메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 98, Issue 3, 2010, Pages 749-812

Preventing state budget crises: Managing the fiscal volatility problem

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 78649596615     PISSN: 00081221     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (36)

References (314)
  • 2
    • 78649567922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1
    • Id. at 1.
  • 3
    • 78649607323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Nelson A. Rockefeller inst, of gov't, st. revenue rep. no. 76
    • See DONALD J. BOYD & LUCY DADAYAN, THE NELSON A. ROCKEFELLER INST, OF GOV'T, ST. REVENUE REP. NO. 76, STATE TAX DECLINE IN EARLY 2009 WAS THE SHARPEST ON RECORD 1 (2009), http://www.rockinst.org/pdf/government-finance/ state-revenue-report/200907-17-SRR-76.pdf.
    • (2009) State Tax Decline in Early 2009 Was the Sharpest on Record , pp. 1
    • Boyd, D.J.1    Dadayan, L.2
  • 4
    • 78649618701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This Article uses the term "balanced-budget constraints" to refer to informal forces that lead states to balance their budgets in addition to the formal legal rules that require states to do so. For further discussion on the nature of state balanced-budget constraints, see infra Part I.B
    • This Article uses the term "balanced-budget constraints" to refer to informal forces that lead states to balance their budgets in addition to the formal legal rules that require states to do so. For further discussion on the nature of state balanced-budget constraints, see infra Part I.B.
  • 5
    • 78649560063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fiscal volatility dilemmas have troubled U.S. cities and states, as well as many foreign nations. There is even reason to think the U.S. federal government might face fiscal volatility problems at some point in the future (see infra Part I.D.). Although this Article will briefly consider how fiscal volatility plays out at other levels of government, and although most of the Article's prescriptions apply to other government levels, the Article's primary concern is how U.S. state governments should respond to the fiscal volatility created by their balanced-budget constraints.
  • 6
    • 78649531089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public choice
    • The distinction between ordinary politics and institutional-design policy is drawn from the writings of public choice scholars like James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock. See generally Gordon Tullock, Public Choice, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS ONLINE, http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article? id=pde2008-P000240. Public choice scholars typically use the term "constitutional politics" in place of "institutional-design policy," but I avoid this phrase as legal audiences sometimes associate "constitutional" rules as necessarily being part of an actual written constitution.
    • The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online
    • Tullock, G.1
  • 7
    • 78649589155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The distinction between ordinary politics and institutional-design policy captures two different modes in which academics might be called on to give policy advice. "Ordinary politics" refers to when policymakers ask academics how they should respond to a given problem at a specific point in time. During an economic downturn, the ordinary politics question usually involves policymakers asking academics for advice on how to raise additional revenues or cut spending while causing the least economic harm. In contrast, "institutional-design policy" refers to when policymakers ask academics how to reform budgetary institutions and procedures so as to improve the decisions made by future policymakers.
  • 8
    • 78649627851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the context of this Article, measures for reducing the harmful consequences of fiscal volatility are considered "second-best" as compared to "first-best" measures for eliminating fiscal volatility. If fiscal volatility could be completely eliminated, there would be no need for secondbest coping measures such as those this Article proposes
    • In the context of this Article, measures for reducing the harmful consequences of fiscal volatility are considered "second-best" as compared to "first-best" measures for eliminating fiscal volatility. If fiscal volatility could be completely eliminated, there would be no need for secondbest coping measures such as those this Article proposes.
  • 9
    • 78649579263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C for a definition and discussion of rainy-day funds
    • See infra Part I.C for a definition and discussion of rainy-day funds.
  • 10
    • 0003587413 scopus 로고
    • University of Chicago Press 1976
    • ADAM SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONS 351 (University of Chicago Press 1976) (1776).
    • (1776) The Wealth of Nations , pp. 351
    • Smith, A.1
  • 13
    • 2442551905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions, tax structure and state-local fiscal distress
    • A notable exception is: Jesse Edgerton, Andrew Haughwout & Rae Rosen, Institutions, Tax Structure and State-local Fiscal Distress, 57 NAT'L TAX J. 147 (2004). However, Edgerton and his co-authors only discuss the macroeconomic stimulatory consequences of fluctuating spending as compared to fluctuating tax rates; they do not discuss the microeconomic riskallocation consequences that are the focus of this Article.
    • (2004) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.57 , pp. 147
    • Edgerton, J.1    Haughwout, A.2    Rosen, R.3
  • 14
    • 78649625835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The term "broad-based taxes" refers to tax instruments that reach the majority of state economic activity. In contrast, "narrow-based taxes" reach a much smaller portion of state economic activity. For instance, cigarette taxes are much narrower in base than retail sales taxes, as cigarette taxes cover only tobacco-related sales while retail sales taxes also cover non-tobaccorelated sales. Income taxes, sales taxes, and property taxes are probably the broadest-based of the commonly used state tax instruments. However, the bases of these tax instruments are broader in some states than in others, depending on the level of built-in exemptions, credits, and other preferences.
  • 15
    • 78649550464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In reference to tax and spending policies, the term "steady states" refers to the average settings of these policies taken across both boom and bust years
    • In reference to tax and spending policies, the term "steady states" refers to the average settings of these policies taken across both boom and bust years.
  • 16
    • 78649579794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Club for growth opposes Utah GOP sen. bob bennett's reelection
    • Jan. 8
    • E.g., Stephanie Condon, Club for Growth Opposes Utah GOP Sen. Bob Bennett's ReElection, CBS NEWS POLITICAL HOTSHEET, Jan. 8, 2010, http://www.cbsnews.com/blogs/2010/01/08/politics/politicalhotsheet/entry6073174. shtml (reporting on examples of "the anti-tax group Club for Growth['s] . . . trend of backing conservative candidates over more traditional Republican politicians").
    • (2010) CBS News Political Hotsheet
    • Condon, S.1
  • 17
    • 78649574071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Will the real tax-and-spender please 'fess up?
    • June 13 reporting on John McCain calling Obama a "tax-and-spend liberal"
    • See, e.g., Larry Rohter, Will the Real Tax-and-Spender Please 'Fess Up?, N.Y. TIMES, June 13, 2008, at A25 (reporting on John McCain calling Obama a "tax-and-spend liberal"), available at http://www.nytimes.com/2008/06/ 13/us/politics/13check.html.
    • (2008) N.Y. Times
    • Rohter, L.1
  • 18
    • 78649609846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I describe the literature on these phenomena in Part III.A.2
    • I describe the literature on these phenomena in Part III.A.2.
  • 19
    • 33645939464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • States, facing budget shortfalls, cut the major and the mundane
    • Apr. 21
    • Timothy Egan, States, Facing Budget Shortfalls, Cut the Major and the Mundane, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 21, 2003, at Al.
    • (2003) N.Y. Times
    • Egan, T.1
  • 21
    • 0001441246 scopus 로고
    • Balanced budget rules and fiscal policy: Evidence from the states
    • 330
    • James M. Poterba, Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Policy: Evidence from the States, 48 NAT'L TAX J. 329, 330 (1995).
    • (1995) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.48 , pp. 329
    • Poterba, J.M.1
  • 22
    • 33748495979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Budgeting for fiscal stability over the business cycle: A countercyclical fiscal policy and the multiyear perspective on budgeting
    • 739 n.8
    • There is actually some controversy as to whether Vermont has a balanced budget requirement. See, e.g., Yilin Hou, Budgeting for Fiscal Stability over the Business Cycle: A Countercyclical Fiscal Policy and the Multiyear Perspective on Budgeting, PUB. ADMINISTRATION REV. 730, 739 n.8 (2007) (claiming that Vermont has a "legal obligation ... to balance the budget" despite some studies "exclud[ing] Vermont from this category"). Regardless, using the broader definition for "balanced-budget constraints" discussed in Part LB, infra, Vermont appears to operate under balanced-budget constraints.
    • (2007) Pub. Administration Rev. , pp. 730
    • Hou, Y.1
  • 24
    • 34548854280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revenue volatility in California
    • 37
    • Jon David Vasché & Brad Williams, Revenue Volatility in California, 36 ST. TAX NOTES 35, 37 (2005).
    • (2005) St. Tax Notes , vol.36 , pp. 35
    • Vasché, J.D.1    Williams, B.2
  • 25
    • 78649577294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 35
    • Id. at 35.
  • 27
    • 2442614984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax policy responses to revenue shortfalls
    • 363-64
    • Elaine Maag & David Merriman, Tax Policy Responses to Revenue Shortfalls, 29 ST. TAX NOTES 363, 363-64 (2003) (emphasis omitted).
    • (2003) St. Tax Notes , vol.29 , pp. 363
    • Maag, E.1    Merriman, D.2
  • 28
    • 78649599950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 7
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 7.
  • 29
    • 78649588612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 30
    • 78649572464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vasché & Williams, supra note 21, at 40
    • Vasché & Williams, supra note 21, at 40;
  • 31
    • 78649542496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 7-8
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 7-8.
  • 32
    • 78649532922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 91-94 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 91-94 and accompanying text.
  • 33
    • 78649544109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra note 63-66 and accompanying text
    • See infra note 63-66 and accompanying text.
  • 34
    • 2442510002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The 2002 downturn in state revenues: A comparative review and analysis
    • 114
    • J. Fred Giertz & Seth H. Giertz, The 2002 Downturn in State Revenues: A Comparative Review and Analysis, 57 NAT'L TAX J. 111, 114 (2004).
    • (2004) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.57 , pp. 111
    • Fred Giertz, J.1    Giertz, S.H.2
  • 35
    • 78649530044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 36
    • 78649549791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Note that state governments only stopped growing as a percentage of state GDPs; in both real and nominal dollar values, state governments continued growing along with the privatesector portions of states' economies
    • Id. Note that state governments only stopped growing as a percentage of state GDPs; in both real and nominal dollar values, state governments continued growing along with the privatesector portions of states' economies.
  • 37
    • 78649548200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding state government budget problems: Insights from the midwest region
    • 240
    • Richard F. Dye & David F. Merriman, Understanding State Government Budget Problems: Insights from the Midwest Region, 34 ST. TAX NOTES 233, 240 (2004) ("[E]ach recession since at least 1970 has been accompanied by significant state and local government fiscal distress.").
    • (2004) St. Tax Notes , vol.34 , pp. 233
    • Dye, R.F.1    Merriman, D.F.2
  • 39
    • 84926086469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Read their lips: Taxation and the right-wing agenda
    • Isaac William Martin, Ajay K. Mehrortra & Monica Prasad eds.
    • Fred Block, Read Their Lips: Taxation and the Right-Wing Agenda, in THE NEW FISCAL SOCIOLOGY 68 (Isaac William Martin, Ajay K. Mehrortra & Monica Prasad eds., 2009). The rise of the antitax movement was undoubtedly at least a partial cause of the stabilization of state tax revenues.
    • (2009) The New Fiscal Sociology , pp. 68
    • Block, F.1
  • 40
    • 17444420776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The "no new taxes " pledge
    • 198
    • William G. Gale & Brennan Kelly, The "No New Taxes " Pledge, 104 TAX NOTES 197, 198 (2004).
    • (2004) Tax Notes , vol.104 , pp. 197
    • Gale, W.G.1    Kelly, B.2
  • 41
    • 78649616374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. The pledge, in its entirety, states; "I,-, pledge to the taxpayers of the -district of the state of-, and to the American people that I will: ONE, oppose any and all efforts to increase the marginal income tax rates for individuals and/or businesses; and TWO, oppose any net reduction or elimination of deductions and credits, unless matched dollar for dollar by further reducing tax rates."
  • 42
    • 78649537198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 43
    • 78649560545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBERT ZAHRADNIK, IRIS J. LAV & ELIZABETH MCNICHOL, CTR. ON BUDGET & POL'Y PRIORITIES, FRAMING THE CHOICES 1 (2005), http://www.cbpp.org/files/ 5-9-05sfb1.pdf [hereinafter FRAMING THE CHOICES]. Note that these figures define tax hikes as increases in the statutory tax rates and spending cuts as reductions from projected spending. Nominal spending totals (as opposed to real totals or spending as a percent of GDP) were not cut.
    • (2005) Ctr. on Budget & Pol'y Priorities, Framing the Choices , pp. 1
    • Zahradnik, R.1    Lav, I.J.2    Mcnichol, E.3
  • 44
    • 34247650821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The state of state budget research
    • Dec. 2005 Silver Anniversary Ed. 49
    • Id. ("[S]tates were three times more likely to rely on spending cuts to close deficits than on revenue increases."); see also Irene Rubin, The State of State Budget Research, PUB. BUDGETING & FIN., Dec. 2005 Silver Anniversary Ed., at 46, 49 (2005) ("One conclusion from this research is that states that used to use both revenue increases and spending decreases to close gaps have in recent years ruled out tax increases, leading nearly exclusively to spending reductions."). At the time of this writing, it is still too soon to know how states will respond to the current downturn that began in 2008. But early reports suggest that spending cuts continue to dominate tax hikes as the preferred coping strategy.
    • (2005) Pub. Budgeting & Fin. , pp. 46
    • Rubin, I.1
  • 46
    • 78649582033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maag & Merriman, supra note 24, at 371-72
    • Maag & Merriman, supra note 24, at 371-72.
  • 47
    • 78649591140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 372
    • Id. at 372;
  • 48
    • 78649535668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Faulty foundations: State structural budget problems and how to fix them
    • 75-77
    • Iris J. Lav, Elizabeth C. McNichol & Robert Zahradnik, Faulty Foundations: State Structural Budget Problems and How to Fix Them, 37 ST. TAX NOTES 43, 75-77 (2001).
    • (2001) St. Tax Notes , vol.37 , pp. 43
    • Lav, I.J.1    McNichol, E.C.2    Zahradnik, R.3
  • 49
    • 78649621685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Budget balancing tactics
    • See generally Nicholas W. Jenny & James Orsi, Budget Balancing Tactics, 3 THE ROCKEFELLER INST. ST. FISCAL NEWS NO. 7 (2003) (describing the politically feasible mechanisms for states to raise revenue in a downturn).
    • (2003) The Rockefeller Inst. St. Fiscal News No. 7 , vol.3
    • Jenny, N.W.1    Orsi, J.2
  • 50
    • 78649562643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corzine shuts down New Jersey's government
    • July 1
    • Consider the 2006 budget crisis in New Jersey, at a time when Democrats controlled the governor's mansion and both legislative chambers. The governor's proposed solution to the state's budget crises was to be funded: 50% by spending cuts, 25% by license and user fees, and only 25% by raising the state's sales tax rate from 6% to 7%. Yet where the first two components of the budget proposal were relatively non-controversial, the legislature refused to enact the salestax hike, which led to the government being shut down in an act of brinkmanship. See Richard G. Jones, Corzine Shuts Down New Jersey's Government, N.Y. TIMES, July 1, 2006, available at http://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage. html?res=9B04E2D81530F932A35754C0A9609C8B63.
    • (2006) N.Y. Times
    • Jones, R.G.1
  • 51
    • 78649606775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 6
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 6.
  • 52
    • 25144459593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NAT'L ASS'N OF ST. BUDGET OFFICERS
    • NAT'L ASS'N OF ST. BUDGET OFFICERS, 2003 STATE EXPENDITURE REPORT 5 (2004) [hereinafter 2003 STATE EXPENDITURE REPORT].
    • (2004) 2003 State Expenditure Report , pp. 5
  • 53
    • 2942753303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • States cutting school funding; Officials predict toll on students and Bush's goals
    • Mar. 15
    • For examples of the impact of these cuts, see generally Dale Russakoff & Linda Perlstein, States Cutting School Funding; Officials Predict Toll on Students and Bush's Goals, WASH. POST, Mar. 15, 2003, at A1.
    • (2003) Wash. Post
    • Russakoff, D.1    Perlstein, L.2
  • 54
    • 78649531619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 44
    • See 2003 STATE EXPENDITURE REPORT, supra note 44, at 5. Note that Medicaid spending is sometimes only cut relative to previously authorized expenditures. The general trend of rapid growth in Medicaid spending over time may overpower cuts in previously authorized expenditures during downturns. See infra notes 53-54 and accompanying text.
    • 2003 State Expenditure Report , pp. 5
  • 56
  • 57
    • 22544472139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking fiscal federalism
    • 2562-613
    • Federal government policies have also contributed to increased fiscal volatility at the state level. David A. Super, Rethinking Fiscal Federalism, 118 HARV. L. REV. 2544, 2562-613 (2005).
    • (2005) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.118 , pp. 2544
    • Super, D.A.1
  • 58
    • 78649612362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax revenue volatility and a statewide education sales tax
    • 305-07
    • John Matthews, Tax Revenue Volatility and a Statewide Education Sales Tax, 38 ST. TAX NOTES 305, 305-07 (2005);
    • (2005) St. Tax Notes , vol.38 , pp. 305
    • Matthews, J.1
  • 59
    • 51349129818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fiscal realities for the state and local governments: What you don't know will hurt you; What you can learn will help you
    • 60-62
    • see also Roger E. Brinner, Joyce Brinner, Matt Eckhouse & Megan Leahey, Fiscal Realities for the State and Local Governments: What You Don't Know Will Hurt You; What You Can Learn Will Help You, 43 Bus. ECON. 55, 60-62 (2008).
    • (2008) Bus. Econ. , vol.43 , pp. 55
    • Brinner, R.E.1    Brinner, J.2    Eckhouse, M.3    Leahey, M.4
  • 60
    • 78649566315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Giertz & Giertz, supra note 30, at 114
    • Giertz & Giertz, supra note 30, at 114.
  • 61
    • 78649582562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vasché & Williams, supra note 21, at 42 ("[O]ther factors that have contributed to volatility in the past-namely, increased reliance on the personal income tax and increasing concentrations of income at the high end of the income distribution-are more permanent and thus likely to continue to contribute to volatility in the future.")
    • Vasché & Williams, supra note 21, at 42 ("[O]ther factors that have contributed to volatility in the past-namely, increased reliance on the personal income tax and increasing concentrations of income at the high end of the income distribution-are more permanent and thus likely to continue to contribute to volatility in the future.").
  • 62
    • 78649559409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Giertz & Giertz, supra note 30, at 115. One reason for the dramatic revenue shortfalls following the 2001 downturn was the collapse of realized capital gains, a pattern which might not be repeated in future economic cycles. But the other causes of increased fiscal volatility are likely to continue
    • Giertz & Giertz, supra note 30, at 115. One reason for the dramatic revenue shortfalls following the 2001 downturn was the collapse of realized capital gains, a pattern which might not be repeated in future economic cycles. But the other causes of increased fiscal volatility are likely to continue.
  • 63
    • 78649559410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2630-32
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2630-32.
  • 64
    • 78649540611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 108th cong
    • STAFF OF H. COMM. ON WAYS & MEANS Comm. Print
    • STAFF OF H. COMM. ON WAYS & MEANS, 108TH CONG., 2004 GREEN BOOK: BACKGROUND MATERIAL AND DATA ON THE PROGRAMS WITHIN THE JURISDICTION OF THE COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS app. C at 5-6 (Comm. Print 2004). Note that these figures refer to total state spending, as opposed to just general account spending (the portion of spending relevant to balanced-budget constraints). Medicaid spending is slightly smaller as a percentage of general account spending than of total spending, as some Medicaid spending is financed by dedicated revenue sources.
    • (2004) 2004 Green Book: Background Material and Data on the Programs Within the Jurisdiction of the Committee on Ways and Means App. C , pp. 5-6
  • 66
    • 31344479807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is there a role for an active fiscal stabilization policy?
    • Torben M. Andersen, Is There a Role for an Active Fiscal Stabilization Policy?, 51 CESIFO ECON. STUD. 511 (2005); see also infra notes 140-145 and accompanying text.
    • (2005) Cesifo Econ. Stud. , vol.51 , pp. 511
    • Andersen, T.M.1
  • 67
    • 78649570195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social security, generational justice, and long-term deficits
    • 294
    • See Neil H. Buchanan, Social Security, Generational Justice, and Long-Term Deficits, 58 TAX L. REV. 275, 294 (2005) ("The practical consequences of failing to adjust for the business cycle are especially severe for state and local governments, most of which operate under (modified) balanced budget requirements.").
    • (2005) Tax L. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 275
    • Buchanan, N.H.1
  • 68
    • 0000614615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Balanced budgets and business cycles: Evidence from the states
    • Arik Levinson, Balanced Budgets and Business Cycles: Evidence from the States, 51 NAT. TAX. J. 715 (1998).
    • (1998) Nat. Tax. J. , vol.51 , pp. 715
    • Levinson, A.1
  • 69
    • 0039174356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political economy of the budget surplus in the United States
    • 3-4
    • See Alberto Alesina, The Political Economy of the Budget Surplus in the United States, 14 J. ECON. PERSP. 3, 3-4 (2000) [hereinafter Alesina, Budget Surplus] (noting the "predictions of a traditional Keynesian model of fiscal policy").
    • (2000) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.14 , pp. 3
    • Alesina, A.1
  • 72
    • 78649625834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C for a discussion of why administratively mandated limits on debt financing are unlikely to solve the fiscal volatility problem
    • See infra Part I.C for a discussion of why administratively mandated limits on debt financing are unlikely to solve the fiscal volatility problem.
  • 73
    • 78649598449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The incentives for this sort of behavior may be even stronger due to term limits on state officials
    • The incentives for this sort of behavior may be even stronger due to term limits on state officials.
  • 76
    • 0347264096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Controlling legislative shortsightedness: The effectiveness of constitutional debt limitations
    • Stewart Sterk & Elizabeth Goldman, Controlling Legislative Shortsightedness: The Effectiveness Of Constitutional Debt Limitations, 1991 Wis. L. REV. 1301;
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1991 , pp. 1301
    • Sterk, S.1    Goldman, E.2
  • 77
    • 84927101729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dysfunctional or optimal institutions?: State debt limitations, the structure of state and local governments, and the finance of American infrastructure
    • 342-49 Elizabeth Garrett, Elizabeth Graddy & Howell E. Jackson eds.
    • John Joseph Wallis & Barry R. Weingast, Dysfunctional or Optimal Institutions?: State Debt Limitations, the Structure of State and Local Governments, and the Finance of American Infrastructure, in FISCAL CHALLENGES: AN INTERDISCIPLINARY APPROACH TO BUDGET POLICY 331, 342-49 (Elizabeth Garrett, Elizabeth Graddy & Howell E. Jackson eds., 2008) [hereinafter FISCAL CHALLENGES].
    • (2008) Fiscal Challenges: An Interdisciplinary Approach to Budget Policy , pp. 331
    • Wallis, J.J.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 78
    • 78649573006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heins, supra note 63, at 7
    • Heins, supra note 63, at 7;
  • 79
    • 78649619248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ratchford, supra note 63, at 79
    • Ratchford, supra note 63, at 79;
  • 80
    • 78649616864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sterk & Goldman, supra note 63
    • Sterk & Goldman, supra note 63;
  • 81
    • 78649584967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wallis & Weingast, supra note 63, at 342-49
    • Wallis & Weingast, supra note 63, at 342-49.
  • 82
    • 78649542495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heins, supra note 63, at 7
    • Heins, supra note 63, at 7;
  • 83
    • 78649614918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ratchford, supra note 63, at 79
    • Ratchford, supra note 63, at 79;
  • 84
    • 78649605579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sterk & Goldman, supra note 63
    • Sterk & Goldman, supra note 63;
  • 85
    • 78649551472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wallis & Weingast, supra note 63, at 342-49
    • Wallis & Weingast, supra note 63, at 342-49.
  • 86
    • 78649591139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heins, supra note 63, at 7
    • Heins, supra note 63, at 7;
  • 87
    • 78649545455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ratchford, supra note 63, at 79
    • Ratchford, supra note 63, at 79;
  • 88
    • 78649531620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sterk & Goldman, supra note 63
    • Sterk & Goldman, supra note 63;
  • 89
    • 78649538251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wallis & Weingast, supra note 63, at 342-49
    • Wallis & Weingast, supra note 63, at 342-49.
  • 90
    • 0000652243 scopus 로고
    • Why are stabilizations delayed?
    • See Alberto Alesina & Allan Drazen, Why are Stabilizations Delayed? 81 AM. ECON. REV. 1170 (1991).
    • (1991) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 1170
    • Alesina, A.1    Drazen, A.2
  • 91
  • 92
    • 84927053633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Starving the beast: The political psychology of budget deficits
    • supra note 63
    • Jonathan Baron & Edward J. McCaffery, Starving the Beast: The Political Psychology of Budget Deficits, in FISCAL CHALLENGES, supra note 63, at 221. The advantages of campaigning for tax cuts without specifying which spending programs will be cut can be explained both by the political psychology literature, as in the Baron and McCaffery article cited above, and by more traditional public-choice models. When spending reductions are specified, the beneficiaries of the spending have strong incentives to campaign against tax cuts. When spending cuts are left unspecified, the beneficiaries of each spending program have only a probabilistic chance of seeing their benefits cut, and thus have reduced incentives to campaign against the tax cuts as compared to the known beneficiaries of the tax cuts.
    • Fiscal Challenges , pp. 221
    • Baron, J.1    McCaffery, E.J.2
  • 93
    • 78649592720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This may be currently happening at the federal level. See infra Part I.D.
    • This may be currently happening at the federal level. See infra Part I.D.
  • 94
    • 78649529501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even if members of either the liberal or conservative coalitions would prefer to limit spending hikes or tax cuts (respectively) in order to restore slack to the budget, they may refrain from doing so out of fear that the opposing coalition will simply take advantage of the slack to advance that coalition's preferred use of revenues
    • Even if members of either the liberal or conservative coalitions would prefer to limit spending hikes or tax cuts (respectively) in order to restore slack to the budget, they may refrain from doing so out of fear that the opposing coalition will simply take advantage of the slack to advance that coalition's preferred use of revenues.
  • 95
    • 2942704124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Changing red to black: Deficit closing alchemy
    • See, e.g., John E. Petersen, Changing Red to Black: Deficit Closing Alchemy, 56 NAT'L TAX. J. 567 (2003);
    • (2003) Nat'l Tax. J. , vol.56 , pp. 567
    • Petersen, J.E.1
  • 96
    • 78649561597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State Government Experience with Balanced Budget Requirements: Relevance to Federal Proposals: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on the Budget, 102d Cong. (1992) (statement of Steven D. Gold, Director of the Center for Study of the States, Nelson A. Rockefeller Institute of Government, State University of New York)
    • State Government Experience with Balanced Budget Requirements: Relevance to Federal Proposals: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on the Budget, 102d Cong. (1992) (statement of Steven D. Gold, Director of the Center for Study of the States, Nelson A. Rockefeller Institute of Government, State University of New York).
  • 97
    • 78649587577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Petersen, supra note 72
    • Petersen, supra note 72.
  • 98
    • 78649561092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levinson, supra note 57, at 717 ("[M]ost state midyear budget gaps appear to be met by spending decreases or revenue increases, rather than interfund or intertemporal transfers that would be symptomatic of gimmickry.")
    • See Levinson, supra note 57, at 717 ("[M]ost state midyear budget gaps appear to be met by spending decreases or revenue increases, rather than interfund or intertemporal transfers that would be symptomatic of gimmickry.").
  • 99
    • 78649567393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poterba, supra note 19, at 332
    • Poterba, supra note 19, at 332.
  • 100
    • 78649602535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • FRAMING THE CHOICES, supra note 37, at 1. The remaining 76% was split between spending cuts (42%), tax and fee increases (14%), use of rainy-day funds (10%), and federal fiscal relief (10%). The use of budget gimmicks was much higher than the historical average partly because states generated significant revenues from one-time securitizations of their future income from the tobacco litigation settlements. See Maag & Merriman, supra note 24, at 372.
  • 101
    • 78649593191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRAMING THE CHOICES, supra note 37, at 5-6 (providing examples of painful coping measures)
    • See, e.g., FRAMING THE CHOICES, supra note 37, at 5-6 (providing examples of painful coping measures).
  • 102
    • 78649624781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Briffault, supra note 20, at 5
    • Briffault, supra note 20, at 5.
  • 103
    • 78649620274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 60
    • Id. at 60
  • 105
    • 37249040342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A framework for understanding state balanced budget requirement systems: Reexamining distinctive features and an operational definition
    • 27 Sept.
    • see also Yilin Hou & Daniel L. Smith, A Framework for Understanding State Balanced Budget Requirement Systems: Reexamining Distinctive Features and an Operational Definition, 26 PUB. BUDGETING & FIN. 22, 27 (Sept. 2006) ("[W]e can conclude that both qualitative and empirical studies of state BBRs are grounded in data that at least partially reflect personal perception, judicial interpretation, and other nonstatutory and nonconstitutional considerations."). See also infra notes 105-113 and accompanying text for a discussion of how antideficit norms governed the behavior of the U.S. federal government for most of the nation's history.
    • (2006) Pub. Budgeting & Fin. , vol.26 , pp. 22
    • Hou, Y.1    Smith, D.L.2
  • 107
    • 0347334605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and economics discovers social norms
    • See also Robert C. Ellickson, Law and Economics Discovers Social Norms, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 537 (1998). For the reasons discussed in Part I.B.I, these norms are functional and are likely enforced through extralegal means-such as through voter retaliation against politicians seen as violating the norms.
    • (1998) J. Legal Stud. , vol.27 , pp. 537
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 108
    • 78649604519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Briffault, supra note 20, at 3
    • Briffault, supra note 20, at 3.
  • 109
    • 78649607836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In other words, this Article uses the term "balanced-budget constraints" to refer to informal forces that lead states to balance their budgets in addition to the formal legal rules that require states to do so
    • In other words, this Article uses the term "balanced-budget constraints" to refer to informal forces that lead states to balance their budgets in addition to the formal legal rules that require states to do so.
  • 110
    • 78649549790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Managing California's fiscal roller coaster
    • 661
    • In addition to the first-best solutions discussed in the text of this Article, states could adjust their tax bases by replacing volatile income taxes with less volatile alternatives like property taxes. However, adjusting tax bases in this fashion would have numerous policy implications that many state legislators (and voters) would consider undesirable. As such, I do not view adjusting state tax bases as a viable first-best solution. For further discussion of the limitations to this alternative approach in the context of California, see David Gamage, Managing California's Fiscal Roller Coaster, 49 ST. TAX NOTES 659, 661 (2008).
    • (2008) St. Tax Notes , vol.49 , pp. 659
    • Gamage, D.1
  • 111
    • 78649547680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NAT'L CONF. OF ST. LEGISLATURES State Budget Stabilization Funds
    • NAT'L CONF. OF ST. LEGISLATURES, RAINY DAY FUNDS: app. A., State Budget Stabilization Funds (2004), http://www.ncsl.org/programs/fiscal/rdfaxa.htm;
    • (2004) Rainy Day Funds: App. A.
  • 112
    • 0013302572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rainy day funds and state government savings
    • Brian Knight & Arik Levinson, Rainy Day Funds and State Government Savings, 52 NAT'L TAX J. 459 (1999).
    • (1999) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.52 , pp. 459
    • Knight, B.1    Levinson, A.2
  • 113
    • 78649571169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 10-11
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 10-11.
  • 114
    • 43949134036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CTR. ON BUDGET & POL'Y PRIORITIES
    • ROBERT ZAHRADNIK, CTR. ON BUDGET & POL'Y PRIORITIES, RAINY DAY FUNDS: OPPORTUNITIES FOR REFORM 1 (2005), http://www.cbpp.org/files/4-16-07sfb.pdf [hereinafter RAINY DAY FUNDS] (indicating that states had $30 billion in reserves to cover a need of approximately $250 billion).
    • (2005) Rainy Day Funds: Opportunities for Reform , pp. 1
    • Zahradnik, R.1
  • 115
    • 78649584966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2643
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2643.
  • 116
    • 78649603990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Seesupra Part I.B.1
    • Seesupra Part I.B.1.
  • 117
    • 78649602028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RAINY DAY FUNDS, supra note 86
    • See, e.g., RAINY DAY FUNDS, supra note 86;
  • 118
    • 78649562642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gamage, supra note 82, at 664
    • Gamage, supra note 82, at 664;
  • 119
    • 65249130572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State saving behavior: Effects of two fiscal and budgetary institutions
    • Yilin Hou & William Duncombe, State Saving Behavior: Effects of Two Fiscal and Budgetary Institutions, 28 PUB. BUDGETING & FIN. 48 (Fall 2008);
    • (2008) Pub. Budgeting & Fin. , vol.28 , Issue.FALL , pp. 48
    • Hou, Y.1    Duncombe, W.2
  • 120
    • 78649568423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Super, supra note 48. An extended discussion of these measures and their limitations is beyond the scope of this paper. For an introduction to the topic, see Dye & Merriman, supra note 33, at 245-46
    • Super, supra note 48. An extended discussion of these measures and their limitations is beyond the scope of this paper. For an introduction to the topic, see Dye & Merriman, supra note 33, at 245-46.
  • 121
    • 78649611903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., NASB, supra note 23, at 11
    • See, e.g., NASB, supra note 23, at 11;
  • 122
    • 78649611372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Giertz & Giertz, supra note 30, at 130
    • Giertz & Giertz, supra note 30, at 130.
  • 123
    • 78649555970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 11
    • NASB, supra note 23, at 11.
  • 124
    • 78649623198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 125
    • 78649549259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dye & Merriman, supra note 33, at 246
    • Dye & Merriman, supra note 33, at 246.
  • 126
    • 78649533980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 245. Dye & Merriman highlight some of the difficulties inherent in relying on saving during boom years to resolve fiscal volatility problems: U.S. business cycles have not been symmetric-expansions have lasted about five times as long as recessions. Observed revenue cycles are also asymmetric, with revenue above trend for about four out of every six years.... A government that wants to keep spending equal to the average or trend level of revenue will be obligated to accumulate surpluses long after actual revenues have begun to fall. Because the expansion lasts so much longer than the contraction, the accumulated surplus must reach a very high peak (more than $1,000 per capita or 50 percent of average annual revenues in our example). And, also because of the asymmetry, the surplus would disappear in extremely short order once revenues dip below trend. We doubt that many political actors could resist the pressure to increase spending or cut taxes with surpluses of this magnitude and could defend reserving so much revenue as insurance against future declines. Even if sufficiently large rainy-day fund contributions could be mandated in light of forecasting problems, politicians could easily raid these funds, either directly or indirectly through the use of budgetary gimmicks. The impulses that lead the ordinary political process to channel all available revenues into tax cuts and spending hikes can only be overcome through powerful countervailing pressures - such as from capital markets or from antideficit norms. Historically, these pressures have not operated to force saving during upturns.
  • 127
    • 78649584425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2649
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2649.
  • 128
    • 78649617910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2575
    • See id. at 2575.
  • 129
    • 78649603464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Edgerton et al., supra note 12, at 147 (noting that "significant distress" pervades the local government sector)
    • See, e.g., Edgerton et al., supra note 12, at 147 (noting that "significant distress" pervades the local government sector);
  • 130
    • 78649541137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How a city can survive a boom and bust cycle without bankruptcy: The case of Houston
    • 90
    • Steven G. Craig, How a City Can Survive a Boom and Bust Cycle Without Bankruptcy: The Case of Houston, in 1997 PROC. 89TH ANN. CONF. NAT'L TAX ASS'N 90, 90 (noting the near-constant use of the term "urban fiscal crisis" in connection with cities over the past thirty years).
    • 1997 Proc. 89th Ann. Conf. Nat'l Tax Ass'n , pp. 90
    • Craig, S.G.1
  • 131
    • 78649537197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edgerton et al., supra note 12, at 147 (explaining that New York City's budget problems in 2003 were at "the extreme of the distribution" of state and local budget crises)
    • See Edgerton et al., supra note 12, at 147 (explaining that New York City's budget problems in 2003 were at "the extreme of the distribution" of state and local budget crises).
  • 132
    • 78649539093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alesina, Tabellini & Campante, supra note 60
    • See Alesina, Tabellini & Campante, supra note 60;
  • 134
    • 0002858872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fiscal policy in Latin America
    • Ben S. Bernanke & Julio Rotemberg eds.
    • Michael Gavin & Roberto Perotti, Fiscal Policy in Latin America, in NBER MACROECONOMICS ANNUAL 1997 11 (Ben S. Bernanke & Julio Rotemberg eds., 1997);
    • (1997) NBER Macroeconomics Annual , vol.1997 , pp. 11
    • Gavin, M.1    Perotti, R.2
  • 135
    • 24344498908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When it rains, it pours: Procyclical capital flows and macroeconomic policies
    • Mark Gertler & Kenneth Rogoff eds.
    • Graciela L. Kaminski, Carmen M. Reinhart & Carlos A. Végh, When It Rains, It Pours: Procyclical Capital Flows and Macroeconomic Policies, in NBER MACROECONOMICS ANNUAL 2004 11 (Mark Gertler & Kenneth Rogoff eds., 2005);
    • (2005) NBER Macroeconomics Annual , vol.2004 , pp. 11
    • Kaminski, G.L.1    Reinhart, C.M.2    Végh, C.A.3
  • 136
    • 23844452365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax base variability and procyclical fiscal policy in developing countries
    • Ernesto Talvi & Carlos Végh, Tax Base Variability and Procyclical Fiscal Policy in Developing Countries, 78 J. DEV. ECON. 156 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Dev. Econ. , vol.78 , pp. 156
    • Talvi, E.1    Végh, C.2
  • 137
    • 78649562114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alesina, Tabellini & Campante, supra note 60, at 2-4
    • See Alesina, Tabellini & Campante, supra note 60, at 2-4;
  • 140
    • 78649565432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alesina, Tabellini & Campante, supra note 60, at 1007 n.2
    • Alesina, Tabellini & Campante, supra note 60, at 1007 n.2.
  • 141
    • 78649546179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are additional complications influencing how national governments should respond to fiscal volatility that are not considered in this Article, due to its focus on the U.S. state level. The Article's prescriptions should be viewed as a relevant contribution to the literature on comparative- and national-level fiscal volatility, but not as an authoritative guide for coping with fiscal volatility on these levels.
  • 142
    • 0346943065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional politics and balanced budgets
    • Nancy C. Staudt, Constitutional Politics and Balanced Budgets, 1998 U. III. L. REV. 1105, 1152-75 (1998).
    • (1998) 1998 U. Iii. L. Rev. , vol.1105 , pp. 1152-1175
    • Staudt, N.C.1
  • 143
    • 78649607322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alesina, supra note 58, at 5-6
    • Alesina, supra note 58, at 5-6.
  • 144
    • 78649597401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Staudt, supra note 105, at 1171
    • Staudt, supra note 105, at 1171
  • 145
    • 0037695008 scopus 로고
    • Clarifying confusion about the balanced budget amendment
    • 347-48
    • (quoting James M. Buchanan, Clarifying Confusion About the Balanced Budget Amendment, 49 NAT'L TAX J. 347, 347-48 (1995)).
    • (1995) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.49 , pp. 347
    • Buchanan, J.M.1
  • 147
    • 78649593190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rise and fall of the norm of budget balance: Seeking a budgetary logic behind the federal budget deficits (2007)
    • presented at October
    • See, e.g., Yilin Hou, The Rise and Fall of the Norm of Budget Balance: Seeking a Budgetary Logic Behind the Federal Budget Deficits (2007) (presented at Ann. Conf. of Ass'n for Budgeting and Fin. Mgmt., October 2007), available at http://papere.ssiB.com/sol3/papers.cfm? abstract-id= 1027640;
    • (2007) Ann. Conf. of Ass'n for Budgeting and Fin. Mgmt.
    • Hou, Y.1
  • 148
    • 78649613404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alesina, supra note 58, at 5-11; Shaviro, supra note 55, at 28-27
    • Alesina, supra note 58, at 5-11; Shaviro, supra note 55, at 28-27.
  • 149
    • 78649556516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alesina, supra note 58, at 6
    • Alesina, supra note 58, at 6.
  • 151
    • 0042088349 scopus 로고
    • Rewriting the fiscal constitution: The case of Gramm-RudmanHollings
    • Kate Stith, Rewriting the Fiscal Constitution: The Case of Gramm-RudmanHollings, 76 CALIF. L. REV. 593 (1988). The Gramm-Rudman-Hollings Balanced Budget Act can be considered a partial balanced budget constraint in that it attempted to make it more difficult for Congress to increase deficits, even as a means of coping with downturns.
    • (1988) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 593
    • Stith, K.1
  • 152
    • 78649591138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shaviro, supra note 55, at 247
    • See Shaviro, supra note 55, at 247.
  • 153
    • 0042589190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Drafting a federal balanced budget amendment that does what it is supposed to do (and no more)
    • 1451
    • Theodore Seto, Drafting a Federal Balanced Budget Amendment that Does What It Is Supposed to Do (And No More), 106 YALE L.J. 1449, 1451 (1997). Critics cited the amendment's lack of enforcement mechanisms as evidence that it would not have actually prevented deficit spending. Supporters responded that the amendment's symbolic value would have been enough to reestablish the antideficit norm that governed U.S. political culture for most of its history. Compare Staudt, supra note 105, with Buchanan, supra note 107.
    • (1997) Yale L.J. , vol.106 , pp. 1449
    • Seto, T.1
  • 156
    • 78649547200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 158
    • 78649575240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 159
    • 78649571168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 60-66 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 60-66 and accompanying text.
  • 160
    • 78649582561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shaviro, supra note 55, at 308
    • Shaviro, supra note 55, at 308.
  • 161
    • 78649551471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arguably, the currently dominant deficit measurements are inadequate for this purpose and will need to be replaced by alternatives that better account for future liabilities. See id
    • Arguably, the currently dominant deficit measurements are inadequate for this purpose and will need to be replaced by alternatives that better account for future liabilities. See id.
  • 162
    • 78649530043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • By using a balanced-budget constraint as a precommitment device, Congress could potentially overcome the collective action problems that hinder efforts to address directly the sources of fiscal unsustainability. This was the idea motivating the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings Act. See Stith, supra note 111, at 621-69. Balanced budget constraints might also serve to reassure government bond holders or taxpayers (or anyone concerned about inflation), once painful adjustments are made, that the dynamics leading to unsustainability will not be repeated. This was the main reason states adopted balanced-budget constraints after the debt crises of the 1900s. See supra notes 60-66 and accompanying text.
  • 163
    • 78649610361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is essentially what has happened in many developing countries and in developed nations that have accrued unsustainable levels of debt. See supra notes 102-104 and accompanying text
    • This is essentially what has happened in many developing countries and in developed nations that have accrued unsustainable levels of debt. See supra notes 102-104 and accompanying text.
  • 164
    • 78649548745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Those wild budget swings
    • July 16
    • Notably, the magnitude of fiscal volatility has increased dramatically at the federal level in recent years, and this volatility may be interfering with the reestablishment of antideficit norms. See Edmund L. Andrews, Those Wild Budget Swings, N.Y. TIMES, July 16, 2006 at 4. During upturns, politicians can claim credit for deficit reductions that are merely cyclical. This has caused some commentators-and possibly a significant number of voters-to conclude that deficits do not matter or that taxes can be cut without revenue loss.
    • (2006) N.Y. Times , pp. 4
    • Andrews, E.L.1
  • 167
    • 0011651659 scopus 로고
    • Horizontal equity: Measures in search of a principle
    • 145
    • Louis Kaplow, Horizontal Equity: Measures in Search of a Principle, 42 NAT'L TAX J. 139, 145 (1989).
    • (1989) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.42 , pp. 139
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 168
    • 0001460395 scopus 로고
    • Taxation and uncertainty
    • 335
    • David S. Bizer & Kenneth L. Judd, Taxation and Uncertainty, 79 AM. ECON. REV. 331, 335(1989).
    • (1989) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.79 , pp. 331
    • Bizer, D.S.1    Judd, K.L.2
  • 169
    • 78649550463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.A
    • See supra Part I.A.
  • 170
    • 0004066308 scopus 로고
    • These are related concepts. From the perspective of actors affected by tax or spending programs, fiscal volatility can be thought of as a form of either risk or uncertainty. Although the terms "risk" and "uncertainty" have distinct meanings, the differences between them are unimportant for our purposes. I will thus use the terms "volatility," "risk," and "uncertainty" interchangeably. For more on this topic, see, e.g., FRANK H. KNIGHT, RISK, UNCERTAINTY AND PROFIT (1921);
    • (1921) Risk, Uncertainty and Profit
    • Knight, F.H.1
  • 171
    • 78649624287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arrow, supra note 124
    • Arrow, supra note 124;
  • 172
    • 78649567921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • last visited Mar. 23
    • History of Economic Thought Website, Choice Under Risk and Uncertainty, http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/uncert/choicecont.htm (last visited Mar. 23, 2010). When distinctions are made between the terms "risk" and "uncertainty," "risk" refers to when future outcomes are unknown, but when the probability distribution of those outcomes is known. In contrast, "uncertainty" refers to when neither future outcomes nor the probabilities of those outcomes occurring are known. KNIGHT at 233-34.
    • (2010) Choice under Risk and Uncertainty
  • 173
    • 0000670301 scopus 로고
    • Some thoughts on risk distribution and the law of Torts
    • See, e.g., Guido Calabresi, Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts, 70 YALE L.J. 499 (1961).
    • (1961) Yale L.J. , vol.70 , pp. 499
    • Calabresi, G.1
  • 174
    • 0000940164 scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty and the evaluation of public investment decisions
    • There is an existing literature analyzing the effects of uncertainty on public investment decisions. However this literature focuses on idiosyncratic risks affecting only a single government program. The literature does not discuss how systematic risks-like fiscal volatility-should be allocated between taxation and spending. See, e.g., Kenneth J. Arrow & Robert C. Lind, Uncertainty and the Evaluation of Public Investment Decisions, 60 AM. ECON. REV. 364 (1970);
    • (1970) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.60 , pp. 364
    • Arrow, K.J.1    Lind, R.C.2
  • 175
    • 0001508450 scopus 로고
    • Risk taking and taxation: An alternative perspective
    • S.M. Kanbur, Risk Taking and Taxation: An Alternative Perspective, 15 J. PUB. ECON. 163 (1981).
    • (1981) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.15 , pp. 163
    • Kanbur, S.M.1
  • 176
    • 78649613911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 163-168 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 163-168 and accompanying text.
  • 177
    • 78649606774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 175-182 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 175-182 and accompanying text.
  • 178
    • 78649532169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 183-190 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 183-190 and accompanying text.
  • 179
    • 34249858135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two approaches to determine public good provision under distortionary taxation
    • See, e.g., Vidar Christiansen, Two Approaches to Determine Public Good Provision under Distortionary Taxation, 60 NAT'L TAX. J. 25 (2007);
    • (2007) Nat'l Tax. J. , vol.60 , pp. 25
    • Christiansen, V.1
  • 180
    • 33745231206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public goods and the distribution of income
    • Louis Kaplow, Public Goods and The Distribution of Income, 50 EUR. ECON. REV. 1627 (2006);
    • (2006) Eur. Econ. Rev. , vol.50 , pp. 1627
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 181
    • 0039568861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Integrating expenditure and tax decisions: The marginal cost of funds and the marginal benefit of projects
    • Joel Slemrod & Shlomo Yitzhaki, Integrating Expenditure and Tax Decisions: The Marginal Cost of Funds and the Marginal Benefit of Projects, 54 NAT'L TAX. J. 189 (2001).
    • (2001) Nat'l Tax. J. , vol.54 , pp. 189
    • Slemrod, J.1    Yitzhaki, S.2
  • 182
    • 78649594456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Without quantifying the amount of harm that could be mitigated by improving the risk allocation of fiscal volatility, it is hard to know how serious the risk-spreading problem is as compared to the size-of-government problem (if there even is a size-of-government problem). Yet there already exists an enormous literature examining the size-of-government problem, whereas this is the first paper to evaluate the risk-spreading implications of state-level fiscal volatility. In order to analyze effectively the risk-spreading decision, it is useful to cabin the size-ofgovernment decision.
  • 185
    • 78649546704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Super, supra note 48, at 2611-40
    • See Super, supra note 48, at 2611-40.
  • 186
    • 78649553095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also infra notes 185-187 and accompanying text
    • See also infra notes 185-187 and accompanying text.
  • 187
    • 78649607321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A "zeroth-order approximation" is roughly equivalent to an educated first guess
    • A "zeroth-order approximation" is roughly equivalent to an educated first guess.
  • 189
    • 78649593903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shaviro, supra note 55, at 205-11
    • Shaviro, supra note 55, at 205-11.
  • 190
    • 78649593189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Super, supra note 48, at 2607-11
    • See Super, supra note 48, at 2607-11.
  • 191
    • 78649592719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Edgerton et al., supra note 12
    • See, e.g., Edgerton et al., supra note 12;
  • 193
    • 57749174039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State and local finances and the macroeconomy: The high-employment budget and fiscal impetus
    • 544
    • Glenn Follette, Andrea Kusko & Byron Lutz, State and Local Finances and the Macroeconomy: The High-Employment Budget and Fiscal Impetus, 61 NAT'L TAX. J. 531, 544 (2008) (concluding that the macroeconomic effects of state government policy options are "relatively modest").
    • (2008) Nat'l Tax. J. , vol.61 , pp. 531
    • Follette, G.1    Kusko, A.2    Lutz, B.3
  • 194
    • 73849097259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking the role of fiscal policy
    • See, e.g., Martin Feldstein, Rethinking the Role of Fiscal Policy, 99 AM. ECON. REV. 556 (2009);
    • (2009) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 556
    • Feldstein, M.1
  • 195
    • 70350024700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The lack of an empirical Rationale for a revival of discretionary fiscal policy
    • John B. Taylor, The Lack of an Empirical Rationale for a Revival of Discretionary Fiscal Policy, 99 AM. ECON. REV. 550 (2009).
    • (2009) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 550
    • Taylor, J.B.1
  • 196
    • 78649563401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In any case, exploring these issues more fully is beyond the scope of this Article
    • In any case, exploring these issues more fully is beyond the scope of this Article.
  • 197
    • 78649608383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arrow & Lind, supra note 130, at 364
    • Arrow & Lind, supra note 130, at 364.
  • 198
    • 84995186518 scopus 로고
    • Portfolio selection
    • 91
    • Harry Markowitz, Portfolio Selection, 7 J. FIN. 77, 91 ( 1952).
    • (1952) J. Fin. , vol.7 , pp. 77
    • Markowitz, H.1
  • 200
    • 3242729568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax uncertainty and investment: A cross-country empirical investigation
    • See, e.g., Kelly D. Edmiston, Tax Uncertainty and Investment: A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation, 42 ECON. INQUIRY 425 (2004). However, some research has found that volatility in capital income taxation can be welfare enhancing.
    • (2004) Econ. Inquiry , vol.42 , pp. 425
    • Edmiston, K.D.1
  • 201
    • 78649534498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bizer & Judd, supra note 126
    • See, e.g., Bizer & Judd, supra note 126;
  • 202
    • 0001130127 scopus 로고
    • The economic effects of production taxes in a stochastic growth model
    • Michael Dotsey, The Economic Effects of Production Taxes in a Stochastic Growth Model, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 1168 (1990).
    • (1990) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 1168
    • Dotsey, M.1
  • 203
    • 0012941194 scopus 로고
    • Uncertain tax policies, individual behavior, and welfare
    • See also James Aim, Uncertain Tax Policies, Individual Behavior, and Welfare, 78 AM. ECON. REV. 237 (1988) (concluding that uncertainty in the tax base may positively affect welfare, while uncertainty in tax rates generally negatively affects welfare, as tax base uncertainty-but not tax rate uncertainty-deters undesirable tax planning).
    • (1988) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.78 , pp. 237
    • Aim, J.1
  • 204
    • 78649600485 scopus 로고
    • Experimental evidence of the effect of tax rate uncertainity on security prices, investers clienteles, and tax payments
    • 24
    • But see Julie H. Collins & Daniel P. Murphy, Experimental Evidence Of The Effect Of Tax Rate Uncertainity On Security Prices, Investers Clienteles, And Tax Payments, 17, J. AM TAX ASS'N, 1, 24 (1995)
    • (1995) J. Am Tax Ass'n , vol.17 , pp. 1
    • Collins, J.H.1    Murphy, D.P.2
  • 205
    • 78649549258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaplow, supra note 125, at 152 n.21
    • Kaplow, supra note 125, at 152 n.21;
  • 206
    • 0000296878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anomalies: Risk aversion
    • 219
    • Matthew Rabin & Richard H. Thaler, Anomalies: Risk Aversion, 15 J. ECON. PERSP. 219, 219 (2001).
    • (2001) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.15 , pp. 219
    • Rabin, M.1    Thaler, R.H.2
  • 207
    • 16344375445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Bayesian approach to uncertainty aversion
    • Rabin and Thaler, supra note 150, at 219-30, argue that the standard view (that risk aversion arises from the diminishing marginal utility of money) cannot explain the fact that individuals are averse to small risks as well as to large risks. Instead, Rabin and Thaler suggest that risk aversion results from the biases of loss aversion and mental accounting. There are also other nonstandard theories for why individuals are averse to risk and uncertainty. See, e.g., Yoram Halevy & Vincent Feltkamp, A Bayesian Approach to Uncertainty Aversion, 72 REV. ECON. STUD. 449 (2005). Yet, like the standard model, the nonstandard explanations for risk aversion also conclude that individuals exhibit increasing marginal risk aversion. Hence, the nonstandard views are equally consistent with the arguments of this Article as is the standard model. (Although I rely on the standard view of risk aversion in the text of this Article because it is far more widely accepted than the alternatives, I'll note as a tangent that I am partially persuaded by Rabin and Thaler's critique).
    • (2005) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.72 , pp. 449
    • Halevy, Y.1    Feltkamp, V.2
  • 209
    • 78649591669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 210
    • 78649595941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even billionaires may be frustrated by crime (lack of police funding), traffic (lack of transportation spending), and the like. Purchasing a private jet or one's own security force does not provide a perfect substitute
    • Even billionaires may be frustrated by crime (lack of police funding), traffic (lack of transportation spending), and the like. Purchasing a private jet or one's own security force does not provide a perfect substitute.
  • 211
    • 78649538249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This transfer would be efficient and welfare-enhancing following the Kaldor-Hicks methodology
    • This transfer would be efficient and welfare-enhancing following the Kaldor-Hicks methodology.
  • 212
    • 78649626295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As Kenneth Arrow explains, supra note 124, at 137-38, "at any moment society is faced with a set of possible new projects which are on the average profitable though one cannot know for sure which particular projects will succeed and which will fail. If risks cannot be shifted, then very possibly none of the projects will be undertaken." Volatility can deter entrepreneurs and investors from taking on risks that would be expected to improve societal welfare. Moreover, firms as well as individuals can be risk-averse. Arrow and Lind, supra note 130, at 376. Both the managers of firms and stockholders owning large blocks of shares can cause firms to act in a riskaverse fashion. Consequently, by adding risk to the economy, fiscal volatility can deter both firms and individuals from socially-desirable entrepreneurial activities. Although the additional risk caused by fiscal volatility is not directly connected to entrepreneurial activities, it may combine with the risk already inherent in these activities to deter risk-taking behavior that would not have been deterred based on the inherent risk alone.
  • 213
    • 78649586545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Just as planning costs can force administrators to fire staff or abandon projects during downturns, during upturns the administrators may find they have not previously hired enough staff or started construction projects early enough, and that surplus funds can thus not be used efficiently. See Matthews, supra note 49, at 306
    • Just as planning costs can force administrators to fire staff or abandon projects during downturns, during upturns the administrators may find they have not previously hired enough staff or started construction projects early enough, and that surplus funds can thus not be used efficiently. See Matthews, supra note 49, at 306.
  • 214
    • 78649627850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 156
    • See supra note 156.
  • 215
    • 78649578765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For instance, students must apply for teacher training programs at least a year or two in advance of seeking teaching jobs. Since volatile spending makes the availability of teaching jobs fluctuate significantly over time, this volatility probably deters some students from becoming teachers who would otherwise be inclined to enter the profession
    • For instance, students must apply for teacher training programs at least a year or two in advance of seeking teaching jobs. Since volatile spending makes the availability of teaching jobs fluctuate significantly over time, this volatility probably deters some students from becoming teachers who would otherwise be inclined to enter the profession.
  • 216
    • 78649579793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By "unprofitable" I mean unprofitable in the economic sense; a project becomes unprofitable if the resources that must still be invested in order to complete the project could yield greater returns if diverted to an alternative use (the opportunity costs of continuing the project exceed the expected gains)
    • By "unprofitable" I mean unprofitable in the economic sense; a project becomes unprofitable if the resources that must still be invested in order to complete the project could yield greater returns if diverted to an alternative use (the opportunity costs of continuing the project exceed the expected gains).
  • 217
    • 0031521237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Organizational slack and response to environmental shifts: The impact of resource allocation patterns
    • See, e.g., Joseph L.C. Cheng & Idalene F. Kesner, Organizational Slack and Response to Environmental Shifts: The Impact of Resource Allocation Patterns, 23 J. MGMT. 1 (1997)
    • (1997) J. Mgmt. , vol.23 , pp. 1
    • Cheng, J.L.C.1    Kesner, I.F.2
  • 218
    • 78649587576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussing how slack operates in an environmental policy context
    • (discussing how slack operates in an environmental policy context);
  • 219
    • 0000718530 scopus 로고
    • Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making
    • Jitendra V. Singh, Performance, Slack, and Risk Taking in Organizational Decision Making, 29 ACAD. MGMT. J. 562 (1986).
    • (1986) Acad. Mgmt. J. , vol.29 , pp. 562
    • Singh, J.V.1
  • 220
    • 78649605048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While not every citizen receives direct payments from a state, every citizen benefits to at least some extent from spending programs such as transportation infrastructure, education, and the criminal justice system
    • While not every citizen receives direct payments from a state, every citizen benefits to at least some extent from spending programs such as transportation infrastructure, education, and the criminal justice system.
  • 221
    • 78649590617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The regressivity of individual state taxes from 1980 to 2000: A nationwide comparison
    • See Robert J. Landry, III, The Regressivity of Individual State Taxes from 1980 to 2000: A Nationwide Comparison, 41 ST. TAX NOTES 899 (2006), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=927150##.
    • (2006) St. Tax Notes , vol.41 , pp. 899
    • Landry III, R.J.1
  • 222
    • 78649531619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 44
    • 2003 STATE EXPENDITURE REPORT, supra note 44, at 4. Again, this Article only discusses state general-account spending as this is the spending subject to balanced-budget constraints. Spending funded by the states' capital budgets is not usually cut during downturns.
    • 2003 State Expenditure Report , pp. 4
  • 223
    • 78649576233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is no straightforward way to calculate the extent to which different income groups benefit from education spending. But, at least to me, it seems implausible to think that the benefits of education spending are distributed as unequally in dollar values as are incomes
    • There is no straightforward way to calculate the extent to which different income groups benefit from education spending. But, at least to me, it seems implausible to think that the benefits of education spending are distributed as unequally in dollar values as are incomes
  • 225
    • 78649584424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theories of tax justice: Ruminations on the benefit partnership, and ability-to-pay principles
    • 406
    • cf. Joseph M. Dodge, Theories of Tax Justice: Ruminations on the Benefit Partnership, and Ability-to-Pay Principles, 58 TAX L. REV. 399, 406 (2005) (acknowledging and disputing this argument).
    • (2005) Tax L. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 399
    • Dodge, J.M.1
  • 226
    • 78649532919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 137 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 137 and accompanying text.
  • 227
    • 78649626294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an exception that demonstrates the general rule, this result might not apply if the taxes raised to fund the additional spending were head taxes-taxes that take the same dollar amount from each taxpayer. Or, somewhat more plausibly, if only user fees and licenses were raised to pay for additional spending, these revenue sources might be sufficiently regressive so as to make the net effect nonredistributive. But raising tax rates on the margin for the major-broad based state taxes (e.g., sales, income, and property) to fund additional state spending in the major categories will almost certainly be redistributive.
  • 228
    • 78649613910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stated more formally, the utility loss that the first taxpayer would experience is higher than the utility loss that the second taxpayer would experience, as the utility-to-dollar values are higher for the first taxpayer
    • Stated more formally, the utility loss that the first taxpayer would experience is higher than the utility loss that the second taxpayer would experience, as the utility-to-dollar values are higher for the first taxpayer than for the second taxpayer.
  • 229
    • 78649599505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The move here is similar to the logic typically used to justify making interpersonal utility comparisons based on the diminishing marginal utility of money. There may well be some wealthy taxpayer who derives more utility from a marginal dollar than does some poor taxpayer, but when abstracting across an entire population, it seems reasonable to conclude that wealthy taxpayers as a class will derive less utility from a marginal dollar than will poor taxpayers as a class. Similarly, wealthy taxpayers as a class should have more slack.
  • 230
    • 78649551469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, the direct planning cost effects and the indirect risk-spreading effects are perhaps inextricably intertwined, as borrowing, saving, and the use of third-party insurance are both mechanisms for indirect risk spreading and also forms of slack
    • Indeed, the direct planning cost effects and the indirect risk-spreading effects are perhaps inextricably intertwined, as borrowing, saving, and the use of third-party insurance are both mechanisms for indirect risk spreading and also forms of slack.
  • 231
    • 78649600487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Partial insurance
    • Inst, for Fiscal Stud, Working Paper No. W02/16
    • Richard Blundell, Luigi Pistaferri & Ian Preston, Partial Insurance. Information and Consumption Dynamics (Inst, for Fiscal Stud, Working Paper No. W02/16, 2002), available at http://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/2002.
    • (2002) Information and Consumption Dynamics
    • Blundell, R.1    Pistaferri, L.2    Preston, I.3
  • 232
    • 27744507635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Banking the poor
    • Michael S. Barr, Banking the Poor, 21 YALE J. REG. 121 (2004);
    • (2004) Yale J. Reg. , vol.21 , pp. 121
    • Barr, M.S.1
  • 233
    • 34248643173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Just until payday
    • 886-95
    • Ronald J Mann & Jim Hawkins, Just Until Payday, 54 UCLA L. REV. 855, 886-95 (2007).
    • (2007) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.54 , pp. 855
    • Mann, R.J.1    Hawkins, J.2
  • 234
    • 78649584095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The number of individuals insuring through these methods is probably small, but there is no doubt that these techniques are more available to the wealthy than to the poor
    • The number of individuals insuring through these methods is probably small, but there is no doubt that these techniques are more available to the wealthy than to the poor.
  • 235
    • 78649535485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brinner et al., supra note 49, at 60-63
    • Brinner et al., supra note 49, at 60-63.
  • 236
    • 78649601023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 237
    • 78649603989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In contrast, a gross receipts tax or a value added tax (VAT) would be due regardless of profitability
    • In contrast, a gross receipts tax or a value added tax (VAT) would be due regardless of profitability.
  • 238
    • 79956338049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The uneasy case for extending the sales tax to services
    • 440-41
    • See Kirk J. Stark, The Uneasy Case for Extending the Sales Tax to Services, 30 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 435, 440-41 (2003).
    • (2003) Fla. St. U. L. Rev. , vol.30 , pp. 435
    • Stark, K.J.1
  • 239
    • 78649562113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 447-48
    • See id. at 447-48.
  • 240
    • 2442604440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cyclical variability in state government revenue: Can tax reform reduce it?
    • For a more in depth discussion of the factors inherent in state level tax systems that contribute to revenue volatility exceeding of economic volatility, see Russell S. Sobel & Gary A. Wagner, Cyclical Variability in State Government Revenue: Can Tax Reform Reduce It?, 29 ST. TAX NOTES 569 (2003).
    • (2003) St. Tax Notes , vol.29 , pp. 569
    • Sobel, R.S.1    Wagner, G.A.2
  • 241
    • 78649601022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brinner et al, supra note 49, at 60-63
    • Brinner et al, supra note 49, at 60-63.
  • 242
    • 78649553884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vasché & Williams, supra note 21, at 39 (estimating that California's short-term revenue elasticity was 3.51 between fiscal years 1992 and 2004)
    • See Vasché & Williams, supra note 21, at 39 (estimating that California's short-term revenue elasticity was 3.51 between fiscal years 1992 and 2004).
  • 243
    • 77950182861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foreword: The disfavored constitution: State fiscal limits and state constitutional law
    • 915-18
    • Richard Briffault, Foreword: The Disfavored Constitution: State Fiscal Limits and State Constitutional Law, 34 RUTGERS L.J. 907, 915-18 (2003);
    • (2003) Rutgers L.J. , vol.34 , pp. 907
    • Briffault, R.1
  • 244
    • 78649546703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2605-07
    • Super, supra note 48, at 2605-07.
  • 245
    • 78649602956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Briffault, supra note 183, at 915-18
    • See Briffault, supra note 183, at 915-18.
  • 246
    • 0040433193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The local response to tax limitation measures: Do local governments manipulate voters to increase revenues?
    • See, e.g., David N. Figlio & Arthur O'Sullivan, The Local Response to Tax Limitation Measures: Do Local Governments Manipulate Voters to Increase Revenues?, 44 J.L. & ECON. 233 (2001).
    • (2001) J.L. & Econ. , vol.44 , pp. 233
    • Figlio, D.N.1    O'Sullivan, A.2
  • 247
    • 78649611902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 248
    • 78649615867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 249
    • 34247397970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do economists agree on anything? yes!
    • Nov.
    • See Robert Whaples, Do Economists Agree on Anything? Yes!, THE ECONOMISTS VOICE, NOV. 2006, http://www.bepress.com/ev/vol3/iss9/artl (surveying economists' opinions on a variety of issues related to markets and government regulation).
    • (2006) The Economists Voice
    • Whaples, R.1
  • 250
    • 78649597909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The analysis here partially draws on the writings of David Super, supra note 48, at 2630. Note that although the market could theoretically fund some of these programs, moral hazard problems may make governments more efficient providers of these programs
    • The analysis here partially draws on the writings of David Super, supra note 48, at 2630. Note that although the market could theoretically fund some of these programs, moral hazard problems may make governments more efficient providers of these programs.
  • 251
    • 78649547199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Super, supra note 48, at 2611-14
    • See Super, supra note 48, at 2611-14.
  • 252
    • 78649613403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property tax circuit breakers: Fair and cost-effective relief
    • See John H. Bowman, Daphne A. Kenyon, Adam Langley & Bethany P. Paquin, Property Tax Circuit Breakers: Fair and Cost-Effective Relief, 53 ST. TAX NOTES 235 (2009).
    • (2009) St. Tax Notes , vol.53 , pp. 235
    • Bowman, J.H.1    Kenyon, D.A.2    Langley, A.3    Paquin, B.P.4
  • 253
    • 78649592177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some further discussion of this issue can be found in Part III.B
    • Some further discussion of this issue can be found in Part III.B.
  • 254
    • 78649578207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Another possible approach for coping with fiscal volatility is to broaden tax bases during downturns while narrowing them during upturns. This approach is similar to adjusting tax rates in that it results in tax burdens fluctuating across the economic cycle, but it accomplishes this through a different mechanism. However, broadening and narrowing a tax base will generally be suboptimal from a risk-spreading perspective. Changing the elements of a tax base typically affects a much narrower group of taxpayers than does adjusting the rates of the tax instrument, thus causing the effects of volatility to be more concentrated. Additionally, adjusting the elements of a tax base is likely to engender more undesirable game playing on the part of taxpayers than would adjusting tax rates.
  • 255
    • 78649583100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax laws function like entitlement spending in that they remain in effect until explicitly altered. Discretionary general account spending must be rebudgeted annually
    • Tax laws function like entitlement spending in that they remain in effect until explicitly altered. Discretionary general account spending must be rebudgeted annually.
  • 256
    • 78649574603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This can be inferred from how rarely the political debate focuses on fiscal volatility issues as compared to questions related to the steady-state levels for taxes and spending
    • This can be inferred from how rarely the political debate focuses on fiscal volatility issues as compared to questions related to the steady-state levels for taxes and spending.
  • 257
    • 78649532920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The exceptions to this maxim only serve to support the general rule. For instance, Democrats and Republicans dispute whether allowing the Bush tax cuts to expire should be viewed as "raising taxes." The frame here is contestable because the parties can argue about whether the relevant baseline includes extension of the temporary tax cuts. But were the Democrats to propose raising tax rates further-beyond the pre-Bush levels-there would be no doubt that this would be considered a "tax hike." Whether overall revenues are increasing or declining due to economic circumstances is not currently viewed as a relevant consideration in whether a policy change is called a "tax cut" or a "tax hike." See infra notes 203-205 and accompanying text.
  • 258
    • 78649598447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One might argue that general account spending does not have baselines in the same sense as does tax legislation, as general account spending must be reauthorized each year. But this argument is not fully persuasive as most general account spending is reauthorized without full review and changes from the previous year's levels of spending are usually viewed as "spending cuts" or "spending hikes." Zero-base budgeting is seldom implemented in practice.
  • 259
    • 78649612892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The difference between state general account spending and federal discretionary spending is that the federal government can incur deficits. Hence, at the federal level, revenue volatility (the default response to economic cycles under a tax-rates baseline) causes the deficit to automatically grow and shrink unless the legislature proactively adjusts tax or spending policies. In contrast, at the state level, there is no actual default fiscal policy. The tax-rates baseline means that any legislated change to tax rates is coded as a "tax cut" or "tax hike," but any legislated change to spending will similarly be coded as a "spending cut" or a "spending hike." See supra note 194. Revenue volatility forces states to adjust either their tax or spending policies as their economies cycle, but the states must actively decide which specific policies to adjust. This Article focuses on the definition of "tax cuts" and "tax hikes" because these terms are more salient within the current political environment-as reflected by the increasing rarity of "tax hikes." The motivating idea is that, as voters appear to increasingly be making decisions based on whether politicians are seen as voting for "tax cuts" or "tax hikes," we should strive to make the content of these terms reflect what voters actually care about. Or, alternatively, we should strive to eliminate any negative consequences of the increased salience of these terms that does not result from the reasons voters care about the terms. Voters presumably care about these terms based on their preferences for steady-state policy, not based on preferences for how fiscal volatility should be allocated. Therefore, we should define these terms so that the terms convey the information voters seek about legislated changes to steady-state fiscal policy (the size-of-government decision), without negatively affecting how states respond to cyclical economic fluctuations (the fiscal volatility decision).
  • 260
    • 78649545660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • last visited Mar. 24, 2010
    • InvestorDictionary.com, Define meaning of the word Tax cut, http://www.investordictionary.com/definition/tax+cut.aspx (last visited Mar. 24, 2010).
    • Define Meaning of the Word Tax Cut
  • 261
    • 78649590618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For instance, the California State Department of Finance and the State's Legislative Analysts Office analyze the effects of a number of economic variables on the amount of tax revenue collected by the State, including trends in consumer and business spending, housing, employment, profits, and income distributions. See Vasché and Williams, supra note 21, at 40.
  • 262
    • 78649562641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • At this point, it may be helpful to clarify the difference between adopting a new tax baseline and adopting a tax expenditure limit. Numerous states have adopted tax expenditure limits in order to prevent legislatures from raising taxes or to limit the circumstances under which legislatures can raise taxes. An example of a tax expenditure limit is a rule requiring that a supermajority of a legislature vote to approve a tax hike. Whereas tax expenditure limits are designed to bias the evolution of steady-state policies (usually, against raising taxes and spending), the choice of baselines is only meant to influence which aspects of steady-state policies fluctuate in response to fiscal volatility. Adopting a new baseline should not prevent legislatures from adjusting steady-state policies as they desire. Instead, adopting a new baseline only alters the mechanism through which legislatures change steady-state policies.
  • 263
    • 0036264347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A perspective on psychology and economies
    • 662
    • Matthew Rabin, A Perspective on Psychology and Economies, 46 EUR. ECON. REV. 657, 662 (2002).
    • (2002) Eur. Econ. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 657
    • Rabin, M.1
  • 264
    • 78649536699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gale & Kelly, supra note 35, at 198
    • Gale & Kelly, supra note 35, at 198.
  • 265
    • 78649611901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Turning slogans into tax policy
    • 759-61
    • See Karen C. Burke & Grayson M.P. McCouch, Turning Slogans Into Tax Policy, 27 VA. TAX REV. 747, 759-61 (2008).
    • (2008) Va. Tax Rev. , vol.27 , pp. 747
    • Burke, K.C.1    McCouch, G.M.P.2
  • 266
    • 78649595462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • TAX POLICY CENTER
    • See LEONARD E. BURMAN & JEFFREY ROHALY, TAX POLICY CENTER, SENATOR KERRY'S TAX PROPOSALS (2004), http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/UploadedPDF/ 1000634-Kerry Plan.pdf (describing Kerry's tax proposals);
    • (2004) Senator Kerry's Tax Proposals
    • Burman, L.E.1    Rohaly, J.2
  • 267
    • 78649607835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political memo; some candidates quick to urge tax-cut repeal
    • May. 30
    • Adam Nagourney, Political Memo; Some Candidates Quick to Urge Tax-Cut Repeal, N.Y. TIMES, May. 30, 2003, at A24 (describing statements about whether the Bush Tax Cuts should be repealed by both Democrats and Republicans).
    • (2003) N.Y. Times
    • Nagourney, A.1
  • 268
    • 78649623744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 123, at 71
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 123, at 71.
  • 269
    • 85050420478 scopus 로고
    • Tax policy at the beginning of the clinton administration
    • 563
    • Michael J. Graetz, Tax Policy at the Beginning of the Clinton Administration, 10 YALE J. ON REG. 561, 563 (1993).
    • (1993) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.10 , pp. 561
    • Graetz, M.J.1
  • 270
    • 78649566314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 271
    • 0002337668 scopus 로고
    • Cognitive theory and tax
    • 1896-97
    • Before indexing, inflation caused taxpayers' income to be taxed at increasingly higher rates over time as greater portions of their income moved into higher tax brackets. This effect was so pronounced in the late 1970s that the "change from 1976 to 1981 represented an increase of 23% in the real level of the income-tax burden." Edward J. McCaffery, Cognitive Theory and Tax, 41 UCLA L. REV. 1861, 1896-97 (1994). By any holistic measure, the level of taxation increased during this period. Yet these changes were not generally viewed as government-sponsored tax hikes. "Indeed, the two major Carter era tax bills, the 1977 Tax Reduction and Simplification Act and the 1978 Revenue Act, were each billed, projected, and expected to be tax reductions." Id. at 1897 (emphasis in original). With nominal tax rates functioning as the tax baseline, the Carter administration was credited with passing tax cuts even though the real level of taxation was increasing. The absence of indexing allowed the government's revenue intake to rise without Congress or the Carter administration taking significant political heat for passing tax hikes.
    • (1994) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.41 , pp. 1861
    • McCaffery, E.J.1
  • 273
    • 78649611371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Technical and policy standards for inflation adjustments under the internal revenue code
    • The advocates of inflation indexing were only partially successful; many important elements of the federal income tax remain unindexed-most notably, the alternative minimum tax. For further discussion, see Richard J. Kovach, Technical and Policy Standards for Inflation Adjustments Under the Internal Revenue Code, 33 OKLA. CITY U. L. REV. 603 (2008);
    • (2008) Okla. City U. L. Rev. , vol.33 , pp. 603
    • Kovach, R.J.1
  • 274
    • 78649605047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inflation adjustments affecting individual taxpayers in 2003: Analysis and commentary
    • James C. Young, Inflation Adjustments Affecting Individual Taxpayers in 2003: Analysis and Commentary, 96 TAX NOTES 1895 (2002).
    • (2002) Tax Notes , vol.96 , pp. 1895
    • Young, J.C.1
  • 275
    • 78649563917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 123, at 159
    • See SHAVIRO, supra note 123, at 159.
  • 276
    • 78649556850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11
    • Id. at 11.
  • 277
    • 78649624779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For other innovative proposals involving tax and spending baselines, see Leonard Burman, Robert Shiller, Gregory Leiserson & Jeffery Rohaly, The Rising Tide Tax System, Indexing the Tax System for Changes in Inequality (Mar. 22, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author); JASON FURMAN, BROOKINGS INST, COPING WITH DEMOGRAPHIC UNCERTAINTY (2007), http://wagner.nyu.edu/ performance/socialsecurity/demographicuncertainty.pdf. 215. See, e.g., Alesina, supra note 58, at 12 ("The academic literature has pointed out that the fragmentation of a political system is an obstacle to the implementation of the appropriate fiscal decisions, particularly when various shocks require a swift fiscal response. In the most general sense, political fragmentation is a situation in which many political groups have a voice in fiscal decisions, and many have veto power. The point is not that fragmentation necessarily creates budget deficits, but that fragmentation creates obstacles to policy changes, because it becomes more difficult to reach agreements about corrective fiscal measures.").
    • (2007) Brookings Inst, Coping with Demographic Uncertainty
    • Furman, J.1
  • 279
    • 0000206660 scopus 로고
    • State responses to fiscal crises: The effects of budgetary institutions and politics
    • James M. Poterba, State Responses to Fiscal Crises: The Effects of Budgetary Institutions and Politics, 102 J. POL. ECON. 799 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.102 , pp. 799
    • Poterba, J.M.1
  • 281
    • 10044298804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The endowment effect and legal analysis
    • See, e.g,. Russell Korobkin, The Endowment Effect and Legal Analysis, 97 Nw. U. L. REV. 1227 (2003);
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1227
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 283
    • 78649621684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 123, at 26
    • See SHAVIRO, supra note 123, at 26.
  • 284
    • 25144478450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political psychology of redistribution
    • Edward J. McCaffery & Jonathan Baron, The Political Psychology of Redistribution, 52 UCLA L. REV. 1745 (2005).
    • (2005) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 1745
    • McCaffery, E.J.1    Baron, J.2
  • 285
    • 0004059890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ALAN S. BLINDER, CENTRAL BANKING IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 55 (1999) (claiming that Congress's need to pass a law to overturn the Federal Reserve's interest rate decisions makes these "decisions, for all practical purposes, immune from reversal").
    • (1999) Central Banking in Theory and Practice , pp. 55
    • Blinder, A.S.1
  • 286
    • 0000872034 scopus 로고
    • Anomalies: The flypaper effect
    • James R. Hiñes, Jr. & Richard H. Thaler, Anomalies: The Flypaper Effect, 9 J. ECON. PERSP. 217 (1995) (summarizing the literature on the flypaper effect).
    • (1995) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.9 , pp. 217
    • Hiñes Jr., J.R.1    Thaler, R.H.2
  • 287
    • 21144463189 scopus 로고
    • State responses to the TRA86 revenue windfalls: A new test of the flypaper effect
    • Helen F. Ladd, State Responses to the TRA86 Revenue Windfalls: A New Test of the Flypaper Effect, 12 J. POL'Y ANALYSIS & MGMT. 82 (1993).
    • (1993) J. Pol'y Analysis & Mgmt. , vol.12 , pp. 82
    • Ladd, H.F.1
  • 288
    • 78649544956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 82
    • Id. at 82.
  • 289
    • 78649612361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 83
    • Id. at 83.
  • 290
    • 78649537720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 101
    • Id. at 101.
  • 291
    • 0004159206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 5550, April, 0
    • More generally, a sizeable empirical literature has concluded that fiscal institutions "matter." See, e.g., James M. Poterba, Do Budget Rules Work? 0 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 5550, April 1996) ("Several distinct strands of empirical evidence, from the U.S. federal experience with anti-deficit rules, from U.S. state experience with balanced budget rules, and from international comparisons of budget outcomes in nations with different fiscal institutions, suggest that fiscal institutions do matter.").
    • (1996) Do Budget Rules Work?
    • Poterba, J.M.1
  • 292
    • 0031536529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax limitations to reduce municipal property taxes: Truth in taxation in Texas
    • 45-49
    • Robert L. Bland & Phanit Laosirirat, Tax Limitations to Reduce Municipal Property Taxes: Truth in Taxation in Texas, 19 J. URB. AFF. 45, 45-49 (1997).
    • (1997) J. Urb. Aff. , vol.19 , pp. 45
    • Bland, R.L.1    Laosirirat, P.2
  • 293
    • 78649594455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 294
    • 78649597400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 295
    • 78649625833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 296
    • 78649537196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 45-46
    • Id. at 45-46.
  • 297
    • 78649623197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • TEX. CONST, art. VIII, §21(a)
    • TEX. CONST, art. VIII, §21(a).
  • 298
    • 78649590616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OFFICE OF THE TEX. COMPTROLLER OF PUB. ACCOUNTS
    • See also OFFICE OF THE TEX. COMPTROLLER OF PUB. ACCOUNTS, TRUTH-IN-TAXATION: A GUIDE FOR SETTING TAX RATES (2005), http://www.window. state.tx.us/taxinfo/proptax/tnt05/96-312.pdf.
    • (2005) Truth-in-taxation: A Guide for Setting Tax Rates
  • 299
    • 0004194348 scopus 로고
    • U.S. ADVISORY COMM'N ON INTERGOVERNMENTAL REL. 1977
    • See U.S. ADVISORY COMM'N ON INTERGOVERNMENTAL REL. , SIGNIFICANT FEATURES OF FISCAL FEDERALISM 151-67 (1995, 1977).
    • (1995) Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism , pp. 151-167
  • 300
    • 78649530042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 301
    • 33751077681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Full disclosure: Unanticipated improvements in property tax uniformity
    • 110 June
    • Gary C. Cornia & Lawrence C. Walters, Full Disclosure: Unanticipated Improvements in Property Tax Uniformity, 25 PUB. BUDGETING & FIN. 106, 110 (June 2005).
    • (2005) Pub. Budgeting & Fin. , vol.25 , pp. 106
    • Cornia, G.C.1    Walters, L.C.2
  • 302
    • 78649595463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The advocates of the truth-in-taxation property tax measures viewed themselves as promoting a softer version of a tax-expenditure limit with the purpose of reigning in the growth of local governments. See Bland & Laosirirat, supra note 228. This Article argues for revenue-target baselines for statewide sales and income taxes in order to transfer some of the effects of fiscal volatility from the public to the private sector, not to limit the growth of government. Consequently, the political actors supporting revenue-target baselines for local property taxes would not necessarily support these baselines for statewide sales and income taxes.
  • 303
    • 78649539592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At the time of this writing, the truth-in-taxation property tax systems remain intact, and to this author's knowledge there have not yet been any significant political moves to abolish them
    • At the time of this writing, the truth-in-taxation property tax systems remain intact, and to this author's knowledge there have not yet been any significant political moves to abolish them.
  • 304
    • 78649579792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that if a progressive-rate income tax (as opposed to a flat-rate income tax) is to be adjusted, the authorizing statute must specify which rates are to be adjusted as the economy cycles. As with indexing and other design variables, any answer to this question must be somewhat arbitrary. There is no theoretically "correct" method for adjusting the rates of a progressive income tax. One possible approach would be to attempt to adjust the rates so as to make the tax adjustments distributionally neutral. But this is not the only possibility, and a normative argument can be made in favor of adjusting the rates so that high-income taxpayers bear more of the tax burden during downturns and less during upturns. See supra notes 168-73 and accompanying text.
  • 305
    • 78649625321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We currently label this forecasting as the revenue estimating process because we use tax rates as our baseline. With revenue targets as the baseline, the process would be labeled as taxrate estimating. Under either system, calculations made by administrative officials significantly impact fiscal policy outcomes
    • We currently label this forecasting as the revenue estimating process because we use tax rates as our baseline. With revenue targets as the baseline, the process would be labeled as taxrate estimating. Under either system, calculations made by administrative officials significantly impact fiscal policy outcomes.
  • 306
    • 78649599504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 91 -94 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 91 -94 and accompanying text.
  • 307
    • 78649556849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Additionally, the main obstacle to full financing of rainy-day funds remains the ability of the dominant political coalition to raid these funds either explicitly or through the use of gimmicks
    • Additionally, the main obstacle to full financing of rainy-day funds remains the ability of the dominant political coalition to raid these funds either explicitly or through the use of gimmicks.
  • 309
    • 78649561598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 4
    • Id. at 4.
  • 310
    • 78649557388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 37
    • FRAMING THE CHOICES, supra note 37, at 5-6.
    • Framing the Choices , pp. 5-6
  • 311
    • 78649532168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCNICHOL & LAV, supra note 243, at 3
    • See MCNICHOL & LAV, supra note 243, at 3.
  • 312
    • 78649600486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 48-54 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 48-54 and accompanying text.
  • 313
    • 78649577791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coping through California's budget crises in light of proposition 13 and California's fiscal constitution
    • Jack Citrin & Isaac William Martin eds.
    • For a discussion of alternative solutions for the state of California, see David Gamage, Coping Through California's Budget Crises in Light of Proposition 13 and California's Fiscal Constitution, in AFTER THE TAX REVOLT: PROPOSITION 13 TURNS 30 59-65 (Jack Citrin & Isaac William Martin eds, 2009).
    • (2009) After the Tax Revolt: Proposition 13 Turns , vol.30 , pp. 59-65
    • Gamage, D.1
  • 314
    • 78649564431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aug. 13, 2009, 12:27 EST
    • Freakonomics Blog, http://freakonomics.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/08/13/ (Aug. 13, 2009, 12:27 EST) ("no crisis should go to waste").


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.