메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 6, Issue 2, 1992, Pages 223-271

Stacking the Senate, Changing the Nation: Republican Rotten Boroughs, Statehood Politics, and American Political Development

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84959601731     PISSN: 0898588X     EISSN: 14698692     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0898588X00000985     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (65)

References (57)
  • 1
    • 84959579035 scopus 로고
    • Party Systems and the Political Process
    • William N. Chambers and Walter Dean Burnham, eds, The American Party Systems, 2nd ed. (New York: Oxford University Press
    • Walter Dean Burnham, “Party Systems and the Political Process,” in William N. Chambers and Walter Dean Burnham, eds., The American Party Systems, 2nd ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1975), p. 297.
    • (1975) , pp. 297
    • Dean Burnham, W.1
  • 3
    • 0003709357 scopus 로고
    • Sectionalism and American Political Development
    • Madison: University of Wisconsin Press
    • Richard Bensel, Sectionalism and American Political Development, 1880–1980 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1984).
    • (1984) , pp. 1880-1980
    • Bensel, R.1
  • 4
    • 0021545661 scopus 로고
    • Why Not Equal Protection?
    • Margaret Weir, Ann S. Orloff, and Theda Skocpol, The Politics of Social Policy in the United States (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988); Christopher Howard et al., “Government Institutions, Women's Associations, and the Enactment of Mothers” Pensions in the United States, 1910-1935” (paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.
    • Ann S. Orloff and Theda Skocpol, “Why Not Equal Protection?” American Sociological Review, 49 (1984): 726—750; Margaret Weir, Ann S. Orloff, and Theda Skocpol, The Politics of Social Policy in the United States (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988); Christopher Howard et al., “Government Institutions, Women's Associations, and the Enactment of Mothers” Pensions in the United States, 1910-1935” (paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.).
    • (1984) American Sociological Review , vol.49 , pp. 726-750
    • Orloff, A.S.1    Skocpol, T.2
  • 5
    • 0004212175 scopus 로고
    • Bringing the State Back
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • Peter B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol, Bringing the State Back In (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985).
    • (1985)
    • Evans, P.B.1    Dietrich, R.2    and Theda, S.3
  • 6
    • 84959635492 scopus 로고
    • Social Choice and Individual Values (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1951); Richard D. McKelvey, “Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control
    • Kenneth Arrow, Social Choice and Individual Values (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1951); Richard D. McKelvey, “Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control,” Journal of Economic Theory, 16 (1976): 472–482.
    • (1976) Journal of Economic Theory , vol.16 , pp. 472-482
    • Arrow, K.1
  • 7
    • 84936180133 scopus 로고
    • The Industrial Organization of Congress
    • McNollgast, “Structure and Process. Politics and Policy, ” Virginia Law Review, 75 (1989): 431–482
    • Barry R. Weingast and William J. Marshall, “The Industrial Organization of Congress,” Journal of Political Economy, 96 (1988): 132-163; McNollgast, “Structure and Process. Politics and Policy,” Virginia Law Review, 75 (1989): 431–482.
    • (1988) Journal of Political Economy , vol.96 , pp. 132-163
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Marshall, W.J.2
  • 8
    • 34250241742 scopus 로고
    • Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice
    • cf. Keith Krehbiel, “Spatial Models of Legislative Choice, ” Legislative Studies Quarterly, 13 (1988): 259–320
    • Kenneth Shepsle and Barry Weingast, “Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice,” Public Choice, 37 (1981): 503-519; cf. Keith Krehbiel, “Spatial Models of Legislative Choice,” Legislative Studies Quarterly, 13 (1988): 259–320.
    • (1981) Public Choice , vol.37 , pp. 503-519
    • Shepsle, K.1    Weingast, B.2
  • 9
    • 84959626865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weingast and Marshall, “The Industrial Organization of Congress
    • Weingast and Marshall, “The Industrial Organization of Congress.”
  • 10
    • 0003522633 scopus 로고
    • Political Economy of Public Administration
    • Ph.D. dissertation McNollgast, “Structure and Process, Politics and Policy”; Moe, “Political Uncertainty
    • Murray Horn, “Political Economy of Public Administration” (Ph.D. dissertation, 1990); McNollgast, “Structure and Process, Politics and Policy”; Moe, “Political Uncertainty.”
    • (1990)
    • Horn, M.1
  • 11
    • 0009293903 scopus 로고
    • Blueprints for Leviathan
    • New York: Atheneum
    • Roy F. Nichols, Blueprints for Leviathan (New York: Atheneum, 1963).
    • (1963)
    • Nichols, R.F.1
  • 12
    • 0002021502 scopus 로고
    • New York: Harper, 1976); Barry R. Weingast, “Political Economy of Slavery,” (unpublished manuscript, Stanford University
    • David Potter, The Impending Crisis (New York: Harper, 1976); Barry R. Weingast, “Political Economy of Slavery,” (unpublished manuscript, Stanford University, 1991).
    • (1991) The Impending Crisis
    • Potter, D.1
  • 13
    • 0041045527 scopus 로고
    • Yankee Leviathan
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • Richard Bensel, Yankee Leviathan (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), p. 88.
    • (1990) , pp. 88
    • Bensel, R.1
  • 14
    • 84959636103 scopus 로고
    • On strategies adopted in the House to overcome this Republican “executive cartel,” see Charles Stewart III, “Lessons from the Post-Civil War Era, ” In Gary Cox and Sam Kernell, eds, The Politics of Divided Government (Boulder, CO: Westview
    • On strategies adopted in the House to overcome this Republican “executive cartel,” see Charles Stewart III, “Lessons from the Post-Civil War Era,” In Gary Cox and Sam Kernell, eds., The Politics of Divided Government (Boulder, CO: Westview, 1991).
    • (1991)
  • 15
    • 84959681387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of related issues during the period immediately following that covered in this paper, see Bensel, Yankee Leviathan
    • For a discussion of related issues during the period immediately following that covered in this paper, see Bensel, Yankee Leviathan, pp. 88–101.
  • 16
    • 84959612628 scopus 로고
    • and because the statehood debate was a persistent matter whose affects on one important institutions, the Senate, can be traced fairly precisely
    • We also focus on statehood politics, understanding full well that there are other questions about the American electoral universe that we don't explore. The most obvious are black voting rights and matters such as the Force Bill. (See Bensel, Sectionalism.) We so proceed both because others have tackled black voting rights (Richard Valelly, “Party, Coercion, and Inclusion: The Two Reconstructions and the South's Electoral Politics,” Politics and Society [forthcoming
    • We also focus on statehood politics, understanding full well that there are other questions about the American electoral universe that we don't explore. The most obvious are black voting rights and matters such as the Force Bill. (See Bensel, Sectionalism.) We so proceed both because others have tackled black voting rights (Richard Valelly, “Party, Coercion, and Inclusion: The Two Reconstructions and the South's Electoral Politics,” Politics and Society [forthcoming 1993]) and because the statehood debate was a persistent matter whose affects on one important institutions, the Senate, can be traced fairly precisely.
    • (1993)
  • 17
    • 0004063144 scopus 로고
    • Atlas of the Historical Geography of the United States
    • Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Institution of Washington plates 77 and 78
    • Charles Oscar Paullin, Atlas of the Historical Geography of the United States (Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Institution of Washington, 1932), plates 77 and 78.
    • (1932)
    • Oscar Paullin, C.1
  • 18
    • 84959674851 scopus 로고
    • [Nevada's] population is obviously unworthy of the privilege of sending two men to the Senate, and has in fact allowed itself to sink, for all practical purposes, into sort of a rotten borough, which can be controlled or purchased by leaders of the Silver Ring
    • New York, Macmillan
    • “[Nevada's] population is obviously unworthy of the privilege of sending two men to the Senate, and has in fact allowed itself to sink, for all practical purposes, into sort of a rotten borough, which can be controlled or purchased by leaders of the Silver Ring.” (James Bryce, American Commonwealth [New York, Macmillan, 1888], Vol. II, p. 219
    • (1888) (James Bryce, American Commonwealth , vol.2 , pp. 219
  • 19
    • 84959670686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mormon historiography refers to this as the “Utah War
    • Mormon historiography refers to this as the “Utah War.”
  • 20
    • 84959704011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bensel Yankee Leviathan
    • See Bensel, Yankee Leviathan, pp. 89–91.
  • 21
    • 84959710609 scopus 로고
    • The original Nevada Territory was roughly 60 percent its current size. It was extended to its current eastern borders in 1866, following the discovery of silver in the westernmost reaches of the Utah Territory, now the easternmost reaches of Nevada. At the same time the Nevada Territory was organized, the Colorado Territory was organized from land taken from the easternmost section of Utah and from Nebraska. On the creation of Nevada and its push to statehood, see Russel R. Elliott, History of Nevada (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1973); Thomas Wren, A History of the State of Nevada (New York: Lewis, 1904); and Robert Laxalt, Nevada: A Bicentennial History (New York: Norton
    • The original Nevada Territory was roughly 60 percent its current size. It was extended to its current eastern borders in 1866, following the discovery of silver in the westernmost reaches of the Utah Territory, now the easternmost reaches of Nevada. At the same time the Nevada Territory was organized, the Colorado Territory was organized from land taken from the easternmost section of Utah and from Nebraska. On the creation of Nevada and its push to statehood, see Russel R. Elliott, History of Nevada (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1973); Thomas Wren, A History of the State of Nevada (New York: Lewis, 1904); and Robert Laxalt, Nevada: A Bicentennial History (New York: Norton, 1977).
    • (1977)
  • 22
    • 33646140028 scopus 로고
    • Colorado: A Bicentennial History
    • New York: Norton
    • Marshall Sprague, Colorado: A Bicentennial History (New York: Norton, 1976).
    • (1976)
    • Sprague, M.1
  • 23
    • 84959617775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • History of Nevada
    • Statements to the effect that the only reason Nevada was admitted was to provide one of these benefits to Republicans appear in Woodrow Wilson, Congressional Government (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1956 [18851); Bryce, American Commonwealth; and Elliott
    • Statements to the effect that the only reason Nevada was admitted was to provide one of these benefits to Republicans appear in Woodrow Wilson, Congressional Government (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1956 [18851); Bryce, American Commonwealth; and Elliott, History of Nevada.
  • 24
    • 84959635676 scopus 로고
    • Nevada had a population of 6,857 in the 1860 census and 42,491 in the 1870 census. No reliable census was taken between the decennial years. Based on a linear interpolation between 1860 and 1870, Nevada's population would have been 21,111 in a polynomial interpolation of the census returns for 1860, 1870, 1880, and 1890 would have the population at 26,254 in
    • Nevada had a population of 6,857 in the 1860 census and 42,491 in the 1870 census. No reliable census was taken between the decennial years. Based on a linear interpolation between 1860 and 1870, Nevada's population would have been 21,111 in a polynomial interpolation of the census returns for 1860, 1870, 1880, and 1890 would have the population at 26,254 in 1864.
    • (1864)
  • 25
    • 84959655091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An additional motivation for the early admission of Nevada may also been at work: the potential threat of secession by California and Nevada during the Civil War may have led to the latter's early admission as a concession to both
    • An additional motivation for the early admission of Nevada may also been at work: the potential threat of secession by California and Nevada during the Civil War may have led to the latter's early admission as a concession to both.
  • 26
    • 84959665574 scopus 로고
    • At this time seats in the House of Representatives were apportioned using a method called the “Vinton method.” Under this method, the total population of the country was divided by the size of the House as determined in the reapportionment bill. The resulting “ratio of representation” was essentially the number of inhabitants needed for each seat in the House of Representatives. The ratio of representation was then divided into the population of each state to determine how many representatives they would be entitled to; fractions were discarded at this step. Then, any remaining representatives needing to be allocated were assigned to the states having the largest remainders from the prior step (Congressional Quarterly, Guide to Congress, 2nd ed. [Washington: Congressional Quarterly Press Under the reapportionment that followed the 1860 census, the “ratio of representation” was 127,381
    • At this time seats in the House of Representatives were apportioned using a method called the “Vinton method.” Under this method, the total population of the country was divided by the size of the House as determined in the reapportionment bill. The resulting “ratio of representation” was essentially the number of inhabitants needed for each seat in the House of Representatives. The ratio of representation was then divided into the population of each state to determine how many representatives they would be entitled to; fractions were discarded at this step. Then, any remaining representatives needing to be allocated were assigned to the states having the largest remainders from the prior step (Congressional Quarterly, Guide to Congress, 2nd ed. [Washington: Congressional Quarterly Press, 1983], p. 565). Under the reapportionment that followed the 1860 census, the “ratio of representation” was 127,381.
    • (1983) , pp. 565
  • 27
    • 84959621069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congressional Globe
    • 3 March 1863, 37th Cong., 3d sess
    • Congressional Globe, 3 March 1863, 37th Cong., 3d sess., p. 1510.
  • 29
    • 84951993744 scopus 로고
    • Recent History of the United States, rev. and enlarged
    • Boston: Houghton Mifflin
    • Frederic L. Paxson, Recent History of the United States, rev. and enlarged ed. (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1929), pp. 198–199.
    • (1929) , pp. 198-199
    • Paxson, F.L.1
  • 30
    • 84959724028 scopus 로고
    • Congressional Record
    • 9 April
    • Congressional Record, 9 April 1888, p. 2836.
    • (1888)
  • 31
    • 84959597597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Ibid., p. 3037.
  • 32
    • 84959693216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Ibid., p. 3003.
  • 33
    • 84959644197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Ibid., p. 948.
  • 34
    • 84959676368 scopus 로고
    • Calvin Roberts and Susan A. Roberts, New Mexico (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press
    • Calvin Roberts and Susan A. Roberts, New Mexico (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, 1988), p. 154.
    • (1988) , pp. 154
  • 35
    • 84959723108 scopus 로고
    • Congressional Record
    • 14 February
    • Congressional Record 14 February 1889, p. 1906.
    • (1889) , pp. 1906
  • 36
    • 84959615490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Party Systems
    • Burnham, “Party Systems,” p. 297.
    • Burnham1
  • 37
    • 84959587684 scopus 로고
    • For instance, Stephen A. Douglas answered one of Lincoln's famous questions at Freeport by noting the following: “I hold it to be a sound rule of universal application to require a territory to contain the requisite population for a member of Congress, before it is admitted as a State into the Union.” (quoted in Roy P. Basler, The Collected Works of Abraham Lincoln [new Bunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press
    • For instance, Stephen A. Douglas answered one of Lincoln's famous questions at Freeport by noting the following: “I hold it to be a sound rule of universal application to require a territory to contain the requisite population for a member of Congress, before it is admitted as a State into the Union.” (quoted in Roy P. Basler, The Collected Works of Abraham Lincoln [new Bunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 1953], Vol. III, p. 50
    • (1953) , vol.3 , pp. 50
  • 38
    • 84971177643 scopus 로고
    • The Institutionalization of the U.S. House of Representatives
    • See Nelson Polsby Bensel, Sectionalism
    • See Nelson Polsby, “The Institutionalization of the U.S. House of Representatives,” American Political Science Review 62(1968): 144-168; Bensel, Sectionalism.
    • (1968) American Political Science Review , vol.62 , pp. 144-168
  • 39
    • 0010702426 scopus 로고
    • Partisan Cleavage and Cohesion in the House of Representatives, 1861–1974 Keith T. Poole and Howard Rosenthal, “The Enduring 19th Century Battle for Economic Regulation: The Interstate Commerce Act Revisited” (unpublished manuscript, Carnegie Mellon University, 1991
    • Jerome M. Clubb and Santa A. Traugott, “Partisan Cleavage and Cohesion in the House of Representatives, 1861–1974,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 7 (1977): 375-401; Keith T. Poole and Howard Rosenthal, “The Enduring 19th Century Battle for Economic Regulation: The Interstate Commerce Act Revisited” (unpublished manuscript, Carnegie Mellon University, 1991).
    • (1977) Journal of Interdisciplinary History , vol.7 , pp. 375-401
    • Clubb, J.M.1    Traugott, S.A.2
  • 40
    • 84959670337 scopus 로고
    • See Thomas M. Wolf, “Congressional Sea Change: Conflict and Organizational Accommodation in the House of Representatives, 1878-1921” (Ph.D. dissertation, M.I.T. Poole and Rosenthal, “The Enduring 19th Century Battle
    • See Thomas M. Wolf, “Congressional Sea Change: Conflict and Organizational Accommodation in the House of Representatives, 1878-1921” (Ph.D. dissertation, M.I.T., 1981), chap. 2; Poole and Rosenthal, “The Enduring 19th Century Battle,” p. 8.
    • (1981) , pp. 2
  • 41
    • 0004157554 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Theory of Democracy
    • New York: Harper
    • Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper, 1957).
    • (1957)
    • Downs, A.1
  • 42
    • 84959670598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives
    • Cox, “Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives.”
    • Cox1
  • 43
    • 84959609372 scopus 로고
    • This summary of tariff history is drawn from O. H. Perry, “Proposed Tariff Legislation since 1883,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 2 (1887): 69-79; F. W. Taussig, Tariff History of the United States, 8th ed. (New York: Putnam, 1931); Judith Goldstein, Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press Sharyn O'Halloran, Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, forthcoming
    • This summary of tariff history is drawn from O. H. Perry, “Proposed Tariff Legislation since 1883,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 2 (1887): 69-79; F. W. Taussig, Tariff History of the United States, 8th ed. (New York: Putnam, 1931); Judith Goldstein, Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1991); and Sharyn O'Halloran, Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, forthcoming).
    • (1991)
  • 44
    • 84959624198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A new party is defined as gaining control of the government when the following three conditions are met: when (1) a single party controls both houses of Congress and the presidency following a congressional (or congressional/presidential) election, (2) this party did not control the entire federal government following the prior congressional election, and (3) the last time a single party controlled the entire federal government, it was a different party than the one currently controlling it
    • A new party is defined as gaining control of the government when the following three conditions are met: when (1) a single party controls both houses of Congress and the presidency following a congressional (or congressional/presidential) election, (2) this party did not control the entire federal government following the prior congressional election, and (3) the last time a single party controlled the entire federal government, it was a different party than the one currently controlling it.
  • 45
    • 84959590907 scopus 로고
    • In 1842 tariff rates had been undergoing a decade-long decline under the Compromise Tariff of
    • In 1842 tariff rates had been undergoing a decade-long decline under the Compromise Tariff of 1833.
    • (1833)
  • 46
    • 0003443606 scopus 로고
    • Financial History of the United States
    • New York: McGraw-Hill, 1952); Robert C. West, Banking Reform and the Federal Reserve, 1863–1923 (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1977); Richard H. Timberlake, The Origins of Central Banking in the United States (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1978); Gary M. Walton and Hugh Rockoff, History of the American Economy, 6th ed. (San Diego: Harcourt
    • Paul Studenski and Herman E. Krooss, Financial History of the United States (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1952); Robert C. West, Banking Reform and the Federal Reserve, 1863–1923 (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1977); Richard H. Timberlake, The Origins of Central Banking in the United States (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1978); Gary M. Walton and Hugh Rockoff, History of the American Economy, 6th ed. (San Diego: Harcourt, 1991).
    • (1991)
    • Studenski, P.1    Krooss, H.E.2
  • 47
    • 84982953439 scopus 로고
    • Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1963).
    • (1963)
  • 48
    • 84959658748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While some have read this as a bill to protect shippers and others as a bill to bolster the railroads fragile cartels, these conclusions result from focusing solely on one of the two problems generated by railroads and ignoring the other. Both perspectives are needed to understand the 1887 Act and neither view alone provides an accurate picture. See Gilligan, Marshall, and Weingast, Regulation and the Theory of Legislative Choice
    • While some have read this as a bill to protect shippers and others as a bill to bolster the railroads fragile cartels, these conclusions result from focusing solely on one of the two problems generated by railroads and ignoring the other. Both perspectives are needed to understand the 1887 Act and neither view alone provides an accurate picture. See Gilligan, Marshall, and Weingast, “Regulation and the Theory of Legislative Choice.”
  • 49
    • 84959634582 scopus 로고
    • “Regulation and the Theory of Legislative Choice”; “The Economic Incidence of the Interstate Commerce Act of
    • “Regulation and the Theory of Legislative Choice”; “The Economic Incidence of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887.”
    • (1887)
  • 50
    • 84959669822 scopus 로고
    • notes, this is exactly the mechanism used three years later in the Sherman Antitrust Act
    • As Fiorina
    • As Fiorina (1986) notes, this is exactly the mechanism used three years later in the Sherman Antitrust Act.
    • (1986)
  • 51
    • 84959599083 scopus 로고
    • Columbus: Ohio State University Press Gilligan, Marshall, and Weingast, “The Economic Incidence of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887
    • R. Dewey, The Long and Short Haul Principle of Rate Regulation (Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 1935); Gilligan, Marshall, and Weingast, “The Economic Incidence of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887.”
    • (1935) The Long and Short Haul Principle of Rate Regulation
    • Dewey, R.1
  • 52
    • 84959597974 scopus 로고
    • While the post—New Deal experience with the Court prompts us to associate partisan labels with judicial ideology cautiously, prior to the New Deal, commentators did not have a problem in associating partisan labels with judicial philosophy. See, for instance, Woodrow Wilson, Congressional Government (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1956
    • While the post—New Deal experience with the Court prompts us to associate partisan labels with judicial ideology cautiously, prior to the New Deal, commentators did not have a problem in associating partisan labels with judicial philosophy. See, for instance, Woodrow Wilson, Congressional Government (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1956 [1885]), p. 45.
    • (1885) , pp. 45
  • 53
    • 84959722235 scopus 로고
    • This is based on the family of models developed in the following: Randall Calvert, Mathew D. McCubbins, and Barry R. Weingast, “A Theory of Political Control and Agency Discretion,” American Journal of Political Science 33 (1990): 588-611; Peter H. Lemieux and Charles Stewart III, “Advice? Yes. Consent? Maybe: Senate Confirmation of Surpreme Court Nominations” (presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.); Lemieux and Stewart, “Senate Confirmation of Supreme Court Nominations from Washington to Reagan, ” Hoover Institution Working Paper Series, P-90-3
    • This is based on the family of models developed in the following: Randall Calvert, Mathew D. McCubbins, and Barry R. Weingast, “A Theory of Political Control and Agency Discretion,” American Journal of Political Science 33 (1990): 588-611; Peter H. Lemieux and Charles Stewart III, “Advice? Yes. Consent? Maybe: Senate Confirmation of Surpreme Court Nominations” (presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.); Lemieux and Stewart, “Senate Confirmation of Supreme Court Nominations from Washington to Reagan,” Hoover Institution Working Paper Series, P-90-3, 1990.
    • (1990)
  • 54
    • 84975960792 scopus 로고
    • On the courts, see Lemieux and Stewart, “Advice? Yes. Consent? Maybe,” and “Senate Confirmation of Supreme Court Nominations.” On the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB), see Terry M. Moe, “Interests, Institutions, and Positive Theory: The Politics of the NLRB,”
    • On the courts, see Lemieux and Stewart, “Advice? Yes. Consent? Maybe,” and “Senate Confirmation of Supreme Court Nominations.” On the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB), see Terry M. Moe, “Interests, Institutions, and Positive Theory: The Politics of the NLRB,” Studies in American Political Development 2 (1987): 236–299.
    • (1987) Studies in American Political Development , vol.2 , pp. 236-299
  • 55
    • 84873284215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lochner v. New York
    • U.S.
    • Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45.
    • , vol.45 , pp. 198
  • 56
    • 84959641666 scopus 로고
    • See Morton Keller, Affairs of State (Cambridge: Harvard University Press
    • See Morton Keller, Affairs of State (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1977).
    • (1977)
  • 57
    • 84959707594 scopus 로고
    • While positive political theory remains a relative newcomer to the study of macropolitical events, it may well prove the most valuable tool for explaining the institutional foundations of such events. See William H. Riker, Liberalism Against Populism (San Francisco: Freeman, 1982), Keith T. Poole and Howard Rosenthal, “Patterns of Congressional Voting,” American Journal of Political Science 35 (1991): 228–278, and Barry R. Weingast, “The Political Economy of Slavery” (unpublished manuscript, Stanford University
    • While positive political theory remains a relative newcomer to the study of macropolitical events, it may well prove the most valuable tool for explaining the institutional foundations of such events. See William H. Riker, Liberalism Against Populism (San Francisco: Freeman, 1982), Keith T. Poole and Howard Rosenthal, “Patterns of Congressional Voting,” American Journal of Political Science 35 (1991): 228–278, and Barry R. Weingast, “The Political Economy of Slavery” (unpublished manuscript, Stanford University, 1991).
    • (1991)


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.