메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 25, Issue 7, 2012, Pages 45-55

Should Utilities Compensate Customers for Service Interruptions?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

CONDITION; FINANCIAL COMPENSATION; FINANCIAL PENALTY; SERVICE INTERRUPTION; STATE COMMISSIONS;

EID: 84867455432     PISSN: 10406190     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1016/j.tej.2012.08.001     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (6)

References (26)
  • 1
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • See Ronald Coase, The Problem of Social Cost
    • Oct.
    • See Ronald Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, J. LAW & ECON. 3 (Oct. 1960), at 1-44.
    • (1960) J. LAW & ECON , vol.3 , pp. 1-44
  • 2
    • 0035613563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mann, The Fairness Criterion in Public Utility Regulation: Does Fairness Still Matter?
    • (March), at
    • Doug N. Jones and Patrick C. Mann, The Fairness Criterion in Public Utility Regulation: Does Fairness Still Matter? J. ECON. ISSUES 35(1) (March 2001), at 153-72.
    • (2001) J. ECON. ISSUES , vol.35 , Issue.1 , pp. 153-172
    • Doug, N.J.1    Patrick, C.2
  • 3
    • 85168793391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A utility, for example, could be motivated to overspend on reliability to avoid outages
    • ''Overspending'' means that at an existing level of reliability the marginal benefits from reduced outages are less than the marginal costs.
    • A utility, for example, could be motivated to overspend on reliability to avoid outages. ''Overspending'' means that at an existing level of reliability the marginal benefits from reduced outages are less than the marginal costs.
  • 4
    • 85168785991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The latter pricing scheme reflects what economists call ''perfect price discrimination.''
    • Under this extreme form of discrimination, the utility would extract all the value that customers receive from electricity consumption. Although economically efficient, few people would consider this outcome to pass a ''fairness'' test.
    • The latter pricing scheme reflects what economists call ''perfect price discrimination.'' Under this extreme form of discrimination, the utility would extract all the value that customers receive from electricity consumption. Although economically efficient, few people would consider this outcome to pass a ''fairness'' test.
  • 5
    • 85168780321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One interpretation of ''reasonable care'' is that the customer should use the same degree of care that a person of ordinary prudence would exercise in the same or a similar situation.
    • One interpretation of ''reasonable care'' is that the customer should use the same degree of care that a person of ordinary prudence would exercise in the same or a similar situation.
  • 6
    • 85168776186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As pointed out elsewhere in this article, it could also be inefficient in the sense that customers would tend to be more careless in controlling the damages from a service interruption
    • As pointed out elsewhere in this article, it could also be inefficient in the sense that customers would tend to be more careless in controlling the damages from a service interruption.
  • 7
    • 85168791006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In restoring service, a utility incurs costs that it might never recover
    • Exceptions include a special rider that allows a utility to recover its costs from a major storm and deferred recovery of the costs during the next rate case
    • In restoring service, a utility incurs costs that it might never recover. Exceptions include a special rider that allows a utility to recover its costs from a major storm and deferred recovery of the costs during the next rate case.
  • 8
    • 85168785698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penalties for substandard reliability should exceed in dollars the higher costs for a utility to improve its reliability. Otherwise
    • the utility would prefer to pay the penalty and continue to have substandard reliability.
    • Penalties for substandard reliability should exceed in dollars the higher costs for a utility to improve its reliability. Otherwise, the utility would prefer to pay the penalty and continue to have substandard reliability.
  • 9
    • 85168782103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Customers would differ as to the additional amount they would be willing to pay because of the varying effect of outages on individual customers
    • Customers would differ as to the additional amount they would be willing to pay because of the varying effect of outages on individual customers.
  • 10
    • 85168785064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The outcome is also economically efficient in that the increased value of electricity to customers is greater than the additional costs to the utility
    • The assumption is that customers have an estimate of the decrease in the value of lost load from more reliable service.
    • The outcome is also economically efficient in that the increased value of electricity to customers is greater than the additional costs to the utility. The assumption is that customers have an estimate of the decrease in the value of lost load from more reliable service.
  • 11
    • 85168790182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ''Pareto optimality'' is an economically efficient world in which no person becomes better off without another person becoming worse off.
    • ''Pareto optimality'' is an economically efficient world in which no person becomes better off without another person becoming worse off.
  • 12
    • 85168778603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, American Society of Civil Engineers, Failure to Act: The Economic Impact of Current Investment Trends in Electricity Infrastructure (Reston, VA: American Society of Civil Engineers, April ). The report warns that if the country fails to make the necessary investments (which involves hundreds of billions of dollars) to upgrade its generation, transmission, and distribution systems, businesses and other power consumers will suffer more frequent blackouts and brownouts, motivating them to develop secondary or backup sources of power. The report estimated that power interruptions could cost an industrial firm between $2,000 and $5,000 and a commercial business between $700 and $1,300
    • See, for example, American Society of Civil Engineers, Failure to Act: The Economic Impact of Current Investment Trends in Electricity Infrastructure (Reston, VA: American Society of Civil Engineers, April 2012). The report warns that if the country fails to make the necessary investments (which involves hundreds of billions of dollars) to upgrade its generation, transmission, and distribution systems, businesses and other power consumers will suffer more frequent blackouts and brownouts, motivating them to develop secondary or backup sources of power. The report estimated that power interruptions could cost an industrial firm between $2,000 and $5,000 and a commercial business between $700 and $1,300.
    • (2012)
  • 13
    • 85168787535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From the author's observation, typically electric utilities apologize for a prolonged outage but then defend it as an uncontrollable event and refuse to offer any compensation to customers.
    • From the author's observation, typically electric utilities apologize for a prolonged outage but then defend it as an uncontrollable event and refuse to offer any compensation to customers.
  • 14
    • 85168793878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pacific Economics Group, Service Quality Regulation for Detroit Edison: A Critical Assessment, March and Pacific Economics Group Research, System Reliability Regulation: A Jurisdictional Survey. The latter study identified several states where regulators require utilities to report on their service-reliability metrics and monitor the utilities' performance for the metrics: In the U.S., eight States and the District of Columbia have system reliability targets for some of the utilities in the State, while 12 States have penalty/reward mechanisms for at least some utilities in the State. Seventeen U.S. States have system reliability monitoring regimes (at 52)
    • See Pacific Economics Group, Service Quality Regulation for Detroit Edison: A Critical Assessment, March 2007; and Pacific Economics Group Research, System Reliability Regulation: A Jurisdictional Survey. The latter study identified several states where regulators require utilities to report on their service-reliability metrics and monitor the utilities' performance for the metrics: In the U.S., eight States and the District of Columbia have system reliability targets for some of the utilities in the State, while 12 States have penalty/reward mechanisms for at least some utilities in the State. Seventeen U.S. States have system reliability monitoring regimes (at 52).
    • (2007)
  • 15
    • 85168778980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Serena Hesmondhalgh et al., Approaches to Setting Electric Distribution Reliability Standards and Outcomes
    • See also Serena Hesmondhalgh et al., Approaches to Setting Electric Distribution Reliability Standards and Outcomes.
  • 16
    • 85168789281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This argument assumes that a utility compensates customers based on their actual losses
    • It does not apply when a utility pays customers a fixed amount for outages no matter what the effect is on an individual customer.
    • This argument assumes that a utility compensates customers based on their actual losses. It does not apply when a utility pays customers a fixed amount for outages no matter what the effect is on an individual customer.
  • 17
    • 85168783232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This argument is dubious because studies have shown definitely that customer losses from power outages are much greater than any reduction they may receive on their bills
    • This argument is dubious because studies have shown definitely that customer losses from power outages are much greater than any reduction they may receive on their bills.
  • 18
    • 85168785512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The author is aware of only four utilities that pay compensation based on actual damages, subject to a cap and other specified conditions
    • They are Ameren and Commonwealth Edison in Illinois, Southern California Edison, and Consolidated Edison inNewYork.
    • The author is aware of only four utilities that pay compensation based on actual damages, subject to a cap and other specified conditions. They are Ameren and Commonwealth Edison in Illinois, Southern California Edison, and Consolidated Edison inNewYork.
  • 19
    • 85168780022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A counterargument is that compensation by itself could motivate a utility to upgrade its system
    • The motivation depends on the size of the compensation (assuming that the utility is unable to recover it from ratepayers) relative to the incremental cost of upgrades. If, for example, compensation were greater than the incremental cost, the utility would tend to upgrade its system. This outcome is efficient when customers value the increased reliability more than the additional costs for upgrading.
    • A counterargument is that compensation by itself could motivate a utility to upgrade its system. The motivation depends on the size of the compensation (assuming that the utility is unable to recover it from ratepayers) relative to the incremental cost of upgrades. If, for example, compensation were greater than the incremental cost, the utility would tend to upgrade its system. This outcome is efficient when customers value the increased reliability more than the additional costs for upgrading.
  • 20
    • 0001543237 scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Hung-Po Chao and Robert Wilson, Priority Service: Pricing, Investment, and Market Organization
    • (Dec.
    • See, for example, Hung-Po Chao and Robert Wilson, Priority Service: Pricing, Investment, and Market Organization, AMER. ECON. REV. 77(5) (Dec. 1987) at 899-916.
    • (1987) AMER. ECON. REV. , vol.77 , Issue.5 , pp. 899-916
  • 21
    • 85168777232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This problem also would arise if customers file a false claim.
    • This problem also would arise if customers file a false claim.
  • 22
    • 85168785695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the United Kingdom, for example, the regulator, the Office of the Gas and Electricity Markets (OFGEM), has what it calls Guaranteed Standards in place that require distribution companies to compensate customers, subject to certain exemptions, if the companies fail to restore service within a specified time period. The standards cover 12 areas, including service restoration, connections, and voltage quality. OFGEM expressed that the objective is to compensate customers for the inconvenience caused by an outage, and not for subsequent financial losses. The mechanism also gives distribution companies incentives to restore service as soon as practicable within a specified time period to avoid paying compensation. See
    • In the United Kingdom, for example, the regulator, the Office of the Gas and Electricity Markets (OFGEM), has what it calls Guaranteed Standards in place that require distribution companies to compensate customers, subject to certain exemptions, if the companies fail to restore service within a specified time period. The standards cover 12 areas, including service restoration, connections, and voltage quality. OFGEM expressed that the objective is to compensate customers for the inconvenience caused by an outage, and not for subsequent financial losses. The mechanism also gives distribution companies incentives to restore service as soon as practicable within a specified time period to avoid paying compensation. See http://www.ofgem.gov.uk/Networks/ ElecDist/QualofServ/GuarStandds/Pages/GuarStandds.aspx.
  • 23
    • 85168780345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ''Consumer surplus'' measures the difference between the value of consumed electricity and the outlays required by a customer to pay for the electricity
    • ''Consumer surplus'' measures the difference between the value of consumed electricity and the outlays required by a customer to pay for the electricity.
  • 24
    • 85168782508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical evidence is lacking as to whether utilities are the lowest-cost damage mitigator
    • This evidence would be important in identifying which party, from an efficiency perspective based on the Coase theorem, should be liable for outage damages.
    • Empirical evidence is lacking as to whether utilities are the lowest-cost damage mitigator. This evidence would be important in identifying which party, from an efficiency perspective based on the Coase theorem, should be liable for outage damages.
  • 25
    • 85168792289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As stated elsewhere in this article, however, customers do have some control over the damages they suffer from an outage
    • As stated elsewhere in this article, however, customers do have some control over the damages they suffer from an outage.
  • 26
    • 85168780489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A customer would have to show that the utility was negligent
    • resulting in damages, for example, in the formof spoiled food, water damage to a home, equipment failure, and repair costs
    • A customer would have to show that the utility was negligent, resulting in damages, for example, in the formof spoiled food, water damage to a home, equipment failure, and repair costs.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.