메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 77, Issue 3, 2011, Pages 855-888

Deal or no deal? Licensing negotiations in standard-setting organizations

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84857174864     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Conference Paper
Times cited : (40)

References (81)
  • 2
    • 84857182884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ( " A holder of IP incorporated into a standard can exploit its position if it is costly for users of the standard to switch to a different technology after the standard is set.") [hereinafter IP REPORT], available at
    • See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION 38 (2007) ( " A holder of IP incorporated into a standard can exploit its position if it is costly for users of the standard to switch to a different technology after the standard is set.") [hereinafter IP REPORT], available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf.
    • (2007) U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition , vol.38
  • 8
    • 84857188061 scopus 로고
    • (John Eatwell, Murray Milgate & Peter Newman eds.), The ability to act opportunistically does not imply that rights holders necessarily exercise this ability
    • Oliver D. Hart, Incomplete Contracts, in 2 THE NEW PALGRAVE: A DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS 752 (John Eatwell, Murray Milgate & Peter Newman eds., 1987). The ability to act opportunistically does not imply that rights holders necessarily exercise this ability.
    • (1987) Incomplete Contracts in 2 THE NEW PALGRAVE: A DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS , vol.752
    • Hart, O.D.1
  • 9
    • 84857182900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frequently Asked Questions ANSI
    • See Frequently Asked Questions, ANSI, http://www.ansi.org/about-ansi/ faqs/faqs.aspx?menuid=l.
  • 10
    • 0008283061 scopus 로고
    • [M]onopsony power is to the demand side of a market what monopoly power is to the supply side."). In what follows I use the terms "buyer market power by an SSO" and "SSO monopsony power" to refer to the collective exercise of buyer market power and monopsony power by members of the SSO. Concerns about licensee holdup can arise if the SSO has buyer market power that falls short of monopsony power
    • See Roger D. Blair & Jeffrey L. Harrison, Antitrust Policy and Monopsony, 76 CORNELL L. REV. 297, 306 (1991) ("[M]onopsony power is to the demand side of a market what monopoly power is to the supply side."). In what follows I use the terms "buyer market power by an SSO" and "SSO monopsony power" to refer to the collective exercise of buyer market power and monopsony power by members of the SSO. Concerns about licensee holdup can arise if the SSO has buyer market power that falls short of monopsony power.
    • (1991) Antitrust Policy and Monopsony 76 CORNELL L. REV. , vol.297 , pp. 306
    • Blair, R.D.1    Harrison, J.L.2
  • 11
    • 0038159322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While members of an SSO are often actual or potential competitors in markets for products that employ a technology included in a standard, such competition is not necessary for joint royalty negotiation to have anticompetitive effects. Technology users have a joint interest in securing a low royalty, and through collective action may be able to negotiate a lower royalty than any one of them could obtain through independent bilateral negotiation
    • See, e.g., David J. Teece & Edward F. Sherry, Standards Setting and Antitrust, 87 MINN. L. REV. 1913, 1928, 1931 (2003). While members of an SSO are often actual or potential competitors in markets for products that employ a technology included in a standard, such competition is not necessary for joint royalty negotiation to have anticompetitive effects. Technology users have a joint interest in securing a low royalty, and through collective action may be able to negotiate a lower royalty than any one of them could obtain through independent bilateral negotiation.
    • (2003) Standards Setting and Antitrust, 87 MINN. L. REV. , vol.1913-1928 , pp. 1931
    • Teece, D.J.1    Sherry, E.F.2
  • 12
    • 84857156323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business Review Letter from Thomas O. Bamett, Assistant Att'y Gen., to Robert A. Skitol, Drinker, Biddle & Reath, LLP (Oct. 30), [hereinafter VITA Letter], available at
    • See Business Review Letter from Thomas O. Bamett, Assistant Att'y Gen., to Robert A. Skitol, Drinker, Biddle & Reath, LLP (Oct. 30, 2006) [hereinafter VITA Letter], available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/ busreview/219380.pdf.
    • (2006)
  • 13
    • 84857188900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business Review Letter from Thomas O. Bamett, Assistant Att'y Gen., to Michael A. Lindsay, Dorsey & Whitney LLP (Apr. 30), [hereinafter IEEE Letter], available at
    • Business Review Letter from Thomas O. Bamett, Assistant Att'y Gen., to Michael A. Lindsay, Dorsey & Whitney LLP (Apr. 30, 2007) [hereinafter IEEE Letter], available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/busreview/222978.pdf.
    • (2007)
  • 15
    • 84857182886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remarks at Conference on Standardization and the Law: Developing the Golden Mean for Global Trade 7 (Sept. 23), ("[J]oint ex ante royalty discussions that are reasonably necessary to avoid holdup do not warrant per se condemnation. Rather, they merit the balancing undertaken in a rule of reason review."), available at
    • Chairman Deborah Piatt Majoras, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Recognizing the Procompetitive Potential of Royalty Discussions in Standard Setting, Remarks at Conference on Standardization and the Law: Developing the Golden Mean for Global Trade 7 (Sept. 23, 2005) ("[J]oint ex ante royalty discussions that are reasonably necessary to avoid holdup do not warrant per se condemnation. Rather, they merit the balancing undertaken in a rule of reason review."), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/majoras/050923stanford.pdf.
    • (2005) Chairman Deborah Piatt Majoras, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Recognizing the Procompetitive Potential of Royalty Discussions in Standard Setting
  • 17
    • 84857181214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Agencies describe the general analytic framework for evaluation of collaborations among competitors in Fed. Trade Comm'n & U.S. Dep't of Justice, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors, [hereinafter Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors], available at
    • The Agencies describe the general analytic framework for evaluation of collaborations among competitors in Fed. Trade Comm'n & U.S. Dep't of Justice, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors (2000) [hereinafter Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors], available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/04/ftcdojguidelines.pdf.
    • , vol.2000
  • 26
    • 0036961271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("One of the most common requirements imposed on IP owners is an obligation to license IP rights on reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms. But virtually no SSO policies specify what that phrase means, leaving courts to decide what terms are 'reasonable.'")
    • See, e.g., Mark A. Lemley, Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations, 90 CALIF. L. REV. 1889, 1913 (2002) ("One of the most common requirements imposed on IP owners is an obligation to license IP rights on reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms. But virtually no SSO policies specify what that phrase means, leaving courts to decide what terms are 'reasonable.'").
    • (2002) Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations, 90 CALIF. L. REV. , vol.1889 , pp. 1913
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 29
    • 84857156330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No. 06-509-JJF, 2006 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 61383 (D. Del. Aug. 16, 2006)
    • Nokia Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., No. 06-509-JJF, 2006 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 61383 (D. Del. Aug. 16, 2006).
    • Nokia Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc.
  • 44
    • 84857156328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing pivotal buyers in the context of exclusive dealing arrangements)
    • see also Ilya R. Segal & Michael D. Whinston, Naked Exclusion: Comment, 90 AM. ECON. REV. 296 (2000) (discussing pivotal buyers in the context of exclusive dealing arrangements).
    • (2000) Naked Exclusion: Comment, 90 AM. ECON. REV. , vol.296
    • Segal, I.R.1    Whinston, M.D.2
  • 45
    • 71949118352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ANSI policy states that "Voluntary consensus standards serve as the cornerstone of the U.S. standardization system. These documents arise from an open process that depends upon data gathering, a vigorous discussion of all viewpoints, and agreement among a diverse range of stakeholders, (2d ed., July 2, available at
    • ANSI policy states that "Voluntary consensus standards serve as the cornerstone of the U.S. standardization system. These documents arise from an open process that depends upon data gathering, a vigorous discussion of all viewpoints, and agreement among a diverse range of stakeholders." A N S I , OVERVIEW OF THE U . S . STANDARDIZATION SYSTEM 2 ( 2 d ed., July 2 0 0 7 ) , available at http://publicaa.ansi.org/sites/apdl/Documents/ News%20and%20Publications/Other%20Documents/US-Stdzn-System-FINAL.pdf.
    • (2007) ANSI, Overview of the U.S. Standardization System
  • 47
    • 84857188906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (rev. of JM21M, May), available at
    • JEDEC, JEDEC MANUAL OF ORGANIZATION AND PROCEDURE § 5 (rev. of JM21M, M a y 2 0 0 8 ) , available at http://www.jedec.org/sites/default/files/ JM21P%5Bl%5D.pdf.
    • (2008) JEDEC, JEDEC Manual of Organization and Procedure , vol.5
  • 48
    • 84857158417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The IEEE requires that at least 75 percent of a working group must vote on a proposed standard and 75 percent of the votes must be in the affirmative to adopt the standard, 5.4.3.1, available at
    • The IEEE requires that at least 75 percent of a working group must vote on a proposed standard and 75 percent of the votes must be in the affirmative to adopt the standard. IEEE-SA STANDARDS BOARD, I E E E - S A STANDARDS BOARD OPERATIONS MANUAL § 5 . 4 . 3 . 1 (2011), available at http://standards. ieee.org/guides/ opman/sect5.html.
    • (2011) IEEE-SA Standards Board, IEEE-SA Standards Board Operations Manual
  • 50
    • 84857188904 scopus 로고
    • Switching also may be difficult if alternatives are risky, if there is high demand for backward compatibility, or if switching would incur a loss of experience economies
    • See, e.g., Joseph Farrell & Garth Saloner, Coordination Through Committees and Markets, 19 RAND J. ECON. 235 (1988). Switching also may be difficult if alternatives are risky, if there is high demand for backward compatibility, or if switching would incur a loss of experience economies.
    • (1988) Coordination Through Committees and Markets, 19 RAND J. ECON. , vol.235
    • Farrell, J.1    Saloner, G.2
  • 51
    • 84857156337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Mar. 25), (PowerPoint presentation)
    • MPEG LA, ATSC Patent Portfolio License Briefing 7 (Mar. 25, 2010) (PowerPoint presentation), http://www.mpegla.com/main/programs/ATSC/Documents/ atscweb.ppt.
    • (2010) MPEG LA, ATSC Patent Portfolio License Briefing , vol.7
  • 52
    • 84857156338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • May 1, (PowerPoint presentation)
    • MPEG LA, AVC Patent Portfolio License Briefing 8-9 (May 1, 2011) (PowerPoint presentation), http://www.mpegla.com/main/programs/avc/Documents/ avcweb.ppt.
    • (2011) MPEG LA, AVC Patent Portfolio License Briefing , pp. 8-9
  • 53
  • 58
    • 84857182896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DVB-T, SISVEL, http://www.sisvel.com/english/licensingprograms/dvbt/ licensingprogram.
    • DVB-T SISVEL
  • 59
    • 84857156340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CDMA2000, SISVEL, http://www.sisvel.com/english/licensingprograms/ cda2/licenseterms.
    • CDMA2000, SISVEL
  • 60
    • 84857182893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Via Licensing-FAQs
    • See Via Licensing-FAQs, http://www.vialicensing.com/about/faq.aspx.
  • 68
    • 84857157336 scopus 로고
    • ("For any uniform price unequal to marginal cost, there is a nonlinear outlay schedule that is preferred by each consumer and that yields greater vendor profit.")
    • Robert D. Willig, Pareto-Superior Nonlinear Outlay Schedules, 9 BELL J. ECON. 56, 56 (1978) ("For any uniform price unequal to marginal cost, there is a nonlinear outlay schedule that is preferred by each consumer and that yields greater vendor profit.").
    • (1978) Pareto-Superior Nonlinear Outlay Schedules, 9 BELL J. ECON. , vol.56 , pp. 56
    • Willig, R.D.1
  • 69
    • 84857188911 scopus 로고
    • Note that licensing terms with late adopters can disadvantage early adopters even if late adopters are differentially locked in to the licensed technology as a consequence of investments that are specific to the technology, because the patentee can take advantage of lock-in by charging higher fixed fees
    • See R. Preston McAfee & Marius Schwartz, Opportunism in Multilateral Vertical Contracting: Nondiscrimination, Exclusivity, and Uniformity, 84 AM. ECON. REV. 210 (1994). Note that licensing terms with late adopters can disadvantage early adopters even if late adopters are differentially locked in to the licensed technology as a consequence of investments that are specific to the technology, because the patentee can take advantage of lock-in by charging higher fixed fees.
    • (1994) Opportunism in Multilateral Vertical Contracting: Nondiscrimination, Exclusivity, and Uniformity, 84 AM. ECON. REV. , vol.210
    • McAfee, R.P.1    Schwartz, M.2
  • 70
    • 77749308692 scopus 로고
    • For example, a licensing arrangement that prevents the licensee from dealing in other technologies may encourage the licensee to develop and market the licensed technology or specialized applications of that technology, available at
    • For example, a licensing arrangement that prevents the licensee from dealing in other technologies may encourage the licensee to develop and market the licensed technology or specialized applications of that technology. U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property 1 4.1.2 (1995), available at http://www.ftc. gov/bc/0558.pdf.
    • (1995) U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property 1 4.1.2
  • 71
    • 84857181237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business Review Letter from Joel I. Klein, Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Gerrard [sic] R. Beeney, Esq., Sullivan & Cromwell, at 13 ( June 26, 1997), available at
    • See, e.g., Business Review Letter from Joel I. Klein, Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Gerrard [sic] R. Beeney, Esq., Sullivan & Cromwell, at 13 (June 26, 1997), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/215742.pdf.
  • 72
    • 84857156342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business Review Letter from Joel I. Klein, Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Garrard R. Beeney, Esq., Sullivan & Cromwell, at 14 (Dec. 16, 1998), available at
    • Business Review Letter from Joel I. Klein, Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Garrard R. Beeney, Esq., Sullivan & Cromwell, at 14 (Dec. 16, 1998), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/ atr/public/busreview/2121 .pdf.
  • 73
    • 84857160322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • available at
    • See, e.g., ANSI, 62-2007 ANSI Patent Policy Revision (2007), available at http://publicaa.ansi.org/sites/apdl/ Reference%20Documents%20Regarding%20ANSI%20Patent%20Policy/62-2007%20ANSI%20 Patent%20Policy%20Revision.pdf.
    • (2007) ANSI, 62-2007 ANSI, Patent Policy Revision
  • 80
    • 69549090106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[T]he different strategic positions of integrated firms and innovation specialists may lead to the selection of inferior standards.")
    • See, e.g., Richard Schmalensee, Standard- Setting, Innovation Specialists and Competition Policy, 57 J. INDUS. ECON. 526, 543 (2009) ("[T]he different strategic positions of integrated firms and innovation specialists may lead to the selection of inferior standards.")
    • (2009) Standard- Setting, Innovation Specialists and Competition Policy, 57 J. INDUS. ECON. , vol.526 , pp. 543
    • Schmalensee, R.1
  • 81
    • 84857182898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The IEEE alone has an active portfolio of nearly 1300 standards and projects under development. See News & Events, IEEE STANDARDS ASSOCIATION, http://standards.ieee.org/announcements/index.html.
    • News & Events, IEEE Standards Association


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.