-
1
-
-
78650067235
-
-
Parties in polarized systems are more reluctant to initiate political crises - due to ideological or other reasons - for fear of breaking up a coalition. This is so because they see no alternative to the present coalition except early elections
-
Parties in polarized systems are more reluctant to initiate political crises - due to ideological or other reasons - for fear of breaking up a coalition. This is so because they see no alternative to the present coalition except early elections.
-
-
-
-
2
-
-
78650046870
-
-
A proto-coalition is defined as a coalition that could potentially form given the ideological positions of its members and their seat proportions
-
A proto-coalition is defined as a coalition that could potentially form given the ideological positions of its members and their seat proportions.
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
84937292823
-
Coalition termination and the strategic timing of parliamentary elections
-
Arthur Lupia and Kaare Strøm, 'Coalition Termination and the Strategic Timing of Parliamentary Elections', American Political Science Review, 89 (1995), 648-65;
-
(1995)
American Political Science Review
, vol.89
, pp. 648-665
-
-
Lupia, A.1
Strøm, K.2
-
6
-
-
78650070396
-
-
One may argue that the two hypotheses are, in fact, identical because cabinet duration is correlated with the number of cabinets in a given electoral cycle. While this may be true in principle, the actual correlation in our data between these two measures of political stability is moderate but not as high as one would expect. We discuss this below
-
One may argue that the two hypotheses are, in fact, identical because cabinet duration is correlated with the number of cabinets in a given electoral cycle. While this may be true in principle, the actual correlation in our data between these two measures of political stability is moderate but not as high as one would expect. We discuss this below.
-
-
-
-
7
-
-
84965943789
-
The durability of coalition governments in parliamentary democracies
-
Paul V. Warwick, 'The Durability of Coalition Governments in Parliamentary Democracies', Comparative Political Studies, 11 (1979), 465-98.
-
(1979)
Comparative Political Studies
, vol.11
, pp. 465-498
-
-
Warwick, P.V.1
-
11
-
-
0037273448
-
A structural model of government formation
-
Daniel Diermeier, Hulya Eraslan and Antonio Merlo, 'A Structural Model of Government Formation', Econometrica, 71 (2003), 27-70.
-
(2003)
Econometrica
, vol.71
, pp. 27-70
-
-
Diermeier, D.1
Eraslan, H.2
Merlo, A.3
-
13
-
-
77956907070
-
A unified model of cabinet duration in parliamentary democracies
-
King et al. Gary King, James E. Alt, Nancy Elizabeth Burns, and
-
King et al. (Gary King, James E. Alt, Nancy Elizabeth Burns and Michael Laver, 'A Unified Model of Cabinet Duration in Parliamentary Democracies', American Journal of Political Science, 34 (1990), 846-71)
-
(1990)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.34
, pp. 846-871
-
-
Laver, M.1
-
16
-
-
84927455107
-
Comparing party systems: A multidimensional approach
-
Donald A. Gross and Lee Sigelman, 'Comparing Party Systems: A Multidimensional Approach', Comparative Politics, 16 (1984), 463-79.
-
(1984)
Comparative Politics
, vol.16
, pp. 463-479
-
-
Gross, D.A.1
Sigelman, L.2
-
17
-
-
8344277511
-
Polarization: Concepts, measurement, estimation
-
Jean Yves Duclos, Joan Esteban and Debraj Ray, 'Polarization: Concepts, Measurement, Estimation', Econometrica, 72 (2004), 1737-72;
-
(2004)
Econometrica
, vol.72
, pp. 1737-1772
-
-
Duclos, J.Y.1
Esteban, J.2
Ray, D.3
-
18
-
-
0000595914
-
On the measurement of polarization
-
Joan-Maria Esteban and Debraj Ray, 'On the Measurement of Polarization', Econometrica, 62 (1994), 819-51.
-
(1994)
Econometrica
, vol.62
, pp. 819-851
-
-
Esteban, J.1
Ray, D.2
-
19
-
-
73749088206
-
United we stand: Constituency homogeneity and comparative party polarization
-
Philipp Rehm and Timothy Reilly, 'United We Stand: Constituency Homogeneity and Comparative Party Polarization', Electoral Studies, 29 (2010), 40-53.
-
(2010)
Electoral Studies
, vol.29
, pp. 40-53
-
-
Rehm, P.1
Reilly, T.2
-
20
-
-
78650068113
-
-
unpublished paper, University of California, Davis
-
Zeev Maoz, 'Network Polarization' unpublished paper, University of California, Davis (2009).
-
(2009)
Network Polarization
-
-
Maoz, Z.1
-
21
-
-
0003492719
-
-
Additional measures of polarization are based on the ideological difference between the largest parties in the system, Oxford: Oxford University Press
-
Additional measures of polarization are based on the ideological difference between the largest parties in the system (Alan Ware, Political Parties and Party Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1996))
-
(1996)
Political Parties and Party Systems
-
-
Ware, A.1
-
22
-
-
23844550583
-
-
standardized left-right policy differences between all pairs of parties, and, unpublished manuscript, Wissenschaftzentrum Berlin fur Sozialforschung
-
the standardized left-right policy differences between all pairs of parties (Hans-Dieter Klingemann and Bernhard Wessels, 'Sincere Voting in Different Electoral Systems' (unpublished manuscript, Wissenschaftzentrum Berlin fur Sozialforschung, 2002)
-
(2002)
Sincere Voting in Different Electoral Systems
-
-
Klingemann, H.1
Wessels, B.2
-
23
-
-
21044456939
-
Party system compactness: Measurement and consequences
-
or on the ideological compactness of the system using both the ideological diversity of voters and the issue distances between each pair of parties, and
-
or on the ideological compactness of the system using both the ideological diversity of voters and the issue distances between each pair of parties (Michael R. Alvarez and Jonathan Nagler, 'Party System Compactness: Measurement and Consequences', Political Analysis, 12 (2004), 46-62).
-
(2004)
Political Analysis
, vol.12
, pp. 46-62
-
-
Alvarez, M.R.1
Nagler, J.2
-
24
-
-
78650042929
-
-
i is the seat shares of clique i
-
i is the seat shares of clique i.
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
0003948494
-
-
See, and, New York: Cambridge University Press
-
See Stanley Wasserman and Katherine Faust, Social Network Analysis (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997), pp. 3-17;
-
(1997)
Social Network Analysis
, pp. 3-17
-
-
Wasserman, S.1
Faust, K.2
-
27
-
-
78650038298
-
-
These figures are drawn using the twenty-six issues from the CMP dataset. These data are discussed below
-
These figures are drawn using the twenty-six issues from the CMP dataset. These data are discussed below.
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
33745302792
-
Systemic polarization, interdependence, and international conflict, 1816-2002
-
See Maoz
-
See Maoz (Zeev Maoz, 'Systemic Polarization, Interdependence, and International Conflict, 1816-2002', Journal of Peace Research, 43 (2006), 391-411;
-
(2006)
Journal of Peace Research
, vol.43
, pp. 391-411
-
-
Maoz, Z.1
-
29
-
-
78650050505
-
-
'Network Polarization' for more details on the measurement of this polarization index. The index presented here offers a slight variation and a number of extensions on Maoz, An elaborate explanation and derivation of this index is given in Maoz, 'Network Polarization'
-
and 'Network Polarization') for more details on the measurement of this polarization index. The index presented here offers a slight variation (and a number of extensions) on Maoz ('Systemic Polarization, Interdependence, and International Conflict, 1816-2002', pp. 395-7). An elaborate explanation and derivation of this index is given in Maoz, 'Network Polarization'.
-
Systemic Polarization, Interdependence, and International Conflict, 1816-2002
, pp. 395-397
-
-
-
30
-
-
78650052403
-
-
our analyses, we use three different cut-off points to designate cliques. See the discussion in the text
-
In our analyses, we use three different cut-off points to designate cliques. See the discussion in the text.
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
78650037694
-
-
maximum value of COI asymptotically approaches 1 as k becomes sufficiently large. Maoz 'Network Polarization' provides more details on the properties of this index
-
The maximum value of COI asymptotically approaches 1 as k becomes sufficiently large. Maoz ('Network Polarization') provides more details on the properties of this index.
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
78650039635
-
-
countries included in the dataset are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain and Sweden
-
The countries included in the dataset are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain and Sweden.
-
-
-
-
39
-
-
0004162268
-
-
Oxford: Oxford University Press
-
Ian Budge, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Eric Tannenbaum and Judith Bara, Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001).
-
(2001)
Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998
-
-
Budge, I.1
Klingemann, H.2
Volkens, A.3
Tannenbaum, E.4
Bara, J.5
-
40
-
-
2142745735
-
Checking the party policy estimates: Reliability
-
These measures generally correlate with other widely used measures on party positioning like expert surveys, party placements of election survey respondents and other word-scoring techniques. See, e.g., in Ian Budge, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Eric Tannenbaum and Judith Bara, eds, Oxford: Oxford University Press
-
These measures generally correlate with other widely used measures on party positioning like expert surveys, party placements of election survey respondents and other word-scoring techniques. See, e.g., Derek Hearl, 'Checking the Party Policy Estimates: Reliability', in Ian Budge, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Eric Tannenbaum and Judith Bara, eds, Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), pp. 111-25;
-
(2001)
Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998
, pp. 111-125
-
-
Hearl, D.1
-
41
-
-
7644233213
-
Checking the party policy estimates: Convergent validity
-
in Budge et al., eds.
-
Michael McDonald and Sylvia Mendes, 'Checking the Party Policy Estimates: Convergent Validity', in Budge et al., eds., Mapping Policy Preferences, pp. 127-41;
-
Mapping Policy Preferences
, pp. 127-141
-
-
McDonald, M.1
Mendes, S.2
-
42
-
-
0038385893
-
Extracting policy positions from political texts using words as data
-
Michael Laver, Kenneth Benoit and John Garry, 'Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts Using Words as Data', American Political Science Review, 97 (2003), 311-31.
-
(2003)
American Political Science Review
, vol.97
, pp. 311-331
-
-
Laver, M.1
Benoit, K.2
Garry, J.3
-
44
-
-
0004162268
-
-
See, for the details of measurement for the specific issues we used
-
See Budge et al., Mapping Policy Preferences, for the details of measurement for the specific issues we used.
-
Mapping Policy Preferences
-
-
Budge1
-
46
-
-
78650047299
-
-
This cut-off point may seem arbitrary. Thus, we used two additional cut-off points. The first was the median of the distribution of overlap figures which was sometimes higher and sometimes lower than the mean, for different elections and for different countries. The second was the two-third percentile 67 percentile level of overlap. We label this as NPI p67. This cut-off point created a significantly smaller set of proto-coalitions than did the other two cut-off points. The results of this sensitivity variation were a set of three different measures of NPI which differed quite significantly from each other. The substantive results are retained, however. The results of these additional analyses can be found on our web-page at, From this point on, we proceed to measure NPI in the manner described in the previous section
-
This cut-off point may seem arbitrary. Thus, we used two additional cut-off points. The first was the median of the distribution of overlap figures (which was sometimes higher and sometimes lower than the mean, for different elections and for different countries). The second was the two-third percentile (67 percentile) level of overlap. We label this as NPI (p67). This cut-off point created a significantly smaller set of proto-coalitions than did the other two cut-off points. The results of this sensitivity variation were a set of three different measures of NPI which differed quite significantly from each other. The substantive results are retained, however. The results of these additional analyses can be found on our web-page at http://psfaculty.ucdavis.edu/zmaoz/ datasets.htm. From this point on, we proceed to measure NPI in the manner described in the previous section.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
78650050504
-
-
ij = 1-
-
ij is in the [0, 1] range and higher values indicate strong ideological affinity between parties.
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
78650049224
-
-
See Appendix Table for descriptive statistics. One important point to note is that the variation of NPI over the range of possible values is much larger than the variation of other polarization indices over their possible ranges
-
See Appendix Table for descriptive statistics. One important point to note is that the variation of NPI over the range of possible values is much larger than the variation of other polarization indices over their possible ranges.
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
78650054553
-
-
See Appendix for more details on these control variables
-
See Appendix for more details on these control variables.
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
78650039125
-
-
our data, the relationship between the status of a cabinet minority or majority and the number of parties in the cabinet is highly significant: Chi-Square 5 324.24; Yule's Q 5 0.841; Tau-b 5 0.541
-
In our data, the relationship between the status of a cabinet (minority or majority) and the number of parties in the cabinet is highly significant: Chi-Square 5 324.24; Yule's Q 5 0.841; Tau-b 5 0.541.
-
-
-
-
52
-
-
78650059001
-
-
Average duration of minority governments in our sample was 852 days N = 73; SD = 439.88; the average duration of majority governments was 1, 161 days N = 139; SD = 458.97. The difference is statistically significant t = - 4.625, p < 0.0001
-
Average duration of minority governments in our sample was 852 days (N = 73; SD = 439.88); the average duration of majority governments was 1, 161 days (N = 139; SD = 458.97). The difference is statistically significant (t = - 4.625, p < 0.0001).
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
78650063984
-
-
drawback of this set of measures is that it is based on interpolated left-right positions of parties, not on their positions as reflected in their actual party manifestos. This interpolation is based on the assumption of linear position change over time of political parties between two points of actual left-right measurement
-
The drawback of this set of measures is that it is based on interpolated left-right positions of parties, not on their positions as reflected in their actual party manifestos. This interpolation is based on the assumption of linear position change over time of political parties (between two points of actual left-right measurement).
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
78650041860
-
-
This is a relatively simple test, but it is theoretically trivial, as all other indices attempt to capture different aspects of the same thing
-
This is a relatively simple test, but it is theoretically trivial, as all other indices attempt to capture different aspects of the same thing.
-
-
-
-
58
-
-
78650051988
-
-
following tables report only a fraction of the analyses we performed with various combinations of control variables. We dropped the parliamentary fragmentation index due to its high correlation with the effective number of parties. We also dropped the electoral system dummies due to their high correlation with measures of disproportionality. Generally speaking, neither of these dropped controls exhibited any significant effect on the dependent variables when included in the analyses, and nor did their introduction change significantly the results reported herein
-
The following tables report only a fraction of the analyses we performed with various combinations of control variables. We dropped the parliamentary fragmentation index due to its high correlation with the effective number of parties. We also dropped the electoral system dummies due to their high correlation with measures of disproportionality. Generally speaking, neither of these dropped controls exhibited any significant effect on the dependent variables when included in the analyses, and nor did their introduction change significantly the results reported herein.
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
78650049432
-
-
Here too, we ran the full equations with all polarization indices including NPI, and - with the exception of the significant impact of NPI on the average duration of cabinets and the significant negative impact of NPI on the number of cabinets in an electoral cycle - none of the results reported here has changed dramatically
-
Here too, we ran the full equations with all polarization indices (including NPI), and - with the exception of the significant impact of NPI on the average duration of cabinets (and the significant negative impact of NPI on the number of cabinets in an electoral cycle) - none of the results reported here has changed dramatically.
-
-
-
-
60
-
-
0040511125
-
Modeling cabinet durability and termination
-
See Grofman and van Roozeendaal, and
-
See Grofman and van Roozeendaal (Bernard Grofman and Peter van Roozendaal, 'Modeling Cabinet Durability and Termination', British Journal of Political Science, 27 (1997), 419-51
-
(1997)
British Journal of Political Science
, vol.27
, pp. 419-451
-
-
Grofman, B.1
Van Roozendaal, P.2
-
62
-
-
0000732542
-
Party coalitions in multiparty parliaments: A game-theoretic analysis
-
See Dodd, for more details
-
See Dodd (Lawrence C. Dodd, 'Party Coalitions in Multiparty Parliaments: A Game-Theoretic Analysis', American Political Science Review, 68 (1974), 1093-117) for more details.
-
(1974)
American Political Science Review
, vol.68
, pp. 1093-1117
-
-
Dodd, L.C.1
-
64
-
-
34248260512
-
Proportionality, disproportionality, and electoral systems
-
Michael Gallagher, 'Proportionality, Disproportionality, and Electoral Systems', Electoral Studies, 10 (1991), 33-51;
-
(1991)
Electoral Studies
, vol.10
, pp. 33-51
-
-
Gallagher, M.1
-
65
-
-
0004100179
-
-
New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press
-
Arend Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1999).
-
(1999)
Patterns of Democracy
-
-
Lijphart, A.1
-
70
-
-
84949792766
-
Effective number of parties: A measure with applications to western europe
-
Markku Laasko and Rein Taagepera, 'Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Applications to Western Europe', Comparative Political Studies, 12 (1979), 3-27.
-
(1979)
Comparative Political Studies
, vol.12
, pp. 3-27
-
-
Laasko, M.1
Taagepera, R.2
-
71
-
-
78650063799
-
-
It is important to note that the NPI incorporates the ideological cohesion of parties in protocoalitions. However, for any given cabinet, proto-coalitions might be different from actual coalitions, and therefore these reflect two different things
-
It is important to note that the NPI incorporates the ideological cohesion of parties in protocoalitions. However, for any given cabinet, proto-coalitions might be different from actual coalitions, and therefore these reflect two different things.
-
-
-
|