메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 65, Issue 4, 1991, Pages 781-824

Strategy and Irreversibility in Supplier Relations: The Case of the U.S. Automobile Industry

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84972298480     PISSN: 00076805     EISSN: 2044768X     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/3117265     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (182)

References (91)
  • 1
    • 84972129815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supplier
    • to encompass both financially independent downstream firms and vertically integrated divisions.
    • Throughout this article, I use the term “supplier” to encompass both financially independent downstream firms and vertically integrated divisions.
  • 2
  • 3
    • 84972213224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • structure
    • I refer to the nature of relationships among firms (as defined in the next section) as well as traditional industrial organization variables such as concentration ratio, barriers to entry, and rate of technical change.
    • By “structure” I refer to the nature of relationships among firms (as defined in the next section) as well as traditional industrial organization variables such as concentration ratio, barriers to entry, and rate of technical change.
  • 5
    • 84974117709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • technical progress
    • very broadly; I mean it to encompass invention, innovation, and diffusion by both supplying and buying firms. I specifically wish to include organizational innovations such as just-in-time inventory techniques and quality assurance methods such as statistical process control.
    • I use the term “technical progress” very broadly; I mean it to encompass invention, innovation, and diffusion by both supplying and buying firms. I specifically wish to include organizational innovations such as just-in-time inventory techniques and quality assurance methods such as statistical process control.
  • 6
    • 84972454827 scopus 로고
    • Markets and Hierarchies, and the articles cited in David L. Kaserman
    • See, for example, Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies, and the articles cited in David L. Kaserman, “Theories of Vertical Integration: Implications for Antitrust Policy,” Antitrust Bulletin 25 (Fall 1978): 105–28.
    • (1978) Theories of Vertical Integration: Implications for Antitrust Policy , vol.25 , pp. 105-128
    • Williamson1
  • 7
    • 70350127859 scopus 로고
    • Prices vs. Quantities and Vertical Integration
    • M. Therese Flaherty, “Prices vs. Quantities and Vertical Integration,” Bell Journal of Economics 12 (Autumn 1981): 507–25.
    • (1981) Bell Journal of Economics , vol.12 , pp. 507-525
  • 8
    • 0007034478 scopus 로고
    • Supplier Relations and Technical Change: Theory and Application to the US Auto Industry
    • See Susan Helper, “Supplier Relations and Technical Change: Theory and Application to the US Auto Industry” (Ph.D. diss., Harvard University, 1987), and Helper, “An Exit-Voice Analysis of Supplier Relations,” in Morality, Rationality, and Efficiency: New Perspectives on Socio-economics, ed. Richard M. Coughlin (New York, 1991), for more detail.
    • (1987) Ph.D. diss., Harvard University
    • Helper, S.1
  • 9
    • 84972413559 scopus 로고
    • Signetics (A)
    • Stanford Business School Case, “Signetics (A),” 15, and “Signetics (B),” 8, Stanford, Calif., 1982.
    • (1982) Stanford Business School Case , vol.15
  • 10
    • 84972192436 scopus 로고
    • For an alternative conception of incentive systems in supplier relationships, see M. O'Hare, Robert Leone, and M. Zegans, “Privatization of Prisons: A Managerial Perspective” in Private Prisons and the Public Interest, ed. Douglas C. McDonald (New Brunswick, N.J., 1988).
    • (1988) New Brunswick, N.J.
    • McDonald, D.C.1
  • 11
    • 0038288879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For formal analysis of this proposition, see Helper, “Supplier Relations and Technical Change,” chap. 6, and Helper and David I. Levine, “Long-Term Supplier Relations and Product-Market Structure,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 8 (Oct. 1992): 561–81.
    • (1992) Supplier Relations and Technical Change , pp. 561-581
    • Helper1
  • 12
    • 84972200955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Exit-Voice Analysis
    • See Helper, “An Exit-Voice Analysis,” and Helper, “Supplier Relations and Technical Change,” for details.
    • Helper1
  • 13
    • 0003418618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Baltimore, Md.
    • Of course, some technical changes (for example, the invention of the personal computer) require neither very much capital nor very much buyer-specific information exchange. However, these types of technical changes are less likely to be practical in a mature industry such as automobiles, in which huge investments in physical and organizational capital specific to a particular way of doing things have been built up over time. See William J. Abernathy, The Productivity Dilemma: Roadblock to Innovation in the Automobile Industry (Baltimore, Md., 1978); William J. Abernathy and Kenneth Wayne, “The Limits of the Learning Curve,” Harvard Business Review 52 (Sept.-Oct. 1974): 109–19; Abernathy and Kim Clark, “Mapping the Winds of Creative Destruction,” Research Policy 14 (Feb. 1985): 3–22; and Kim Clark, “Managing Technology in International Competition: The Case of Product Development in Response to Foreign Entry,” Harvard Business School Working Paper (Boston, Mass., 1985).
    • (1978) The Productivity Dilemma: Roadblock to Innovation in the Automobile Industry
    • Abernathy, W.J.1
  • 15
    • 0002858147 scopus 로고
    • Managing Our Way to Economic Decline
    • On U.S. managers’ short time horizon, see, for example, Robert Hayes and William Abernathy, “Managing Our Way to Economic Decline,” Harvard Business Review 58 (July-Aug. 1980): 67–77. In contrast, supplier relations in the Japanese auto industry seem better characterized as a case of continuous voice, as Susan Helper, “Comparative Supplier Relations in the US and Japanese Auto Industries,” Business and Economic History, 2d ser. (1990): 153–62, shows.
    • (1980) Harvard Business Review , vol.58 , pp. 67-77
    • Hayes, R.1    Abernathy, W.2
  • 18
    • 0011491904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York
    • Allan Nevins and Frank Hill, Ford: The Times, The Man, The Company (New York, 1954), 232; Nevins and Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge (New York, 1957), 22–23, 88ff., 173–74; Nathan Rosenberg, Perspectives on Technology (New York, 1976); Richard Langlois and Paul Robertson, “Innovation and Vertical Integration in the American Automobile Industry, 1900–1940,” Working Paper, Department of Economics and Management, University College, University of New South Wales, Canberra, Australia, 13.
    • (1954) Ford: The Times, The Man, The Company , pp. 232
    • Nevins, A.1    Hill, F.2
  • 23
    • 34147173129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dodge v. Ford Motor Company, 1070 Mich Sup. Ct. Briefs and Records, cited in Seltzer, A Financial History, 101.
    • A Financial History , pp. 101
    • Seltzer1
  • 26
    • 0000827401 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration, Appropriable Quasi-Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process
    • Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford, and Armen A. Alchian, “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Quasi-Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process,” Journal of Law and Economics 21 (1978): 297; Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., and Stephen Salsbury, Pierre S. du Pont and the Making of the Modern Corporation (New York, 1971).
    • (1978) Journal of Law and Economics , vol.21 , pp. 297
    • Crawford, R.G.1    Alchian, A.A.2
  • 27
    • 84974465495 scopus 로고
    • Explaining Vertical Integration: Lessons from the American Automobile Industry
    • Richard Langlois and Paul Robertson, “Explaining Vertical Integration: Lessons from the American Automobile Industry,” Journal of Economic History 49 (June 1989): 361–75.
    • (1989) Journal of Economic History , vol.49 , pp. 361-375
    • Langlois, R.1    Robertson, P.2
  • 29
    • 84972454824 scopus 로고
    • Parts Makers’ Role Gets Bigger as Automotive History Unfolds
    • P. Heldt, “Parts Makers’ Role Gets Bigger as Automotive History Unfolds,” Automotive Industries, 6 May 1933, 546–48, 554, argues that in the 1920s, independent suppliers made significant improvements in parts including brakes, crankshafts, pistons, valves, springs, carburetors, radiators, clutches, steering gears, and axles.
    • (1933) Automotive Industries , pp. 546-548
    • Heldt, P.1
  • 31
    • 84972426454 scopus 로고
    • Graham and Bettye Pruitt, RirD for Industry: A Century of Technical Innovation at ALCOA
    • New York
    • Margaret B. W. Graham and Bettye Pruitt, RirD for Industry: A Century of Technical Innovation at ALCOA (New York, 1990), 148; quote from Nevins and Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 447.
    • (1990) , pp. 148
    • Margaret, B.W.1
  • 32
    • 0039751120 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • In the days of single sourcing, an important union goal in the case of a strike was to prevent the transfer of automaker-owned tooling to another plant, leading to “games of ’hide-and-seek’ along Detroit side streets, with union members in pursuit of the transfer trucks.” Kenneth Alexander, “Market Practices and Collective Bargaining in Automotive Parts, “ Journal of Political Economy 69 (Feb. 1961): 17. Strikes were a frequent occurrence in the early postwar period; for example, GM reported that in mid-May 1946, 142 of its suppliers were affected by strikes. Harold Katz, The Decline of Competition in the Automobile Industry, 1920–1940 (New York, 1977), 263.
    • (1977) The Decline of Competition in the Automobile Industry , pp. 263
    • Katz, H.1
  • 33
    • 8644243834 scopus 로고
    • Towards a Cooperative Commonwealth: Labor and Restructuring in the U.S. and Canadian Auto Industries
    • Stephen Herzenberg, “Towards a Cooperative Commonwealth: Labor and Restructuring in the U.S. and Canadian Auto Industries” (Ph.D. diss., Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1991), 225.
    • (1991) Ph.D. diss., Massachusetts Institute of Technology , pp. 225
    • Herzenberg, S.1
  • 34
    • 84972189865 scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor, Mich.
    • This estimate is very crude. It is based on 1) the finding in R. Kamath and C. Wilson, “Characteristics of the U.S. Automotive Supplier Industry,” Joint U.S.-Japan Auto Study, no. 10 (Ann Arbor, Mich., 1983) that in 1980, the top forty auto suppliers (.8 percent of the total) made about 31 percent of the total volume of $34 billion in sales of “parts, components, and raw materials” to U.S. automakers whose producers the authors were able to identify; and 2) the observation that in general, it was only the largest suppliers who had much interaction with the automakers. Therefore, the bottom 99.2 percent of suppliers were in the simple exit mode.
    • (1983) Characteristics of the U.S. Automotive Supplier Industry
    • Kamath, R.1    Wilson, C.2
  • 35
    • 0012325741 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • Written, legally binding contracts lasting longer than one year were extremely rare, however. See Michael E. Porter, Cases in Competitive Strategy (New York, 1983), and University of Michigan Transportation Research Institute, “The International Automotive Challenge: Strategy Beyond Cost and Quality,” UMTRI Research Review 17 (Sept.-Dec. 1986): 18.
    • (1983) Cases in Competitive Strategy
    • Porter, M.E.1
  • 36
    • 84881484188 scopus 로고
    • Interview, October 1984.
    • (1984) Interview
  • 37
    • 84972332376 scopus 로고
    • When asked to comment on this incident, a Ford executive freely admitted that in the past, “we cut the legs out from more than one supplier” (August 1985).
    • Supplier interviews, October 1984. When asked to comment on this incident, a Ford executive freely admitted that in the past, “we cut the legs out from more than one supplier” (August 1985).
    • (1984) Supplier interviews
  • 41
    • 84972328492 scopus 로고
    • Interview with GM manager at a former Fisher plant, 4 December 1990; interview with James Meehan, professor of economics, Colby College, April 1986. This example illustrates that the ability of a vertically integrated firm to “effect internal adaptations by fiat” (Williamson, Economic Institutions of Capitalism, 75) is not automatic; incentive systems must be carefully established and maintained. Similarly, the example illustrates that the costs of haggling and the danger of a “hold-up” may be greater with a powerful internal supplier than with an outside firm.
    • (1986) professor of economics, Colby College
    • Meehan, J.1
  • 42
    • 84972313533 scopus 로고
    • General Motors (A): Organization of the Procurement Function
    • E. Raymond Corey, “General Motors (A): Organization of the Procurement Function,” Harvard Business School Case 9–576–251 (1977), 15; interview with manager at ex-Fisher plant, 4 December 1990. In 1971, the Chevrolet Vega was unable to meet emissions standards. GM's Rochester Products Division refused to help with the problem, so Chevrolet had to add an air pump to help exhaust gases burn more effectively. Holley Carburetor was willing to work with Chevrolet on the problem and designed a carburetor that eliminated the need for the pump and saved Chevy $3 million per year. GM management then awarded the contract to produce the Holley-designed carburetor to Rochester Products. Only after strenuous protests by DeLorean was Holley “allowed to keep a little piece of the business.” Wright, On a Char Day, 78–79.
    • (1977) Harvard Business School Case , pp. 15
    • Raymond Corey, E.1
  • 43
    • 84972329225 scopus 로고
    • Chrysler, “blind ambition” drove its Dayton plant to claim that it could make radiators, even though it had no relevant experience and the equipment it was proposing to buy was obsolete. Chrysler eventually rejected the plan, but only at the highest possible level; other disputes were not resolved so satisfactorily; interview with Chrysler engineer, August 1985.
    • (1985) blind ambition
    • Chrysler1
  • 44
    • 84972309507 scopus 로고
    • Smith, Barney, Harris, Upham and Co., New York
    • A. Knight, “Automotive Report,” Smith, Barney, Harris, Upham and Co., New York, 10 Feb. 1983.
    • (1983) Automotive Report
    • Knight, A.1
  • 45
    • 84972313540 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • Chandler, Strategy and Structure; Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., Giant Enterprise: Ford, General Motors, and the Automobile Industry (New York, 1964).
    • (1964)
    • Chandler1
  • 46
    • 84972448857 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration in the United States Automobile Industry
    • Ph.D. diss., Northwestern University
    • Robert Crandall, “Vertical Integration in the United States Automobile Industry” (Ph.D. diss., Northwestern University, 1968).
    • (1968)
    • Crandall, R.1
  • 47
    • 84972459143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Knight, “Automotive Report. “ In contrast, the automakers have not been nearly so successful at protecting their rents from their suppliers of labor. For most of the period since 1913, when Henry Ford's $5 day was double the prevailing manufacturing wage, the automakers have paid their workers wages above the manufacturing average. Between 1948 and 1980, the ratio of auto assembler wages to the average production worker's wages ranged from 1.17 to 1.55. See Harry Katz, Shifting Gears: Changing Labor Relations in the U.S. Automobile Industry (Cambridge, Mass., 1985), Table 2.1.
    • Automotive Report
    • Knight1
  • 48
    • 84972238647 scopus 로고
    • At Chrysler in the 1970s, the cost of expected midstream changes accounted for 20–30 percent of automotive program budgets. Wall Street Journal, 23 Feb. 1988, 24.
    • (1988) Wall Street Journal , pp. 24
  • 49
    • 84972448884 scopus 로고
    • The Metal Finishing Industry, Michigan Business Reports
    • Barriers to entry into some industries could be quite low. In the late 1960s, for example, “a simple [metal] finishing operation could be started in rented quarters for under $10,000.” H. Arnett and D. Smith, The Metal Finishing Industry, Michigan Business Reports, n.s. no. 10 (Ann Arbor, Mich., 1977), 3.
    • (1977) Ann Arbor, Mich. , pp. 3
    • Arnett, H.1    Smith, D.2
  • 50
    • 84881484188 scopus 로고
    • Interview, October 1984; written comments by a Ford executive on a 1986 draft of this manuscript.
    • (1984) Interview
  • 51
    • 84972189297 scopus 로고
    • Porter, Cases in Competitive Strategy; interview with executives at Fleck Manufacturing, a small ($5 million sales) Canadian wiring-harness maker, May 1987.
    • (1987) Cases in Competitive Strategy
    • Porter1
  • 52
    • 38549086633 scopus 로고
    • Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing, and Public Policy
    • David Teece, “Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing, and Public Policy,” Research Policy 15 (Dec. 1986): 285–305.
    • (1986) Research Policy , vol.15 , pp. 285-305
    • Teece, D.1
  • 54
    • 0003398453 scopus 로고
    • The Automobile Industry since 1945
    • Cambridge, Mass.
    • Lawrence J. White, The Automobile Industry since 1945 (Cambridge, Mass., 1971); Michael Moritz and Barrett Seaman, Going for Broke—The Chrysler Story (New York, 1981).
    • (1971)
    • White, L.J.1
  • 59
    • 84972448904 scopus 로고
    • My Years with General Motors
    • Alfred P. Sloan, Jr., My Years with General Motors (Garden City, N.Y., 1963), 69, cited in Abernathy, Productivity Dilemma, 34. See also Stuart W. Leslie, Boss Kettering (New York, 1983), 123–47, and Chandler, Strategy and Structure, 154.
    • (1963) Garden City, N.Y. , pp. 69
    • Sloan, A.P.1
  • 60
    • 0003418618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abernathy, Productivity Dilemma, 35. It may seem unlikely that an incident that occurred nearly seventy years ago would have much influence on corporate behavior today. But this example was cited as late as 1987 by GM engineers as a reason to avoid technological risks. (Conversation with Robert Kazanjian, University of Michigan, reporting on a class he had taught at the GM Tech Center, Feb. 1987.)
    • Productivity Dilemma , pp. 35
    • Abernathy1
  • 62
    • 84902052603 scopus 로고
    • Interview, August 1985.
    • (1985) Interview
  • 64
    • 70449880956 scopus 로고
    • Interview, May 1988.
    • (1988) Interview
  • 66
    • 84972328470 scopus 로고
    • Wall Street Journal, 31 July 1984, 1; Ford interviews, August 1985.
    • (1984) Wall Street Journal , pp. 1
  • 67
    • 84972340994 scopus 로고
    • Modelling the Role of History in Industrial Organization
    • Auto industry executives’ use of this concept seemed very similar to that now in vogue among game theorists; see, for example, David Kreps and A. Michael Spence, “Modelling the Role of History in Industrial Organization,” Harvard University Discussion Paper 992 (July 1983). For example, I interviewed in October 1984 a supplier who had GM-owned tooling at his plant that would take nine months and cost $4–5 million to move to another supplier. When asked why he did not try to raise his price at contract renegotiation time, he said, “Because our reputation would be shot to hell. We might get away with it once, but nobody in the business would ever deal with us again; they'd say, ’You're nothing but a bunch of dishonest crooks.’ “
    • (1983) Harvard University Discussion Paper , pp. 992
    • Kreps, D.1
  • 68
    • 84972469476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Signetics (B), 5, 7–8.
    • , vol.5 , pp. 7-8
    • Signetics1
  • 69
    • 9944221051 scopus 로고
    • Ward's Auto World, June 1987 and Nov. 1988, 59; Mary Connelly, “Acustar stronger since Chrysler plan to sell it fell apart, “ Automotive News, 6 March 1989, 20.
    • (1989) Automotive News , pp. 20
  • 70
    • 84972238630 scopus 로고
    • Michigan Business, April 1987, 71; Michelle Krebs, “GM ready to merge 5 parts units into 2,” Automotive News, 6 March 1989, 3, 6.
    • (1987) , pp. 71
    • Business, M.1
  • 71
  • 72
    • 84972171160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The International Automotive Challenge
    • Robert M. Sinclair, vice-president, engineering, at Chrysler, in University of Michigan Transportation Research Institute, “The International Automotive Challenge,” 22. In the automotive industry as a whole, half of all engineering was done by engineering service firms, according to Ralph Miller, president, Modern Engineering Service Company (31). Cash-rich CM bucked this trend with its purchases of Electronic Data Systems (for $2.5 billion in 1984) and Hughes Aircraft Company (for $5 billion in 1985), acquisitions that significantly increased its computer and electronics capabilities. (Fortune, 8 July 1985, 22).
    • Sinclair, R.M.1
  • 74
    • 84903099703 scopus 로고
    • MA Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
    • Frank Gillett, “The Integrating Supplier” (MA Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1992).
    • (1992) The Integrating Supplier
    • Gillett, F.1
  • 77
    • 84972189825 scopus 로고
    • Chemical Week, 11 Nov. 1987, 10; Wall Street Journal, 23 Feb. 1988, 22. Similar figures could be cited for General Motors and Chrysler.
    • (1987) Chemical Week , pp. 10
  • 80
    • 0345619530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Langlois and Robertson, “Explaining Vertical Integration,” point out, product innovation often has these features, whereas (many types of) process innovation are characterized by the need to work out details centrally.
    • Explaining Vertical Integration
    • Langlois1    Robertson2
  • 81
    • 84972413454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Long-Term Supplier Relations
    • For a game-theoretic analysis of how a change in the buyer's threat point due to a change in final-product market structure can lead to a change in supplier relations strategies from exit to voice, see Helper and Levine, “Long-Term Supplier Relations.”
    • Helper1    Levine2
  • 82
    • 84972171211 scopus 로고
    • Report on Conference Held at Jackson Community College, Jackson, Michigan
    • photocopy
    • General Motors, “Report on Conference Held at Jackson Community College, Jackson, Michigan” (1984), photocopy.
    • (1984) General Motors
  • 83
    • 84972422890 scopus 로고
    • Air-Bag Woes Knock Wind Out of TRW
    • Dana Milbank, “Air-Bag Woes Knock Wind Out of TRW,” Wall Street Journal, 12 March 1991, A4.
    • (1991) Wall Street Journal , pp. A4
    • Milbank, D.1
  • 87
    • 84972314092 scopus 로고
    • Toward Effective Vendor Management: International Comparisons
    • See Roy D. Shapiro, “Toward Effective Vendor Management: International Comparisons,” Harvard Business School Working Paper (1985).
    • (1985) Harvard Business School Working Paper
    • Shapiro, R.D.1
  • 88
    • 84972201407 scopus 로고
    • 232 Japanese Supplier Plants Gunning for Your Business
    • Automotive Industries
    • By early 1989, there were 232 Japanese-owned or joint-venture plants in the United States in operation or in final planning stages. Of these, 85 had contracts with at least one of Ford, GM, or Chrysler. Joseph M. Callahan, “232 Japanese Supplier Plants Gunning for Your Business, “ Automotive Industries, Feb. 1989, 89–112.
    • (1989) , pp. 89-112
    • Callahan, J.M.1
  • 90
    • 0004027032 scopus 로고
    • La Jolla, Calif.
    • Harley Shaiken and Stephen Herzenberg, Automation and Global Production: Automobile Engine Production in Mexico, the United States, and Canada (La Jolla, Calif., 1987), show that cost is significantly less, and quality and machine uptime levels approach U.S. levels at a U.S. automaker's engine plant in Mexico compared with one in the United States making exactly the same (fully de-bugged) product. On the difficulties of coordinating production between the United States and Mexico, see Roy D. Shapiro, “Rio Bravo Electricos,” Harvard Business School Case (1982).
    • (1987) Automation and Global Production: Automobile Engine Production in Mexico, the United States, and Canada
    • Shaiken, H.1    Herzenberg, S.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.