-
2
-
-
0003749661
-
-
examining the Takings Clause in a range of contexts and in connection with the role of the individual and the state
-
There have been many notable works in the vast literature on takings. See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain (1985) (examining the Takings Clause in a range of contexts and in connection with the role of the individual and the state);
-
(1985)
Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain
-
-
Epstein, R.A.1
-
3
-
-
0001656306
-
Property, utility, and fairness: Comments on the ethical foundations of just compensation law
-
analyzing the justifications for compensation in takings cases and proposing a fairness test
-
Frank I. Michelman, Property, Utility, and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical Foundations of "Just Compensation" Law, 80 Harv. L. Rev. 1165 (1967) (analyzing the justifications for compensation in takings cases and proposing a fairness test).
-
(1967)
Harv. L. Rev.
, vol.80
, pp. 1165
-
-
Michelman, F.I.1
-
4
-
-
33750049013
-
The neglected political economy of eminent domain
-
138-39
-
See, e.g., Nicole Stelle Garnett, The Neglected Political Economy of Eminent Domain, 105 Mich. L. Rev. 101, 138-39 (2006).
-
(2006)
Mich. L. Rev.
, vol.105
, pp. 101
-
-
Garnett, N.S.1
-
5
-
-
34147145292
-
Taking compensation private
-
offering a mechanism by which property owners could be fully compensated
-
See, e.g., Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, Taking Compensation Private, 59 Stan. L. Rev. 871 (2007) (offering a mechanism by which property owners could be fully compensated);
-
(2007)
Stan. L. Rev.
, vol.59
, pp. 871
-
-
Bell, A.1
Parchomovsky, G.2
-
6
-
-
84928220736
-
Efficient Just Compensation as a Limit on Eminent Domain
-
1279 arguing for limits on the government's power of eminent domain and government reimbursement for all large, concrete, and compensable costs resulting from takings
-
James Geoffrey Durham, Efficient Just Compensation as a Limit on Eminent Domain, 69 Minn. L. Rev. 1277, 1279 (1985) (arguing for limits on the government's power of eminent domain and government reimbursement for all large, concrete, and compensable costs resulting from takings);
-
(1985)
Minn. L. Rev.
, vol.69
, pp. 1277
-
-
Durham, J.G.1
-
7
-
-
0347450521
-
Making government pay: Markets, politics, and the allocation of constitutional costs
-
arguing that compensation remedies do not adequately deter constitutional violations by the government and other justifications for compensation are inadequate
-
Daryl J. Levinson, Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67 U. Chi. L. Rev. 345 (2000) (arguing that compensation remedies do not adequately deter constitutional violations by the government and other justifications for compensation are inadequate);
-
(2000)
U. Chi. L. Rev.
, vol.67
, pp. 345
-
-
Levinson, D.J.1
-
8
-
-
11144235344
-
Compensation for takings: How much is just?
-
724-25 finding that courts have been inconsistent in applying the Takings Clause and identifying standards by which compensation should be measured
-
Lunney G.S. Compensation for takings: How much is just? Cath. U. L. Rev. 1993 42 721.
-
(1993)
Cath. U. L. Rev.
, vol.42
, pp. 721
-
-
Lunney, G.S.1
-
9
-
-
0000492956
-
Compensation for the taking of land under eminent domain
-
proposing an economic model to address the moral hazard that occurs when landowners believe they will be undercompensated in a government takings and thus overinvest in their land
-
Thomas J. Miceli, Compensation for the Taking of Land Under Eminent Domain, 147 J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. 354 (1991) (proposing an economic model to address the moral hazard that occurs when landowners believe they will be undercompensated in a government takings and thus overinvest in their land);
-
(1991)
J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ.
, vol.147
, pp. 354
-
-
Miceli, T.J.1
-
10
-
-
20744452624
-
The meaning of value: Assessing just compensation for regulatory takings
-
680-81 arguing the level of proper compensation is directly related to how effectively the damages awards can fulfill the goals of the Takings Clause
-
Christopher Serkin, The Meaning of Value: Assessing Just Compensation for Regulatory Takings, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 677, 680-81 (2005) (arguing the level of proper compensation is directly related to how effectively the damages awards can fulfill the goals of the Takings Clause).
-
(2005)
Nw. U. L. Rev.
, vol.99
, pp. 677
-
-
Serkin, C.1
-
11
-
-
78650570755
-
-
Cf. Michelman, supra note 2, at 1171-72, 1235 (arguing that the correct test for compensation is whether it is fair)
-
Cf. Michelman, supra note 2, at 1171-72, 1235 (arguing that the correct test for compensation is whether it is fair).
-
-
-
-
12
-
-
11244275610
-
Regulatory taxings
-
2251 arguing against compensation for takings that are indistinguishable from permissible taxes and suggesting courts should take harm into account when determining whether and how much compensation should be paid
-
Cf. Eduardo Moisés Penalver, Regulatory Taxings, 104 Colum. L. Rev. 2182, 2251 (2004) (arguing against compensation for takings that are indistinguishable from permissible taxes and suggesting courts should take harm into account when determining whether and how much compensation should be paid).
-
(2004)
Colum. L. Rev.
, vol.104
, pp. 2182
-
-
Penalver, E.M.1
-
13
-
-
78650535898
-
-
Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 885-90
-
See Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 885-90;
-
-
-
-
14
-
-
49749092344
-
Taking eminent domain apart
-
958-59
-
Lee Anne Fennell, Taking Eminent Domain Apart, 2004 Mich. St. L. Rev. 957, 958-59 (2004);
-
(2004)
Mich. St. L. Rev.
, vol.2004
, pp. 957
-
-
Fennell, L.A.1
-
15
-
-
78650564171
-
-
Garnett, supra note 3, at 106-10
-
Garnett, supra note 3, at 106-10;
-
-
-
-
17
-
-
0009627364
-
The economics of public use
-
82-83
-
Thomas W. Merrill, The Economics of Public Use, 72 Cornell L. Rev. 61, 82-83 (1986).
-
(1986)
Cornell L. Rev.
, vol.72
, pp. 61
-
-
Merrill, T.W.1
-
19
-
-
78650583621
-
-
364 U.S. 40 (1960)
-
364 U.S. 40 (1960).
-
-
-
-
20
-
-
78650534604
-
-
Id. at 49
-
Id. at 49.
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
78650579243
-
-
Michelman, supra note 2
-
Michelman, supra note 2.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
78650527242
-
-
Id. at 1221-22
-
Id. at 1221-22.
-
-
-
-
23
-
-
78650525624
-
-
438 U.S. 104 (1978)
-
438 U.S. 104 (1978).
-
-
-
-
24
-
-
0000582934
-
The rise and rise of investment-backed expectations
-
437-38 The takings-determination phase of investment-backed expectations spans the period from its origination in a seminal 1967 article by Harvard law professor Frank Michelman, through its incorporation into constitutional jurisprudence by Justice Brennan in Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York...." (footnotes omitted)
-
Steven J. Eagle, The Rise and Rise of "Investment-Backed Expectations," 32 Urb. Law. 437, 437-38 (2000) ("The takings-determination phase of investment-backed expectations spans the period from its origination in a seminal 1967 article by Harvard law professor Frank Michelman, through its incorporation into constitutional jurisprudence by Justice Brennan in Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York....") (footnotes omitted).
-
(2000)
Urb. Law.
, vol.32
, pp. 437
-
-
Eagle, S.J.1
-
25
-
-
78650584289
-
-
Michelman, supra note 2, at 1214-24
-
Michelman, supra note 2, at 1214-24.
-
-
-
-
26
-
-
78650564501
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
78650567410
-
-
Id. at 1221
-
Id. at 1221.
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
78650574432
-
-
Id. at 1223
-
Id. at 1223.
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
78650555892
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
7544247458
-
-
Subsequent commentators have interpreted Michelman's analysis as suggesting that government pay compensation when demoralization costs exceed settlement costs but not otherwise. Interestingly, this does not appear explicitly in Michelman's article. See David A. Dana & Thomas W. Merrill, Property Takings 35-36 (2002).
-
(2002)
Property Takings
, pp. 35-36
-
-
Dana, D.A.1
Merrill, T.W.2
-
31
-
-
0347573321
-
Takings reassessed
-
284-89
-
The debate is generally phrased as identifying the difference between a government action that constitutes a taking - either a regulatory taking or a physical taking - and one that does not constitute a taking. For a collection of some of the many articles criticizing the Supreme Court's regulatory takings jurisprudence, see Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, Takings Reassessed, 87 Va. L. Rev. 277, 284-89 (2001).
-
(2001)
Va. L. Rev.
, vol.87
, pp. 277
-
-
Bell, A.1
Parchomovsky, G.2
-
32
-
-
78650524987
-
-
Dana & Merrill, supra note 19, at 33-34
-
Dana & Merrill, supra note 19, at 33-34.
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
42649117758
-
The problem of equality in takings
-
3-4
-
Nestor M. Davidson, The Problem of Equality in Takings, 102 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1, 3-4 (2008).
-
(2008)
Nw. U. L. Rev.
, vol.102
, pp. 1
-
-
Davidson, N.M.1
-
34
-
-
0010656167
-
Just compensation and just politics
-
292-93
-
Saul Levmore, Just Compensation and Just Politics, 22 Conn. L. Rev. 285, 292-93 (1990).
-
(1990)
Conn. L. Rev.
, vol.22
, pp. 285
-
-
Levmore, S.1
-
35
-
-
78650556902
-
-
Id. at 306-07, 310-11
-
Id. at 306-07, 310-11.
-
-
-
-
36
-
-
78650563223
-
-
Id. at 306-07
-
Id. at 306-07.
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
78650562886
-
-
Id. at 309
-
Id. at 309.
-
-
-
-
38
-
-
78650548442
-
-
Id. at 313
-
Id. at 313.
-
-
-
-
39
-
-
78650533448
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
78650561297
-
-
See Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 881-84
-
See Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 881-84;
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
84934562066
-
Compensation for takings: An economic analysis
-
620-22
-
Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Compensation for Takings: An Economic Analysis, 72 Cal. L. Rev. 569, 620-22 (1984);
-
(1984)
Cal. L. Rev.
, vol.72
, pp. 569
-
-
Blume, L.1
Rubinfeld, D.L.2
-
43
-
-
2542454297
-
Incomplete compensation for takings
-
131-32
-
Thomas W. Merrill, Incomplete Compensation for Takings, 11 N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. 110, 131-32 (2002);
-
(2002)
N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J.
, vol.11
, pp. 110
-
-
Merrill, T.W.1
-
44
-
-
77950290432
-
Takings and public choice: The persuasion of price
-
Charles Rowley & Friedrich Schneider eds., discussing how the government determines just compensation
-
see also William A. Fischel, Takings and Public Choice: The Persuasion of Price, in 2 The Encyclopedia of Public Choice 549 (Charles Rowley & Friedrich Schneider eds., 2003) (discussing how the government determines just compensation).
-
(2003)
The Encyclopedia of Public Choice
, vol.2
, pp. 549
-
-
Fischel, W.A.1
-
46
-
-
78650571229
-
-
See id. at 3
-
See id. at 3.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
78650547434
-
-
See Epstein, supra note 2
-
See Epstein, supra note 2.
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
69849084250
-
Takings: An appreciative retrospective
-
443
-
Epstein's work is generally seen as based upon a Lockean conception of property and the state. See, e.g., Eric R. Claeys, Takings: An Appreciative Retrospective, 15 Wm. & Mary BiU Rts. J. 439, 443 (2006);
-
(2006)
Wm. & Mary BiU Rts. J.
, vol.15
, pp. 439
-
-
Claeys, E.R.1
-
49
-
-
0347220405
-
The significance of public perceptions of the takings doctrine
-
1782
-
William W. Fisher III, The Significance of Public Perceptions of the Takings Doctrine, 88 Colum. L. Rev. 1774, 1782 (1988).
-
(1988)
Colum. L. Rev.
, vol.88
, pp. 1774
-
-
Fisher III, W.W.1
-
50
-
-
84864349437
-
Rent seeking and the compensation principle
-
1562 book review. We discuss the meaning of rent-seeking in Subsection I.B.4, infra
-
Thomas W. Merrill, Rent Seeking and the Compensation Principle, 80 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1561, 1562 (1986) (book review). We discuss the meaning of rent-seeking in Subsection I.B.4, infra.
-
(1986)
Nw. U. L. Rev.
, vol.80
, pp. 1561
-
-
Merrill, T.W.1
-
51
-
-
78650560019
-
-
See generally Dana & Merrill, supra note 19, at 41-46
-
See generally Dana & Merrill, supra note 19, at 41-46.
-
-
-
-
52
-
-
72649094360
-
-
317 U.S. 369, 374 In an effort... to find some practical standard, the courts early adopted, and have retained, the concept of market value
-
See United States v. Miller, 317 U.S. 369, 374 (1943) ("In an effort... to find some practical standard, the courts early adopted, and have retained, the concept of market value.");
-
(1943)
United States V. Miller
-
-
-
53
-
-
73049109432
-
-
844 F.2d 461, 464 7th Cir. [J]ust compensation' has been held to be satisfied by payment of market value
-
Coniston Corp. v. Vill. of Hoffman Estates, 844 F.2d 461, 464 (7th Cir. 1988) ('"[J]ust compensation' has been held to be satisfied by payment of market value.").
-
(1988)
Coniston Corp. V. Vill. of Hoffman Estates
-
-
-
54
-
-
78650538479
-
-
See Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 885-90 (finding the subjective value may exceed market value due to surplus subjective value, goodwill, community premiums, and transaction costs)
-
See Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 885-90 (finding the subjective value may exceed market value due to surplus subjective value, goodwill, community premiums, and transaction costs);
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
78650531189
-
-
Krier & Serkin, supra note 7, at 866
-
see also Krier & Serkin, supra note 7, at 866;
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
78650556579
-
Symposium, the death of poletown: The future of eminent domain and urban development after county of Wayne v. Hathcock
-
Symposium, The Death of Poletown: the Future of Eminent Domain and Urban Development After County of Wayne v. Hathcock, 2004 Mich. St. L. Rev. 837 (2004).
-
(2004)
Mich. St. L. Rev.
, vol.2004
, pp. 837
-
-
-
57
-
-
78650532465
-
-
For further discussion of the importance of compensation at subjective value, see Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 872-75
-
For further discussion of the importance of compensation at subjective value, see Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 4, at 872-75.
-
-
-
-
58
-
-
0042195345
-
Givings
-
For a discussion of the many ways in which the government voluntarily grants benefits to individuals, see Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, Givings, 111 Yale L.J. 547 (2001).
-
(2001)
Yale L.J.
, vol.111
, pp. 547
-
-
Bell, A.1
Parchomovsky, G.2
-
59
-
-
0000576340
-
Economic analysis and just compensation
-
Farber's article does not rely solely on the public choice or rent-seeking account presented here; indeed, Färber acknowledged the plausibility of other economic explanations for the compensation requirement. Daniel A. Färber, Economic Analysis and Just Compensation, 12 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 125 (1992).
-
(1992)
Int'l Rev. L. & Econ.
, vol.12
, pp. 125
-
-
Färber, D.A.1
-
60
-
-
78650549434
-
-
Id. at 131-32
-
Id. at 131-32.
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
78650545021
-
-
Id. at 130-31
-
Id. at 130-31.
-
-
-
-
62
-
-
78650559345
-
-
Id. at 125 "Public choice theory suggests that legislators normally offer compensation to landowners whose property is taken for a project, because they would form a powerful lobby against the project if not 'bought off
-
Id. at 125 ("Public choice theory suggests that legislators normally offer compensation to landowners whose property is taken for a project, because they would form a powerful lobby against the project if not 'bought off.'").
-
-
-
-
63
-
-
29344458072
-
Political economy and the efficiency of compensation for takings
-
190-95
-
Timothy J. Brennan & James Boyd, Political Economy and the Efficiency of Compensation for Takings, 24 Contemp. Econ. Pol'y 188, 190-95 (2006).
-
(2006)
Contemp. Econ. Pol'y
, vol.24
, pp. 188
-
-
Brennan, T.J.1
Boyd, J.2
-
64
-
-
78650526602
-
-
Id. at 191-93
-
Id. at 191-93.
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
78650544369
-
-
Id. at 195. For discussions of the problem that compensation may create "moral hazard" and incentivize over-development
-
Id. at 195. For discussions of the problem that compensation may create "moral hazard" and incentivize over-development,
-
-
-
-
66
-
-
78650552025
-
Not just compensation
-
35
-
see Abraham Bell, Not Just Compensation, 13 J. Contemp. Legal Issues 29, 35 (2003);
-
(2003)
J. Contemp. Legal Issues
, vol.13
, pp. 29
-
-
Bell, A.1
-
67
-
-
0010701194
-
Compensation for compulsory acquisition
-
Paul Burrows, Compensation for Compulsory Acquisition, 67 Land Econ. 49 (1991);
-
(1991)
Land Econ.
, vol.67
, pp. 49
-
-
Burrows, P.1
-
68
-
-
0000710082
-
Regulatory takings: When should compensation be paid?
-
750
-
Thomas J. Miceli & Kathleen Segerson, Regulatory Takings: When Should Compensation Be Paid?, 23 J. Legal Stud. 749, 750 (1994).
-
(1994)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.23
, pp. 749
-
-
Miceli, T.J.1
Segerson, K.2
-
69
-
-
78650525623
-
-
See Brennan & Boyd, supra note 45, at 196, 200
-
See Brennan & Boyd, supra note 45, at 196, 200.
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
78650584610
-
-
See id. at 190
-
See id. at 190.
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
78650528064
-
-
See id. at 191, 197
-
See id. at 191, 197.
-
-
-
-
72
-
-
78650564162
-
-
Univ. of Ala. Econ., Fin. & Legal Studies Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 09-04-01
-
Paul Pecorino, Optimal Compensation for Regulatory Takings (Univ. of Ala. Econ., Fin. & Legal Studies Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 09-04-01, 2009), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract- id=1392927. 52
-
(2009)
Optimal Compensation for Regulatory Takings
-
-
Pecorino, P.1
-
73
-
-
78650534603
-
-
See id. at 4, 6-7
-
See id. at 4, 6-7.
-
-
-
-
74
-
-
78650530321
-
-
See id. at 1, 4
-
See id. at 1, 4.
-
-
-
-
75
-
-
78650547120
-
-
Id. at 1
-
Id. at 1.
-
-
-
-
76
-
-
78650529032
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
78650528704
-
-
Epstein, supra note 2
-
Epstein, supra note 2.
-
-
-
-
78
-
-
78650565847
-
-
Id. at 15
-
Id. at 15.
-
-
-
-
79
-
-
78650558680
-
-
Id. at 12-13, 36
-
Id. at 12-13, 36.
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
78650556888
-
-
See, e.g., Levinson, supra note 4, at 396-400 (attacking Epstein's "libertarianism")
-
See, e.g., Levinson, supra note 4, at 396-400 (attacking Epstein's "libertarianism");
-
-
-
-
81
-
-
0347569385
-
The expanded debate over the future of the regulatory state
-
1484-91 describing Epstein as a "radical anti-interventionist
-
Thomas O. McGarity, The Expanded Debate over the Future of the Regulatory State, 63 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1463, 1484-91 (1996) (describing Epstein as a "radical anti-interventionist");
-
(1996)
U. Chi. L. Rev.
, vol.63
, pp. 1463
-
-
McGarity, T.O.1
-
82
-
-
84928446044
-
Taking takings seriously: An essay for centrists
-
1829 book review "Takings is a very poorly reasoned book; Epstein makes no serious substantive arguments for the positions he advances
-
Mark Kelman, Taking Takings Seriously: An Essay for Centrists, 74 Cal. L. Rev. 1829,1829 (1986) (book review) ("Takings is a very poorly reasoned book; Epstein makes no serious substantive arguments for the positions he advances.");
-
(1986)
Cal. L. Rev.
, vol.74
, pp. 1829
-
-
Kelman, M.1
-
83
-
-
84928447756
-
Takings
-
279-80 book review denouncing Takings as a patchwork that is "ahistorical," is "not... developed," and is not a "serious work of scholarship
-
Joseph L. Sax, Takings, 53 U. Chi. L. Rev. 279, 279-80 (1986) (book review) (denouncing Takings as a "patchwork" that is "ahistorical," is "not... developed," and is not a "serious work of scholarship").
-
(1986)
U. Chi. L. Rev.
, vol.53
, pp. 279
-
-
Sax, J.L.1
-
84
-
-
78650550412
-
-
Epstein, supra note 2, at 184.
-
Epstein, supra note 2, at 184.
-
-
-
-
85
-
-
78650581918
-
-
Id. at 199
-
Id. at 199.
-
-
-
-
86
-
-
78650576063
-
-
See generally Mueller, supra note 29, at 333-35
-
See generally Mueller, supra note 29, at 333-35.
-
-
-
-
87
-
-
84977416001
-
Rent-seeking: A survey
-
575-79
-
See Robert D. Tollison, Rent-Seeking: A Survey, 35 Kyklos 575, 575-79 (1982).
-
(1982)
Kyklos
, vol.35
, pp. 575
-
-
Tollison, R.D.1
-
88
-
-
78650564161
-
-
Merrill, supra note 30, at 1585-87
-
See Merrill, supra note 30, at 1585-87.
-
-
-
-
89
-
-
78650549065
-
-
See id. at 1577-78
-
See id. at 1577-78.
-
-
-
-
90
-
-
78650574426
-
-
Id. at 1578
-
Id. at 1578.
-
-
-
-
91
-
-
78650542872
-
-
See infra Part II
-
See infra Part II.
-
-
-
-
92
-
-
21844515693
-
An economic analysis of takings
-
65-66
-
Benjamin E. Hermalin, An Economic Analysis of Takings, 11 J.L. Econ. & Org. 64, 65-66 (1995).
-
(1995)
J.L. Econ. & Org.
, vol.11
, pp. 64
-
-
Hermalin, B.E.1
-
93
-
-
84979190207
-
The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft
-
using economic modeling to show that the social costs of tariffs and monopolies are larger than the literature indicates
-
See Gordon Tullock, The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft, 5 West. Econ. J. 224 (1967) (using economic modeling to show that the social costs of tariffs and monopolies are larger than the literature indicates).
-
(1967)
West. Econ. J.
, vol.5
, pp. 224
-
-
Tullock, G.1
-
94
-
-
0002968104
-
Rent seeking and profit seeking
-
James M. Buchanan et al. eds., shifting the focus of the study of rent seeking to nonmarket interactions and institutions as part of public choice theory
-
E.g., James M. Buchanan, Rent Seeking and Profit Seeking, in Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society 3, 3-15 (James M. Buchanan et al. eds., 1980) (shifting the focus of the study of rent seeking to nonmarket interactions and institutions as part of public choice theory).
-
(1980)
Toward A Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society
, vol.3
, pp. 3-15
-
-
Buchanan, J.M.1
-
95
-
-
0000420789
-
Toward a more general theory of regulation
-
212-13 developing a formal model of the "optimum size of effective political coalitions set within the framework of a general model of the political process
-
E.g., Sam Peltzman, Toward a More General Theory of Regulation, 19 J.L. & Econ. 211, 212-13 (1976) (developing a formal model of the "optimum size of effective political coalitions set within the framework of a general model of the political process").
-
(1976)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.19
, pp. 211
-
-
Peltzman, S.1
-
96
-
-
0001618495
-
A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence
-
presenting "a theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence
-
E.g., Gary S. Becker, A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, 98 Q.J. Econ. 371 (1983) (presenting "a theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence").
-
(1983)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.98
, pp. 371
-
-
Becker, G.S.1
-
97
-
-
0000367973
-
The political economy of the rent-seeking society
-
developing a model of competitive rent seeking for when rents originate from quantitative restrictions upon international trade
-
E.g., Anne O. Krueger, The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, 64 Am. Econ. Rev. 291 (1974) (developing a model of competitive rent seeking for when rents originate from quantitative restrictions upon international trade).
-
(1974)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.64
, pp. 291
-
-
Krueger, A.O.1
-
99
-
-
0000296028
-
Rent extraction and rent creation in the economic theory of regulation
-
Fred S. McChesney, Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of Regulation, 16 J. Legal Stud. 101 (1987).
-
(1987)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.16
, pp. 101
-
-
McChesney, F.S.1
-
100
-
-
78650535889
-
-
Tullock, supra note 69, at 228
-
75See Tullock, supra note 69, at 228.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
78650529645
-
-
McChesney, Money for Nothing, supra note 74, at 55-66
-
McChesney, Money for Nothing, supra note 74, at 55-66.
-
-
-
-
102
-
-
78650529990
-
-
See Peltzman, supra note 71, at 214
-
See Peltzman, supra note 71, at 214.
-
-
-
-
104
-
-
78650550411
-
-
See supra Section IIA
-
See supra Section IIA.
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
78650578614
-
-
545 U.S. 469 (2005) finding that there was no basis for exempting economic development from the broad definition of "public purpose" and allowing a developer to acquire properties by eminent domain for the construction of a retail and residential complex
-
545 U.S. 469 (2005) (finding that there was no basis for exempting economic development from the broad definition of "public purpose" and allowing a developer to acquire properties by eminent domain for the construction of a retail and residential complex).
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
78650554687
-
-
304 N.W.2d 455 (Mich. 1981) holding that the city did not abuse its discretion in condemning properties in order to convey the land to a private company for the creation of an industrial site that would create jobs and promote the public welfare
-
304 N.W.2d 455 (Mich. 1981) (holding that the city did not abuse its discretion in condemning properties in order to convey the land to a private company for the creation of an industrial site that would create jobs and promote the public welfare).
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
78650556887
-
-
Krier & Serkin, supra note 7, at 859-60 For views critical of the lax public use doctrine employed by courts in these cases to uphold the takings
-
See Krier & Serkin, supra note 7, at 859-60. For views critical of the lax public use doctrine employed by courts in these cases to uphold the takings,
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
78650552504
-
-
see Epstein, supra note 2, at 161-81
-
see Epstein, supra note 2, at 161-81;
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
67549091155
-
Controlling the grasping hand: Economic development takings after kelo
-
Ilya Somin, Controlling the Grasping Hand: Economic Development Takings after Kelo, 15 S. Ct. Econ. Rev. 183 (2007).
-
(2007)
S. Ct. Econ. Rev.
, vol.15
, pp. 183
-
-
Somin, I.1
-
110
-
-
78650562873
-
-
For a general discussion of the problems of givings, see Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 40
-
For a general discussion of the problems of givings, see Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 40.
-
-
-
-
111
-
-
78650561597
-
Eminent domain for private sports stadiums: Fair ball or foul?
-
315 explaining that the land needed for municipallyfinanced sports stadiums is often acquired through eminent domain
-
See Philip Weinberg, Eminent Domain for Private Sports Stadiums: Fair Ball or Foul?, 35 Envtl. L. 311, 315 (2005) (explaining that the land needed for municipallyfinanced sports stadiums is often acquired through eminent domain);
-
(2005)
Envtl. L.
, vol.35
, pp. 311
-
-
Weinberg, P.1
-
112
-
-
0002529389
-
Build the stadium-create the jobs!
-
Roger G. Noll & Andrew Zimbalist eds., explaining that local government often pays for acquiring the land, most of the site preparation, and some of the stadium construction costs before leasing it to a sports team
-
see also Roger G. Noll & Andrew Zimbalist, "Build the Stadium-Create the Jobs!," in Sports, Jobs, and Taxes: The Economic Impact of Sports Teams and Stadiums 1, 7-8 (Roger G. Noll & Andrew Zimbalist eds., 1997) (explaining that local government often pays for acquiring the land, most of the site preparation, and some of the stadium construction costs before leasing it to a sports team).
-
(1997)
Sports, Jobs, and Taxes: The Economic Impact of Sports Teams and Stadiums
, vol.1
, pp. 7-8
-
-
Noll, R.G.1
Zimbalist, A.2
-
113
-
-
78650573770
-
-
Brennan & Boyd, supra note 45, at 191 finding that where landowners and those in favor of land use regulations (e.g., environmentalists) have equal political influence, the social optimum is reached without a need for takings compensation. But transaction costs are almost never symmetric, and this result is not likely to ever occur in the real world
-
Admittedly, were there absolute symmetry in transaction costs between property owners and developers, the existence of givings would eliminate the need for takings compensation. Property would be allocated optimally even without takings compensation and givings charges: any threat to take and give the property would result in an auction between equally situated owners and developers and result in a win for the superior property holder. Brennan and Boyd reached a similar result. Brennan & Boyd, supra note 45, at 191 (finding that where landowners and those in favor of land use regulations (e.g., environmentalists) have equal political influence, the social optimum is reached without a need for takings compensation). But transaction costs are almost never symmetric, and this result is not likely to ever occur in the real world.
-
-
-
-
114
-
-
78650579587
-
-
See supra Subsection I.B.3
-
See supra Subsection I.B.3.
-
-
-
-
115
-
-
84934562066
-
Compensation for takings: An economic analysis
-
evaluating the arguments for and against compensation as a form of insurance against regulatory takings
-
See Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Compensation for Takings: An Economic Analysis, 72 Cal. L. Rev. 569 (1984) (evaluating the arguments for and against compensation as a form of insurance against regulatory takings);
-
(1984)
Cal. L. Rev.
, vol.72
, pp. 569
-
-
Blume, L.1
Rubinfeld, D.L.2
-
116
-
-
0021576415
-
The taking of land: When should compensation be paid?
-
questioning whether compensation for eminent domain takings is efficient
-
Lawrence Blume, Daniel L. Rubinfeld & Perry Shapiro, The Taking of Land: When Should Compensation Be Paid?, 99 Q.J. Econ. 71 (1984) (questioning whether compensation for eminent domain takings is efficient);
-
(1984)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.99
, pp. 71
-
-
Blume, L.1
Rubinfeld, D.L.2
Shapiro, P.3
-
117
-
-
0002877397
-
Takings, insurance, and michelman: Comments on economic interpretations of just compensation law
-
exploring noncompensation and insurance models
-
William A. Fischel & Perry Shapiro, Takings, Insurance, and Michelman: Comments on Economic Interpretations of "Just Compensation" Law, 17 J. Legal Stud. 269 (1988) (exploring noncompensation and insurance models);
-
(1988)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.17
, pp. 269
-
-
Fischel, W.A.1
Shapiro, P.2
-
118
-
-
84934564251
-
An economic analysis of legal transitions
-
addressing the impact of transitional government policy in connection with takings and other economic reforms
-
Louis Kaplow, An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions, 99 Harv. L. Rev. 509 (1986) (addressing the impact of transitional government policy in connection with takings and other economic reforms).
-
(1986)
Harv. L. Rev.
, vol.99
, pp. 509
-
-
Kaplow, L.1
-
119
-
-
49749092344
-
Taking eminent domain apart
-
958-59
-
See, e.g., Lee Anne Fennell, Taking Eminent Domain Apart, 2004 Mich. St. L. Rev. 957, 958-59 (2004).
-
(2004)
Mich. St. L. Rev.
, vol.2004
, pp. 957
-
-
Fennell, L.A.1
-
120
-
-
78650565846
-
-
See supra Subsection I.B.4
-
See supra Subsection I.B.4.
-
-
-
-
121
-
-
1842618721
-
-
§32-244.5-8(2)(A)
-
Ind. Code Ann. §32-244.5-8(2)(A) (2006).
-
(2006)
Ind. Code Ann.
-
-
-
122
-
-
77951269478
-
-
§§523.039(2)-(3)
-
Mo. Ann. Stat. §§523.039(2)-(3) (2006).
-
(2006)
Mo. Ann. Stat.
-
-
-
123
-
-
70449371664
-
Identifying intense preferences
-
1408-09
-
For further examples, see Daphna Lewinsohn-Zamir, Identifying Intense Preferences, 94 Cornell L. Rev. 1391, 1408-09 (2009).
-
(2009)
Cornell L. Rev.
, vol.94
, pp. 1391
-
-
Lewinsohn-Zamir, D.1
-
125
-
-
72649094360
-
-
317 U.S. 369, 374 (1943) (explaining that, for practical reasons, "courts early adopted, and have retained, the concept of market value" in determining takings compensation)
-
see also United States v. Miller, 317 U.S. 369, 374 (1943) (explaining that, for practical reasons, "courts early adopted, and have retained, the concept of market value" in determining takings compensation).
-
United States V. Miller
-
-
-
126
-
-
0348190012
-
Levinson, framing transactions in constitutional law
-
Daryl J. Levinson, Framing Transactions in Constitutional Law, 111 Yale L.J. 1311 (2002).
-
(2002)
Yale L.J.
, vol.111
, pp. 1311
-
-
Daryl, J.1
-
127
-
-
78650530615
-
-
Id. at 1338
-
Id. at 1338.
-
-
-
-
128
-
-
78650536215
-
-
Id. at 1315
-
Id. at 1315.
-
-
-
-
129
-
-
78650535232
-
-
Id. at 1315-17
-
Id. at 1315-17.
-
-
-
-
130
-
-
78650563537
-
-
Id. at 1340
-
Id. at 1340.
-
-
-
-
131
-
-
78650577972
-
-
See supra Section II.B
-
See supra Section II.B.
-
-
-
-
132
-
-
78650574104
-
-
Kaplow, supra note 87
-
Kaplow, supra note 87.
-
-
-
-
133
-
-
78650574770
-
-
Blume, Rubinfeld & Shapiro, supra note 87
-
Blume, Rubinfeld & Shapiro, supra note 87.
-
-
-
-
134
-
-
78650527232
-
-
See id.
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
135
-
-
78650542542
-
-
Blume & Rubinfeld, supra note 87, at 572
-
Blume & Rubinfeld, supra note 87, at 572.
-
-
-
-
136
-
-
78650564800
-
-
See, e.g., Kaplow, supra note 87, at 603
-
See, e.g., Kaplow, supra note 87, at 603.
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
78650551353
-
-
Fischel & Shapiro, supra note 87, at 286
-
Fischel & Shapiro, supra note 87, at 286.
-
-
-
-
139
-
-
78650525298
-
-
See supra Section II.B
-
See supra Section II.B.
-
-
-
-
140
-
-
78650549422
-
-
See supra Section II.B
-
See supra Section II.B.
-
-
-
-
141
-
-
78650557854
-
-
See infra Appendix, Proposition 3
-
See infra Appendix, Proposition 3.
-
-
-
-
142
-
-
78650582230
-
-
e will be zero
-
e will be zero.
-
-
-
-
143
-
-
78650540589
-
-
Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 40
-
Bell & Parchomovsky, supra note 40.
-
-
-
-
144
-
-
78650554059
-
-
See id. at 615-17
-
See id. at 615-17.
-
-
-
|