메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 36, Issue 1, 2013, Pages 31-39

Corralling capture

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84876259985     PISSN: 01934872     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (25)

References (56)
  • 2
    • 84892621434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cultural capture and the financial crisis
    • Daniel Carpenter & David Moss eds., forthcoming, (manuscript at 9, 11, 31)
    • See, e.g., James Kwak, Cultural Capture and the Financial Crisis, in PREVENTING CAPTURE: SPECIAL INTEREST INFLUENCE AND HOW TO LIMIT IT (Daniel Carpenter & David Moss eds., forthcoming 2013), (manuscript at 9, 11, 31), available at http://www.tobinproject.org/sites/tobinproject.org/files/assets/ Kwak%20%20Cultural%20Capture%20and%20the%20Financial%20Crisis%20%2810.24.11%29. pdf.
    • (2013) Preventing Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit It
    • Kwak, J.1
  • 4
    • 0000456233 scopus 로고
    • The theory of economic regulation
    • George J. Stigler, The Theory of Economic Regulation, 2 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT. SCI. 3 (1971) (offering seminal treatment of capture theory);
    • (1971) Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. , vol.2 , pp. 3
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 5
    • 0001618495 scopus 로고
    • A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence
    • see also Gary S. Becker, A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, 98 Q.J. OF ECON. 371 (1983) (extending and critiquing the Stigler model);
    • (1983) Q.j. of Econ. , vol.98 , pp. 371
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 6
    • 0000420789 scopus 로고
    • Toward a more general theory of regulation
    • Sam Peltzman, Toward a More General Theory of Regulation, 19 J.L. & ECON. 211 (1976) (same);
    • (1976) J.L. & Econ. , vol.19 , pp. 211
    • Peltzman, S.1
  • 7
    • 0016105831 scopus 로고
    • Theories of economic regulation
    • 343-50
    • Richard A. Posner, Theories of Economic Regulation, 5 BELL. J. ECON. & MGMT. SCI. 335, 343-50 (1974) (same).
    • (1974) Bell. J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. , vol.5 , pp. 335
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 8
    • 4544337887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public interested regulation
    • 14
    • See Steven P. Croley, Public Interested Regulation, 28 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 7, 14 (2000).
    • (2000) Fla. St. U. L. Rev. , vol.28 , pp. 7
    • Croley, S.P.1
  • 11
    • 84876246174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cognitive capture, parliamentary parentheses, and the rise of fractional apportionment
    • 580-81
    • Stanley I. Langbein, Cognitive Capture, Parliamentary Parentheses, and the Rise of Fractional Apportionment, 39 TAX MGM'T INT'L J. 567, 580-81 (2010);
    • (2010) Tax Mgm't Int'l J. , vol.39 , pp. 567
    • Langbein, S.I.1
  • 12
    • 79953056051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 106, Sept. 14,(unpublished manuscript)
    • Willem H. Buiter, Central banks and financial crises 104, 106 (Sept. 14, 2008) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.willembuiter.com/hole. pdf (setting forth theory of "cognitive regulatory capture").
    • (2008) Central Banks and Financial Crises , pp. 104
    • Buiter, W.H.1
  • 13
    • 84928089906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The government's elite and regulatory capture
    • June 11, 2:00 PM
    • see also Steven M. Davidoff, The Government's Elite and Regulatory Capture, N.Y. TIMES (June 11, 2010, 2:00 PM), http://dealbook.nytimes.com/ 2010/06/11/the-governments-elite-and-regulatory-capture.
    • (2010) N.Y. Times
    • Davidoff, S.M.1
  • 14
    • 84876207183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foreword: Deregulation: A major cause of the financial crisis
    • 231-32
    • See, e.g., Brooksley Born, Foreword: Deregulation: A Major Cause of the Financial Crisis, 5 HARV. L. & POL'Y REV. 231, 231-32 (2011).
    • (2011) Harv. L. & Pol'y Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 231
    • Born, B.1
  • 15
    • 67650453584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The quiet coup
    • May
    • For a version of the argument in the popular press, see Simon Johnson, The Quiet Coup, THE ATLANTIC, May 2009, http:// www.theatlantic.com/magazine/ archive/2009/05/thequiet- coup/7364/ (arguing that the financial industry gradually shaped both the technocratic and normative views of regulators).
    • (2009) The Atlantic
    • Johnson, S.1
  • 16
    • 0010199574 scopus 로고
    • On democracy- bashing: A skeptical look at the theoretical and "empirical" practice of the public choice movement
    • 204-05, 236-68
    • Mark Kelman, On Democracy- Bashing: A Skeptical Look at the Theoretical and "Empirical" Practice of the Public Choice Movement, 74 VA. L. REV. 199, 204-05, 236-68 (1988) (offering an earlier canvass of existing studies and arriving at the same conclusion).
    • (1988) Va. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 199
    • Kelman, M.1
  • 17
    • 84928076846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The paranoid style in the study of american politics
    • 257, Edward J. Balleisen & David A. Moss eds.
    • see also David A. Moss & Mary Oey, The Paranoid Style in the Study of American Politics, in GOVERNMENT AND MARKETS: TOWARD A NEW THEORY OF REGULATION 256, 257 (Edward J. Balleisen & David A. Moss eds., 2010) (describing three policy episodes-voting rights, Medicare, and Superfund-in which "special interests appear to have given way to the general interest in the policymaking process").
    • (2010) Government and Markets: Toward A New Theory of Regulation , pp. 256
    • Moss, D.A.1    Oey, M.2
  • 18
    • 0003415486 scopus 로고
    • For classic arguments for and against reviving the non-delegation doctrine, compare JOHN HART ELY, DEMOCRACY AND DISTRUST: A THEORY OF JUDICIAL REVIEW 125-34 (1980) (arguing for revival of non-delegation doctrine as a way to discipline congressional lawmaking)
    • (1980) Democracy and Distrust: A Theory of Judicial Review , pp. 125-134
    • Hart Ely, J.1
  • 21
    • 0005309033 scopus 로고
    • The illusion of the ideal administration
    • 1190
    • Louis L. Jaffe, The Illusion of the Ideal Administration, 86 HARV. L. REV. 1183, 1190 & n.37 (1973) (arguing against non-delegation's revival)
    • (1973) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.86 , Issue.37 , pp. 1183
    • Jaffe, L.L.1
  • 22
    • 0000942437 scopus 로고
    • The reformation of american administrative law
    • 1693-97
    • Richard B. Stewart, The Reformation of American Administrative Law, 88 HARV. L. REV. 1669, 1693-97 (1975) (same).
    • (1975) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 1669
    • Stewart, R.B.1
  • 23
    • 84865629036 scopus 로고
    • Indus. union dep't v. am. petroleum inst
    • 687, (Rehnquist, J., concurring)
    • The most prominent judicial argument in favor of reviving non-delegation is then-Justice Rehnquist's concurrence in the so-called Benzene Case. See Indus. Union Dep't v. Am. Petroleum Inst., 448 U.S. 607, 687 (1980) (Rehnquist, J., concurring) ("If we are ever to reshoulder the burden of ensuring that Congress itself make the critical policy decisions, these are surely the cases in which to do it. It is difficult to imagine a more obvious example of Congress simply avoiding a choice which was both fundamental for purposes of the statute and yet politically so divisive that the necessary decision or compromise was difficult, if not impossible, to hammer out in the legislative forge.").
    • (1980) U.S. , vol.448 , pp. 607
  • 24
    • 33645922622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whitman v. am. trucking ass'n
    • 476
    • As students of administrative law know, however, the Supreme Court decisively rejected the D.C. Circuit's attempt to revive non-delegation in Whitman v. Am. Trucking Ass'n, 531 U.S. 457, 476 (2001).
    • (2001) U.S. , vol.531 , pp. 457
  • 25
    • 0348080696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nondelegation canons
    • 316
    • Still, some have argued that non-delegation lives on in other forms. See, e.g., Cass R. Sunstein, Nondelegation Canons, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 315, 316 (2000) (arguing that non-delegation doctrine has been "relocated" to various canons of statutory interpretation).
    • (2000) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 315
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 26
    • 84876204140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rick perry's debate lapse: 'oops'-can't remember department of energy
    • Nov. 9
    • Arlette Saenz & Emily Friedman, Rick Perry's Debate Lapse: 'Oops'-Can't Remember Department of Energy, ABC NEWS, Nov. 9, 2011, http://abcnews.go.com/blogs/politics/2011/11/rick-perrys-debate-lapse-oops-cant- remember-departmentof- energy.
    • (2011) Abc News
    • Saenz, A.1    Friedman, E.2
  • 27
    • 79952750731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Insulating agencies: Avoiding capture through institutional design
    • 27-30
    • See, e.g., Rachel E. Barkow, Insulating Agencies: Avoiding Capture Through Institutional Design, 89 TEX. L. REV. 15, 27-30 (2010).
    • (2010) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 15
    • Barkow, R.E.1
  • 29
    • 0040877579 scopus 로고
    • Politics without romance: Implications of public choice theory for statutory interpretation
    • 285-87
    • William N. Eskridge, Jr., Politics Without Romance: Implications of Public Choice Theory for Statutory Interpretation, 74 VA. L. REV. 275, 285-87 (1988) (discussing varying interestgroup dynamics across policy contexts).
    • (1988) Va. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 275
    • Eskridge Jr., W.N.1
  • 32
    • 84876259014 scopus 로고
    • For policy "traceability" in the legislative context, but with obvious applications to the administrative process as well, see R. DOUGLAS ARNOLD, THE LOGIC OF CONGRESSIONAL ACTION 119-20 (1990) (describing congressional use of legislative procedures to conceal actions from public view or make it difficult to trace policy outcomes to legislative (in)action).
    • (1990) The Logic of Congressional Action , pp. 119-120
    • Douglas Arnold, R.1
  • 33
    • 84859643446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Administrative procedure act
    • See Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. § 500 (2006).
    • (2006) U.S.C. , vol.5 , pp. 500
  • 34
    • 0346933988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Administrative Procedure Act §§ 552-553 (setting forth procedural requirements for informal rulemaking).
    • Administrative Procedure Act , pp. 552-553
  • 35
    • 84935117599 scopus 로고
    • Congressional oversight overlooked: Police patrols versus fire alarms
    • 166, 176
    • Matthew O. McCubbins & Thomas Schwartz, Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms, 28 AM. J. POL. SCI. 165, 166, 176 (1984).
    • (1984) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.28 , pp. 165
    • McCubbins, M.O.1    Schwartz, T.2
  • 37
    • 30944467174 scopus 로고
    • Heckler v. chaney
    • 830-35
    • See Heckler v. Chaney, 470 U.S. 821, 830-35 (1985) (holding agency decisions not to enforce to be unreviewable under the APA).
    • (1985) U.S. , vol.470 , pp. 821
  • 38
    • 84902750245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ANDREW P. MORRISS, BRUCE YANDLE & ANDREW DORCHAK, REGULATION BY LITIGATION 1 (2009) (noting that "regulation-by- litigation" entails "bringing suits and achieving ends that could be and traditionally had been achieved by regulatory agencies using rulemaking procedures");
    • (2009) Regulation by Litigation , pp. 1
    • Morriss, A.P.1    Yandle, B.2    Dorchak, A.3
  • 40
    • 0038515255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unfinished business: How litigation relates to health care regulation
    • William M. Sage, Unfinished Business: How Litigation Relates to Health Care Regulation, 28 J. HEALTH POL. POL'Y & L. 387 (2003).
    • (2003) J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. , vol.28 , pp. 387
    • Sage, W.M.1
  • 41
    • 79251627544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally 31 U.S.C. § 3729-3733 (2006).
    • (2006) U.S.C. , vol.31 , pp. 3729-3733
  • 42
    • 84876253979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public regulation of private enforcement: Empirical analysis of doj oversight of qui tam litigation under the false claims act
    • forthcoming
    • David Freeman Engstrom, Public Regulation of Private Enforcement: Empirical Analysis of DOJ Oversight of Qui Tam Litigation Under the False Claims Act, 107 NW. U. L. REV. (forthcoming 2013).
    • (2013) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.107
    • Freeman Engstrom, D.1
  • 43
    • 84868618761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harnessing the private attorney general: Evidence from qui tam litigation
    • 1246
    • David Freeman Engstrom, Harnessing the Private Attorney General: Evidence from Qui Tam Litigation, 112 COLUM. L. REV. 1244, 1246 (2012) (noting more than 600 qui tam suits and $3 billion in recoveries in 2011 compared to 600 securities class actions and only $1.4 billion in recoveries in that same year).
    • (2012) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.112 , pp. 1244
    • Freeman Engstrom, D.1
  • 45
    • 84876268518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (last visited Nov. 4, 2012)
    • Iowa currently has four members of Congress on agricultural committees. Its two Senators sit on the Senate Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition and Forestry, and two of its five Representatives sit on the House Committee on Agriculture. See COMMITTEE MEMBERS, http://agriculture.house.gov/about/ membership (last visited Nov. 4, 2012) (listing the members of the Committee on Agriculture);
    • Committee Members
  • 46
    • 84876248294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (last visited Nov. 4, 2012)
    • COMMITTEE MEMBERSHIP, http://www.ag.senate.gov/about (last visited Nov. 4, 2012) (listing the members of the Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition and Forestry).
    • Committee Membership
  • 47
    • 0004026081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 232-34
    • To be sure, this is a contested point among political scientists, and some have countered the notion that committee members are outliers relative to the median legislator. See, e.g., KEITH KREHBIEL, PIVOTAL POLITICS: A THEORY OF U.S. LAWMAKING 191-200, 232-34 (1998) (offering evidence from the period 1993-1997 that most committee members have policy preferences close to that of the median floor member).
    • (1998) Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.s. Lawmaking , pp. 191-200
    • Krehbiel, K.1
  • 48
    • 0000796326 scopus 로고
    • Bureaucratic discretion or congressional control? regulatory policymaking by the federal trade commission
    • 779, 788-92
    • Other classic studies, however, clearly link committee composition to agency enforcement decisions. See Barry R. Weingast & Mark J. Moran, Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission, 91 J. POL. ECON. 765, 779, 788-92 (1983) (asserting that "firms located in districts represented on FTC oversight committees are favored in the commission's antitrust decisions" and that "[t]he statistical evidence implies that the FTC is remarkably sensitive to changes in the composition of its oversight subcommittee."). Two conclusions follow from studies of the latter type. First, capture of legislative committee members, if it happens, may exacerbate capture at the agency level via oversight activity. Second, committee actions cannot always be perfectly policed by legislative leaders even if committee members are not, on average and over time, ideological outliers relative to legislative medians.
    • (1983) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.91 , pp. 765
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Moran, M.J.2
  • 49
    • 43949093599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The other delegate: Judicially administered statutes and the nondelegation doctrine
    • See Margaret H. Lemos, The Other Delegate: Judicially Administered Statutes and the Nondelegation Doctrine, 81 S. CAL. L. REV. 405 (2008) (exploring the practice of congressional delegation to the judiciary).
    • (2008) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 405
    • Lemos, M.H.1
  • 50
    • 30944435969 scopus 로고
    • Legislative choice of regulatory forms: Legal process or administrative process?
    • 46-52
    • For earlier efforts to theorize about judicial delegations, see Morris P. Fiorina, Legislative Choice of Regulatory Forms: Legal Process or Administrative Process?, 39 PUB. CHOICE 33, 46-52 (1982);
    • (1982) Pub. Choice , vol.39 , pp. 33
    • Fiorina, M.P.1
  • 51
    • 33644679561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legislative allocation of delegated power: Uncertainty, risk, and the choice between agencies and courts
    • Matthew C. Stephenson, Legislative Allocation of Delegated Power: Uncertainty, Risk, and the Choice Between Agencies and Courts, 119 HARV. L. REV. 1035 (2006).
    • (2006) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.119 , pp. 1035
    • Stephenson, M.C.1
  • 52
    • 79956121151 scopus 로고
    • Why the "haves" come out ahead: Speculations on the limits of legal change
    • See Marc Galanter, Why the "Haves" Come Out Ahead: Speculations on the Limits of Legal Change, 9 LAW & SOC'Y REV. 97-103 (1974) (discussing the many advantages that "repeat players" have over the "one-shotters" in litigation).
    • (1974) Law & Soc'y Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 97-103
    • Galanter, M.1
  • 55
    • 84876211131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congressional abdication: Delegation without detail and without waiver
    • See, e.g., C. Boyden Gray, Congressional Abdication: Delegation Without Detail and Without Waiver, 36 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 41 (2013).
    • (2013) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.36 , pp. 41
    • Boyden Gray, C.1
  • 56
    • 84876217137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patriotism and taxation: The tax compliance implications of the tea party movement
    • 73, 74-76
    • "Starve the beast" commonly refers to the political strategy of cutting taxes before cutting spending, then using the ensuing budget deficit as an argument to reduce existing spending or reject new forms of spending. Though it has become a centerpiece of anti-tax advocates such as Grover Norquist, the term is often attributed to President Reagan's budget director, David Stockman. See, e.g., Richard Lavoie, Patriotism and Taxation: The Tax Compliance Implications of the Tea Party Movement, 45 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 39, 73 & n.134, 74-76 (2011) (tracing term's origins and reviewing existing studies about its efficacy as a political strategy).
    • (2011) Loy. L.a. L. Rev. , vol.45 , Issue.134 , pp. 39
    • Lavoie, R.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.