메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 6, Issue 3, 2010, Pages 619-652

Revising the horizontal merger guidelines

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77956932230     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhq007     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (36)

References (39)
  • 1
    • 77956913647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. DEP'TOFJUSTICE & FED. (revised), available at, [hereinafter Horizontal Merger Guidelines]
    • U.S. DEP'TOFJUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES (revised 1997), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/horiz_book/hmgl.html [hereinafter HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES].
    • (1997) Trade Comm'n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 2
    • 77956911493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust modernization comm'n, Report and Recommendations, at. I was one of the Commissioners
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS, at 48 (2007). I was one of the Commissioners.
    • (2007) , pp. 48
  • 5
    • 77950542690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market Definition
    • art. 9
    • See, e.g., Joseph Farrell & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market Definition, 10(1) THE B.E.J. THEORETICAL ECON. art. 9 (2010).
    • (2010) The B.E.J. Theoretical Econ. , vol.10 , Issue.1
    • Farrell, J.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 6
    • 70349224184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why We Need to Measure the Effect of Merger Policy and How to Do It
    • Dennis Carlton, Why We Need to Measure the Effect of Merger Policy and How to Do It, 5 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 77 (2009)
    • (2009) Competition Pol'y Int'l , vol.5 , pp. 77
    • Carlton, D.1
  • 7
    • 77955718946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Improving Critical Loss Analysis
    • See, e.g., Joseph Farrell & Carl Shapiro, Improving Critical Loss Analysis, 7 ANTITRUST SOURCE 1 (2008).
    • (2008) Antitrust Source , vol.7 , pp. 1
    • Farrell, J.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 8
    • 13444279473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The State of Critical Loss Analysis: Let's Make Sure We Understand the Whole Story
    • David Scheffman & Joseph Simons, The State of Critical Loss Analysis: Let's Make Sure We Understand the Whole Story, 3 ANTITRUST SOURCE 1 (2003)
    • (2003) Antitrust Source , vol.3 , pp. 1
    • Scheffman, D.1    Simons, J.2
  • 9
    • 77956924502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • I use the word "appear" because, in practice, unilateral effects are often estimated using a merger simulation model that allows for the nonmerged firms to alter their prices post-merger
  • 10
    • 77956909814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Fixed cost reductions result in real resource savings which benefit society. However, there is no need to debate whether merger review should be based on consumer surplus or total surplus (including both producer and consumer surplus) as long as the role of fixed cost savings in fostering dynamic competition is properly recognized.
  • 11
    • 77956910645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • To cite one example, Murphy and Topel find that advances in medical technology and health care have resulted in very large benefits to consumers. They conclude that "[c]umulative gains in life expectancy after 1900 were worth over $1.2 million to the representative American in 2000, whereas post-1970 gains added about $3.2 trillion per year to national wealth, equal to about half of GDP."
  • 12
    • 33750965437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Value of Health and Longevity
    • Kevin Murphy & Robert Topel, The Value of Health and Longevity, 114 J. POL. ECON. 871 (2006).
    • (2006) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.114 , pp. 871
    • Murphy, K.1    Topel, R.2
  • 13
    • 33947654442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mergers and Innovation
    • for a discussion of cases involving innovation markets
    • See Michael Katz & Howard Shelanski, Mergers and Innovation, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 1 (2007) for a discussion of cases involving innovation markets.
    • (2007) Antitrust L.J. , vol.74 , pp. 1
    • Katz, M.1    Shelanski, H.2
  • 14
    • 33845969119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Intellectual Property, Antitrust and Strategic Behavior
    • (A. Jaffe, J. Lerner & S. Stern eds., National Bureau of Economic Research)
    • See Dennis Carlton & Robert Gertner, Intellectual Property, Antitrust and Strategic Behavior, in INNOVATION POLICY AND THE ECONOMY 3 (A. Jaffe, J. Lerner & S. Stern eds., National Bureau of Economic Research 2003).
    • (2003) Innovation Policy and the Economy , pp. 3
    • Carlton, D.1    Gertner, R.2
  • 15
    • 36248998439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Definition: Use and Abuse
    • Dennis Carlton, Market Definition: Use and Abuse, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 3 (2007)
    • (2007) Competition Pol'y Int'l , vol.3 , pp. 3
    • Carlton, D.1
  • 16
    • 0004199595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fed. Trade Comm'n & Dep'tofjustice, at 1 (Apr. 20) [hereinafter Proposed Guidelines]
    • FED. TRADE COMM'N & DEP'TOFJUSTICE, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES FOR PUBLIC COMMENT, at 1 (Apr. 20, 2010) [hereinafter PROPOSED GUIDELINES].
    • (2010) Horizontal Merger Guidelines for Public Comment
  • 17
    • 33845724627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Evaluating the Performance of Merger Simulation: Evidence from the U.S. Airline Industry
    • See, e.g., Craig Peters, Evaluating the Performance of Merger Simulation: Evidence from the U.S. Airline Industry, 49 J.L. & ECON. 627 (2006).
    • (2006) J.L. & Econ. , vol.49 , pp. 627
    • Peters, C.1
  • 18
    • 77956920620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In particular, the Proposed Guidelines raise the HHI cutoff from 1000 to 1500 for "moderately concentrated" markets and from 1800 to 2500 for "highly concentrated" markets. In moderately concentrated markets, the proposed Guidelines maintain the standard that mergers that induce HHI changes of 100 or more "potentially raise significant competitive concerns and often warrant scrutiny." However, for highly concentrated markets, the proposed Guidelines raise from 50 to 100 the change required for mergers to warrant scrutiny and from 100 to 200 the change required for a merger to create a presumption of enhanced market power.
  • 19
    • 77956940079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For an example, note that, in the pharmaceutical industry (an industry with important nonprice competition to introduce new and improved products), in markets with post-merger HHIs between 3000 and 5000 and merger-induced changes in HHI between 200 and 1200 (which would be presumed to enhance market power under the Proposed Guidelines), there were nearly as many cases (10) in which the merger was approved with no conditions as cases (11) in which relief was sought. In contrast, for oil mergers, of the 23 markets with HHI levels and changes in this range, relief was sought in 22.
  • 20
    • 77956937158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • To the extent that research on this topic occurs, it should also evaluate concentration measures other than HHI that are used by the agencies, such as the number of "significant competitors in the market."
  • 21
    • 77956899052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In particular, in the context of unilateral effects, the Guidelines state that "the elimination of competition between two firms that results from their merger may alone constitute a substantial lessening of competition." In the context of coordinated effects, the Guidelines state that "a merger may diminish competition by enabling or encouraging post-merger coordinated interaction among firms."
  • 22
    • 77956931270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Throughout this section, I use the term "UPP" to refer to the general methodology described in Farrell and Shapiro's paper and the term "UPP index" to refer to the specific mathematical formula computed as part of the methodology
  • 23
    • 79960954506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Should New Merger Guidelines Give UPP Market Definition?
    • The notation here borrows from
    • The notation here borrows from Richard Schmalensee, Should New Merger Guidelines Give UPP Market Definition?, 1 GCP: THE ANTITRUST CHRON. 1 (2009).
    • (2009) GCP: The Antitrust Chron , vol.1 , pp. 1
    • Schmalensee, R.1
  • 24
    • 77956932406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Work in progress, Harvard University), available from the author on request
    • See Glen Weyl, The First-Order Approach to Merger Analysis (Work in progress, Harvard University 2010), available from the author on request
    • (2010) The First-Order Approach to Merger Analysis
    • Weyl, G.1
  • 25
    • 77956938815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • This critique applies not only to UPP but also more generally to merger simulation models that rely on a specific model of oligopoly such as static Bertrand competition. This critique also highlights the need for empirical work on the accuracy of predictions based on UPP. The extent to which, in practice, deviations from Bertrand competition may bias results based on UPP (or merger simulation) cannot be known without substantial testing.
  • 26
    • 77956916324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For example, in a long-run equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market with identical firms, price equals marginal cost, which equals average total cost, and thus exceeds average variable cost.
  • 28
    • 77956944215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • 4 are prices for Firms 1 through 4, respectively. The demand curves for other firms are symmetric to that of Firm 1. The marginal cost for each firm is $75. Competition is assumed to be static Bertrand. Hence, at the pre-merger equilibrium, the following conditions hold: each product has a price of $100, each firm sells a quantity of 25 units, the own-price elasticity for each product is equal to 24, and the cross-price elasticity between all products is equal to 1.
  • 29
    • 28044459376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pass-through Rates and the Price Effects of Mergers
    • See Luke Froeb, Steven Tschantz & Gregory J. Werden, Pass-through Rates and the Price Effects of Mergers, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 703 (2005).
    • (2005) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 703
    • Froeb, L.1    Tschantz, S.2    Werden, G.J.3
  • 30
    • 77956923422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The fact that different demand curves can lead to substantially different price predictions is well understood, having been previously documented in the context of merger simulations.
  • 31
    • 0032738687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Effects of Assumed Demand Form on Simulated Postmerger Equilibria
    • See, e.g., Philip Crooke, Luke Froeb, Steven Tschantz & Gregory Werden, Effects of Assumed Demand Form on Simulated Postmerger Equilibria, 15 REV. INDUS. ORG. 205 (1999).
    • (1999) Rev. Indus. Org. , vol.15 , pp. 205
    • Crooke, P.1    Froeb, L.2    Tschantz, S.3    Werden, G.4
  • 32
    • 0442279264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger Simulation: A Simplified Approach with New Applications
    • The PCAIDS demand system, a variant of the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS), was proposed for use in merger simulations by
    • The PCAIDS demand system, a variant of the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS), was proposed for use in merger simulations by Roy Epstein & Daniel Rubinfeld, Merger Simulation: A Simplified Approach with New Applications, 6 ANTITRUST L.J. 883 (2001).
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.6 , pp. 883
    • Epstein, R.1    Rubinfeld, D.2
  • 33
    • 77956908910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • 4), with the demand curves for all other firms symmetric to that of Firm 1. For both Case A and Case B, the marginal cost for each firm is $75. Competition is again assumed to be static Bertrand. Hence, in the pre-merger equilibria for both Case A and Case B, the following conditions hold: each product has a price of $100, each firm sells a quantity of 25 units, the own-price elasticity for each product is equal to 24, and the cross-price elasticity between all products is equal to 1.
  • 34
    • 77956945246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • As discussed above, the UPP index for Product 1 is precisely the same as a cost change only when the prices of other products are held fixed, so that there are no feedback effects. However, to conform with standard merger simulation methods, the results in Table 2 allow the prices of all products to change. My conclusions are unaffected if I instead model a case in which only the price of Product 1 is allowed to change, with the prices of all other products fixed at their pre-merger levels, thus eliminating feedback effects.
  • 35
    • 77956913926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Note that this result implies that it is entirely possible for there to be situations in which the UPP index is higher for potential merger A than potential merger B even though the predicted price change (using merger simulation) is larger for potential merger B. This result does not require that the mergers under consideration occur in different industries with different demand curves. For example, even if one restricts attention to a specific type of demand curve (for example, PCAIDS), different combinations of own-and cross-price elasticities can generate the same value for the UPP index but yield different predictions of price changes following a merger.
  • 36
    • 77956895950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The only change from Case B of Table 2 is that I assume that, due to efficiencies from the merger, the marginal cost of Product 1 falls by 10 percent.
  • 37
    • 77956913360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Some researchers have suggested using this modification to UPP as a way to include the effect of cross-product efficiencies.
  • 38
    • 77956932146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • As part of his analysis, Peters also studies the simpler method of predicting the post-merger price based on historical relationships between prices and market concentration. Interestingly, he finds that, in many cases, this simpler method yields results that are fairly similar to more sophisticated merger simulation methods.
  • 39
    • 77956925368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • As described there, such retrospective studies would need to control for post-merger changes in industry conditions and for the "selection bias" induced by the fact that only consummated mergers can be studied, but there are standard econometric techniques for implementing such controls.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.