메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 64, Issue 3, 2001, Pages 4-

Multiplayer quantum games

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84861415972     PISSN: 10502947     EISSN: 10941622     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1103/PhysRevA.64.030301     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (11)

References (26)
  • 7
    • 85035274827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • D. A. Meyer, e-print http://xxx.lanl.gov/abs/ quant-ph/0004092.
    • Meyer, D.A.1
  • 9
    • 85035259868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • P. Ball, Nature (London)Science Update, 18 Oct. 1999.
    • Ball, P.1
  • 11
    • 85035291352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • G. Collins, Sci. Am. Int. Ed. Jan. 2000
    • G. Collins, Sci. Am. Int. Ed. Jan. 2000.
  • 12
    • 85035266733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. Eisert and M. Wilkens, e-print http://xxx.lanl.gov/abs/ quant-ph/0004076.
    • Eisert, J.1    Wilkens, M.2
  • 14
    • 85035301264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Without entanglement, the quantized form of Fig. 11(a) remains equivalent to the classical probabilistic game
    • Without entanglement, the quantized form of Fig. 11(a) remains equivalent to the classical probabilistic game.
  • 15
    • 85035282779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adopting the general bit-flip operator (Formula presented) would simply result in a trivial rotation of the features that we discover
    • Adopting the general bit-flip operator (Formula presented) would simply result in a trivial rotation of the features that we discover.
  • 16
    • 85035268863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Since we are interested in purely multipartite entanglement, we call a (pure) state maximally entangled if it is equivalent via local unitary operations to the GHZ-type state, (Formula presented)
    • Since we are interested in purely multipartite entanglement, we call a (pure) state maximally entangled if it is equivalent via local unitary operations to the GHZ-type state, (Formula presented).
  • 17
    • 85035289594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Any other (Formula presented) meeting these conditions would be equivalent, via local unitary operations, to our (Formula presented), and would therefore induce equilibria corresponding to ours
    • Any other (Formula presented) meeting these conditions would be equivalent, via local unitary operations, to our (Formula presented), and would therefore induce equilibria corresponding to ours.
  • 18
    • 85035249608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. Du, e-print quant-ph/0104087.
    • Du, J.1
  • 20
    • 85035282966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If the action is not drawn from (Formula presented) then the resulting state is necessarily not equivalent via local unitary operations to a GHZ state
    • If the action is not drawn from (Formula presented) then the resulting state is necessarily not equivalent via local unitary operations to a GHZ state.
  • 21
    • 85035284083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a survey of recent work on the classical game, see http://www.unifr.ch/econophysics/minority/
    • For a survey of recent work on the classical game, see http://www.unifr.ch/econophysics/minority/.
  • 22
    • 85035260285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interestingly, the complexity of the four player game is such that several Nash equilibria occur. Players may use criteria, such as maximum projection into the subspace of ‘classical’ moves (Formula presented), to establish a focal point, but this becomes a psychological question
    • Interestingly, the complexity of the four player game is such that several Nash equilibria occur. Players may use criteria, such as maximum projection into the subspace of ‘classical’ moves (Formula presented), to establish a focal point, but this becomes a psychological question.
  • 23
    • 85035253349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If we generate a pair of random classical bits, and send duplicates of these bits to each player, then Nash equilibria exist wherein the players use these bits to decide which player should be in the minority
    • If we generate a pair of random classical bits, and send duplicates of these bits to each player, then Nash equilibria exist wherein the players use these bits to decide which player should be in the minority.
  • 24
    • 85035250935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a focal symmetric strategy profile in this game, where each player adopts (Formula presented). However this profile is not a Nash equilibrium unless the players are actually constrained to unitary moves. One could presumably construct a similar game wherein this strategy profile does form a full Nash equilibrium—e.g., the game obtained by replacing the payoff columns in Fig. 22(b) by (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (top to bottom) looks promising in this respect
    • There is a focal symmetric strategy profile in this game, where each player adopts (Formula presented). However this profile is not a Nash equilibrium unless the players are actually constrained to unitary moves. One could presumably construct a similar game wherein this strategy profile does form a full Nash equilibrium—e.g., the game obtained by replacing the payoff columns in Fig. 22(b) by (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (Formula presented) (top to bottom) looks promising in this respect.
  • 25
    • 85035265683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • K. Kraus, States, Effects, and Operations: Fundamental Notions of Quantum Theory, Lecture Notes in Physics Vol. 190 (Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1983)
    • K. Kraus, States, Effects, and Operations: Fundamental Notions of Quantum Theory, Lecture Notes in Physics Vol. 190 (Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1983).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.