Economics 27 (1984): 181–210.
-
(1984)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.27
, pp. 181-210
-
-
Peltzman, S.1
-
69
-
-
0007011470
-
Toward a More General Theory of Regulation
-
Peltzman, “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.”
-
-
-
Peltzman1
-
70
-
-
84976057212
-
A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence
-
Becker, “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.”
-
-
-
Becker1
-
71
-
-
0001691071
-
Economic Perspectives on the Politics of Regulation
-
For a review and critique of this literature, see, Richard Schmalensee and Robert Willig, eds., (Amsterdam: Elsevier, forthcoming)
-
For a review and critique of this literature, see Roger Noll, “Economic Perspectives on the Politics of Regulation,” in Richard Schmalensee and Robert Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization (Amsterdam: Elsevier, forthcoming).
-
Handbook of Industrial Organization
-
-
Noll, R.1
-
75
-
-
0001691071
-
Economic Perspectives on the Politics of Regulation
-
Coase's theorem, along with its assumption of zero transactions costs, has direct implications—never thoroughly addressed by writers in this tradition, to my knowledge—for the economic theory's perspective on political control and other aspects of institutional politics. It is also inconsistent with Olson's logic of mobilization. These issues will be considered later. For one account (somewhat different from mine) of how transactions costs figure into the economic theory, see
-
Coase's theorem, along with its assumption of zero transactions costs, has direct implications—never thoroughly addressed by writers in this tradition, to my knowledge—for the economic theory's perspective on political control and other aspects of institutional politics. It is also inconsistent with Olson's logic of mobilization. These issues will be considered later. For one account (somewhat different from mine) of how transactions costs figure into the economic theory, see Noll, “Economic Perspectives on the Politics of Regulation”.
-
-
-
Noll1
-
77
-
-
0002790687
-
Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models
-
See
-
See Kenneth A. Shepsle, “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models,” American Journal of Political Science 23 (1979): 27–60.
-
(1979)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.23
, pp. 27-60
-
-
Shepsle, K.A.1
-
78
-
-
0013547776
-
Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions
-
Shepsle, “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions”.
-
-
-
Shepsle1
-
79
-
-
84971145641
-
Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of Institutions
-
William H. Riker, “Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of Institutions,” American Political Science Review 74 (1980): 432–47.
-
(1980)
American Political Science Review
, vol.74
, pp. 432-447
-
-
Riker, W.H.1
-
80
-
-
34250241742
-
Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice
-
Kenneth A. Shepsle and Barry R. Weingast, “Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice,” Public Choice 37 (1981): 503–19.
-
(1981)
Public Choice
, vol.37
, pp. 503-519
-
-
Shepsle, K.A.1
Weingast, B.R.2
-
81
-
-
84976081502
-
Gatekeeping and Monopoly Power of Committees: An Analysis of Sincere and Sophisticated Behavior
-
In addition to the above cited works, see, for example, (December)
-
In addition to the above cited works, see, for example, Arthur T. Denzau and Robert J. Mackay, “Gatekeeping and Monopoly Power of Committees: An Analysis of Sincere and Sophisticated Behavior,” American Journal of Political Science 27 (December 1985): 1117–34.
-
(1985)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.27
, pp. 1117-1134
-
-
Denzau, A.T.1
Mackay, R.J.2
-
82
-
-
84976149928
-
The Industrial Organization of Congress
-
(Stanford: Hoover Institution)
-
Barry R. Weingast and William J. Marshall, “The Industrial Organization of Congress,” Working Papers in Economics (Stanford: Hoover Institution, 1986).
-
(1986)
Working Papers in Economics
-
-
Weingast, B.R.1
Marshall, W.J.2
-
83
-
-
84975942103
-
Political Control and Agency Discretion: The Fallacy of Execution
-
(Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, August)
-
See, for example, Randall L. Calvert, Mathew D. McCubbins, and Barry R. Weingast, “Political Control and Agency Discretion: The Fallacy of Execution” (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 1986).
-
(1986)
-
-
Calvert, R.L.1
McCubbins, M.D.2
Weingast, B.R.3
-
84
-
-
84976127430
-
Presidents, Congress, and the ‘Congressional Control of Administration’ Hypothesis
-
(Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, August)
-
Thomas H. Hammond, Jeffrey S. Hill, and Gary J. Miller, “Presidents, Congress, and the ‘Congressional Control of Administration’ Hypothesis” (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, August, 1986).
-
(1986)
-
-
Hammond, T.H.1
Hill, J.S.2
Miller, G.J.3
-
85
-
-
84881995626
-
The Power to Veto
-
Working Papers in Political Science (Stanford: Hoover Institution)
-
Robert J. Mackay and Carolyn L. Weaver, “The Power to Veto,” Working Papers in Political Science (Stanford: Hoover Institution, 1986).
-
(1986)
-
-
Mackay, R.J.1
Weaver, C.L.2
-
86
-
-
0000796326
-
Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission
-
See, for example
-
See, for example, Barry R. Weingast and Mark J. Moran, “Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission,” Journal of Political Economy 91 (1983): 765–800.
-
(1983)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.91
, pp. 765-800
-
-
Weingast, B.R.1
Moran, M.J.2
-
87
-
-
34248440746
-
The Congressional-Bureaucratic System: A Principal-Agent Perspective with Applications to the SEC
-
Barry R. Weingast, “The Congressional-Bureaucratic System: A Principal-Agent Perspective with Applications to the SEC,” Public Choke 44 (1984): 147–92.
-
(1984)
Public Choke
, vol.44
, pp. 147-192
-
-
Weingast, B.R.1
-
88
-
-
0012692294
-
A Political Theory of Regulation with Some Observations on Railway Abandonments
-
Richard Barke and William Riker, “A Political Theory of Regulation with Some Observations on Railway Abandonments,” Public Choice 39 (1982): 73–106.
-
(1982)
Public Choice
, vol.39
, pp. 73-106
-
-
Barke, R.1
Riker, W.2
-
89
-
-
84935117599
-
Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms
-
Mathew D. McCubbins and Thomas Schwartz, “Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms,” American Journal of Political Science 28 (1984): 165–79.
-
(1984)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.28
, pp. 165-179
-
-
McCubbins, M.D.1
Schwartz, T.2
-
90
-
-
84935847115
-
The Legislative Design of Regulatory Structure
-
Mathew D. McCubbins, “The Legislative Design of Regulatory Structure,” American Journal of Political Science 29 (1985): 721–48.
-
(1985)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.29
, pp. 721-748
-
-
McCubbins, M.D.1
-
91
-
-
30944435969
-
Legislative Choice of Regulatory Forms: Legal Process or Administrative Process?
-
Morris P. Fiorina, “Legislative Choice of Regulatory Forms: Legal Process or Administrative Process?” Public Choice 39 (1982): 33–66.
-
(1982)
Public Choice
, vol.39
, pp. 33-66
-
-
Fiorina, M.P.1
-
92
-
-
84935978932
-
The New Economics of Organization
-
For an overview with applications to politics, see
-
For an overview with applications to politics, see Terry M. Moe, “The New Economics of Organization,” American Journal of Political Science 28 (1984); 739–77.
-
(1984)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.28
, pp. 739-777
-
-
Moe, T.M.1
-
94
-
-
84956404975
-
The Industrial Organization of Congress
-
Weingast and Marshall, “The Industrial Organization of Congress”.
-
-
-
Weingast1
Marshall2
-
95
-
-
84979188687
-
The Nature of the Firm
-
There is an interesting irony at work here: the new economics of organization traces its roots to a seminal article by Coase, in which he argued that organizations arise because of—and therefore are explained by—attempts by rational actors to minimize transactions costs. See, Thus, the economic theory of politics and the positive theory of institutions are both grounded in classic articles by Coase—but they are different articles that proceed from diametrically opposed assumptions. His “Nature of the Firm” assumes transactions costs are substantial and uses this to explain the emergence of organizations. “The Problem of Social Cost” argues that, in a world of zero transactions costs, individuals can overcome collective action problems through market exchange. There is nothing inconsistent about the two arguments per se. The economic theory tends to adopt a “negligible transactions costs” view of the world, whereas PTI and the new economics of organization tend to embrace a “high transactions costs” view—with very different consequences, obviously, for their explanations of politics
-
There is an interesting irony at work here: the new economics of organization traces its roots to a seminal article by Coase, in which he argued that organizations arise because of—and therefore are explained by—attempts by rational actors to minimize transactions costs. See Ronald Coase, “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica 4 (1937): 386–405. Thus, the economic theory of politics and the positive theory of institutions are both grounded in classic articles by Coase—but they are different articles that proceed from diametrically opposed assumptions. His “Nature of the Firm” assumes transactions costs are substantial and uses this to explain the emergence of organizations. “The Problem of Social Cost” argues that, in a world of zero transactions costs, individuals can overcome collective action problems through market exchange. There is nothing inconsistent about the two arguments per se. The economic theory tends to adopt a “negligible transactions costs” view of the world, whereas PTI and the new economics of organization tend to embrace a “high transactions costs” view—with very different consequences, obviously, for their explanations of politics.
-
(1937)
Economica
, vol.4
, pp. 386-405
-
-
Coase, R.1
-
97
-
-
0013547776
-
Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions
-
Shepsle, “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions”.
-
-
-
Shepsle1
-
98
-
-
84976146179
-
The Legislative Design of Regulatory Structures
-
McCubbins, “The Legislative Design of Regulatory Structures”.
-
-
-
McCubbins1
-
99
-
-
84975950318
-
The Role of Reputation and Legislative Leadership
-
(Mimeo, Washington University, St. Louis)
-
Calvert, “The Role of Reputation and Legislative Leadership” (Mimeo, Washington University, St. Louis, 1986).
-
(1986)
-
-
Calvert1
-
100
-
-
0013547776
-
Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions
-
For a discussion of some of the issues surrounding institutional “inertia,” see
-
For a discussion of some of the issues surrounding institutional “inertia,” see Shepsle, “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions”.
-
-
-
Shepsle1
-
101
-
-
0003405228
-
-
Two points should be made here. First, the all-or-nothing nature of majoritarian elections (an institutional property) and candidate strategies (which are institutionally conditioned) imply that virtually identical constituencies might elect politicians with very different support coalitions; even though both politicians might subsequently act as conduits, very different constituency interests would get reflected in their political choices. See, (Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath), Second, because transactions costs are so high, constituents cannot achieve a high degree of control over politicians. Were politicians motivated to pursue their own policy preferences (were they ideological, for instance), they would have some flexibility to do so even in the presence of electoral constraints. PTI typically assumes, however, that politicians care only about reelection and that their policy preferences are entirely induced, so these sorts of control issues are rarely explored
-
Two points should be made here. First, the all-or-nothing nature of majoritarian elections (an institutional property) and candidate strategies (which are institutionally conditioned) imply that virtually identical constituencies might elect politicians with very different support coalitions; even though both politicians might subsequently act as conduits, very different constituency interests would get reflected in their political choices. See Morris P. Fiorina, Representatives, Roll Calls, and Their Constituents (Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1974). Second, because transactions costs are so high, constituents cannot achieve a high degree of control over politicians. Were politicians motivated to pursue their own policy preferences (were they ideological, for instance), they would have some flexibility to do so even in the presence of electoral constraints. PTI typically assumes, however, that politicians care only about reelection and that their policy preferences are entirely induced, so these sorts of control issues are rarely explored.
-
(1974)
Representatives, Roll Calls, and Their Constituents
-
-
Fiorina, M.P.1
-
102
-
-
0000084828
-
Self-Interest, Ideology, and Logrolling in Congressional Voting
-
For early attempts to do so, see
-
For early attempts to do so, see James B. Kau and Paul H. Rubin, “Self-Interest, Ideology, and Logrolling in Congressional Voting” Journal of Law and Economics 22 (1979): 365–85.
-
(1979)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.22
, pp. 365-385
-
-
Kau, J.B.1
Rubin, P.H.2
-
103
-
-
0000746905
-
Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics
-
Joseph Kalt and Mark Zupan, “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics,” American Economic Review 74 (1984): 279–300.
-
(1984)
American Economic Review
, vol.74
, pp. 279-300
-
-
Kalt, J.1
Zupan, M.2
-
104
-
-
84935940048
-
Congressional Control of the Bureaucracy: An Assessment of the Positive Theory of ‘Congressional Dominance’
-
For a general discussion of these issues, see, forthcoming
-
For a general discussion of these issues, see Terry M. Moe, “Congressional Control of the Bureaucracy: An Assessment of the Positive Theory of ‘Congressional Dominance’,” Legislative Studies Quarterly 12 (1987): forthcoming.
-
(1987)
Legislative Studies Quarterly
, vol.12
-
-
Moe, T.M.1
-
105
-
-
84935117599
-
Congressional Oversight Overlooked
-
McCubbins and Schwartz, “Congressional Oversight Overlooked.”
-
-
-
McCubbins, S.1
-
106
-
-
0004219816
-
-
For an attempt to extend Olson's logic to issues of organization, see, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press)
-
For an attempt to extend Olson's logic to issues of organization, see Terry M. Moe, The Organization of Interests (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980).
-
(1980)
The Organization of Interests
-
-
Moe, T.M.1
-
107
-
-
84976149960
-
Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics
-
See
-
See Kalt and Zupan, “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics.”
-
-
-
Kalt1
Zupan2
-
109
-
-
0000119792
-
A Rational Choice Perspective on Congressional Norms
-
Weingast, “A Rational Choice Perspective on Congressional Norms,” American Journal of Political Science 23 (1979): 245–62.
-
(1979)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.23
, pp. 245-262
-
-
Weingast1
-
110
-
-
84976146179
-
The Legislative Design of Regulatory Structure
-
There have been some promising moves in this direction within PTI, but they still get back to notions of direct control. McCubbins, for instance, argues that agencies are largely controlled by virtue of the structural—programmatic, organizational, procedural—constraints imposed by Congress. Once these are in place, Congress “controls” the agency without intense monitoring and all the rest. His assumption, however, is that legislators design these structural constraints for optimal control—this is their purpose. Thus, it is ultimately grounded in a model of conscious, intentional control. See, Much the same can be said of McCubbins and Schwartz, who argue that legislators have little incentive to engage in continuous oversight for control purposes (“police patrol” oversight), that their incentive instead is to intervene in response to constituency “fire alarms.” When these bells go off, however, they wield their various rewards and sanctions to whip bureaucrats back into line. Again, bureaucrats are held in check by direct efforts to control their behavior
-
There have been some promising moves in this direction within PTI, but they still get back to notions of direct control. McCubbins, for instance, argues that agencies are largely controlled by virtue of the structural—programmatic, organizational, procedural—constraints imposed by Congress. Once these are in place, Congress “controls” the agency without intense monitoring and all the rest. His assumption, however, is that legislators design these structural constraints for optimal control—this is their purpose. Thus, it is ultimately grounded in a model of conscious, intentional control. See McCubbins, “The Legislative Design of Regulatory Structure.” Much the same can be said of McCubbins and Schwartz, who argue that legislators have little incentive to engage in continuous oversight for control purposes (“police patrol” oversight), that their incentive instead is to intervene in response to constituency “fire alarms.” When these bells go off, however, they wield their various rewards and sanctions to whip bureaucrats back into line. Again, bureaucrats are held in check by direct efforts to control their behavior.
-
-
-
McCubbins1
-
111
-
-
84935117599
-
Congressional Oversight Overlooked
-
See
-
See McCubbins and Schwartz, “Congressional Oversight Overlooked”.
-
-
-
McCubbins, S.1
-
112
-
-
84976057262
-
Bureaucratic Discretion or Legislative Control?
-
See especially
-
See especially Weingast and Moran, “Bureaucratic Discretion or Legislative Control?”.
-
-
-
Weingast1
Moran2
-
113
-
-
0003579536
-
-
This general perspective on professionalism and political control is widely accepted in political science and is not confined to PTI. See, for example
-
This general perspective on professionalism and political control is widely accepted in political science and is not confined to PTI. See, for example, James Q. Wilson, The Politics of Regulation, and.
-
The Politics of Regulation
-
-
Wilson, J.Q.1
-
114
-
-
0003444019
-
-
3rd ed. (Boston: Little, Brown & Co.)
-
Francis E. Rourke, Bureaucracy, Politics, and Public Policy, 3rd ed. (Boston: Little, Brown & Co., 1984).
-
(1984)
Bureaucracy, Politics, and Public Policy
-
-
Rourke, F.E.1
-
115
-
-
84976182492
-
A Rational Choice Perspective on Congressional Norms
-
See
-
See Weingast, “A Rational Choice Perspective on Congressional Norms.”
-
-
-
Weingast1
-
117
-
-
0013547776
-
Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions
-
For a discussion of their relevance to PTI and its further development, see
-
For a discussion of their relevance to PTI and its further development, see Shepsle, “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions”.
-
-
-
Shepsle1
-
118
-
-
84976152298
-
Modern Political Economy and the Study of Regulation
-
See
-
See Romer and Rosenthal, “Modern Political Economy and the Study of Regulation”.
-
-
-
Romer1
Rosenthal2
-
120
-
-
0012832013
-
The New Institutionalism
-
See, for a review
-
See March and Olsen, “The New Institutionalism,” for a review.
-
-
-
March1
Olsen2
-
121
-
-
0004027370
-
-
See, for example, (Princeton: Princeton University Press)
-
See, for example, Robert Keohane, After Hegemony (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984).
-
(1984)
After Hegemony
-
-
Keohane, R.1
-
122
-
-
84974185472
-
The Theory of Games and the Problem of International Cooperation
-
R. Harrison Wagner, “The Theory of Games and the Problem of International Cooperation,” American Political Science Review 77 (1983): 330–46.
-
(1983)
American Political Science Review
, vol.77
, pp. 330-346
-
-
Wagner, R.H.1
|