-
2
-
-
85081524562
-
-
See id. at 660-661
-
See id. at 660-661
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
85081516720
-
-
See id. at 661
-
See id. at 661.
-
-
-
-
4
-
-
85081505921
-
-
See id. at 662
-
See id. at 662.
-
-
-
-
5
-
-
85081494184
-
-
See id. at 663
-
See id. at 663.
-
-
-
-
6
-
-
85081505863
-
-
Id at 664
-
Id at 664.
-
-
-
-
7
-
-
85081525256
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
8
-
-
85081527305
-
-
See id. at 669
-
See id. at 669.
-
-
-
-
9
-
-
85081496779
-
-
See id. at 669 n.41
-
See id. at 669 n.41.
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
85081496531
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
11
-
-
85081494266
-
-
See id. at 659-660
-
See id. at 659-660
-
-
-
-
12
-
-
85081505610
-
-
Press Release, The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, The Prize in Economic Sciences 2009 (Oct 12,) [hereinafter Press Release], available at
-
Press Release, The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, The Prize in Economic Sciences 2009 (Oct 12, 2009) [hereinafter Press Release], available at http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/economics/laureates/2009/press.html.
-
(2009)
-
-
-
15
-
-
85081524713
-
-
Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 675-77
-
Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 675-77;
-
-
-
-
16
-
-
85081523632
-
-
Press Release, supra note 12
-
Press Release, supra note 12.
-
-
-
-
17
-
-
0014413249
-
The tragedy of the commons
-
See Garrett Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 Science 1243 (1968).
-
(1968)
162 Science
, vol.1243
-
-
Hardin, G.1
-
20
-
-
85081494116
-
-
Solum, supra note 15
-
Solum, supra note 15.
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
85081526844
-
-
Note
-
The full story is more complex. The tragedy of the commons is better described as a "volunteer dilemma" and not as a "prisoner's' dilemma." In addition, the "tragedy of the commons" as described by Hardin could involve what are called threshold effects, and if information about these effects were available, then overuse of the commons at the threshold of damage might be both individually and collectively irrational. See Kuhn, supra note 15.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
85081516854
-
-
See, e.g., Hardin, supra note 14, at 1245
-
See, e.g., Hardin, supra note 14, at 1245.
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
85081516618
-
-
Solum, supra note 19; see also Richard G. Lipsey & K. Alec Chrystal, Economics 278-280 (11th ed. 2007)
-
Solum, supra note 19; see also Richard G. Lipsey & K. Alec Chrystal, Economics 278-280 (11th ed. 2007).
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
85081496440
-
-
Property rights and contract law enable economically efficient exchanges by creating the legal mechanism by which parties can exchange private goods
-
Property rights and contract law enable economically efficient exchanges by creating the legal mechanism by which parties can exchange private goods.
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
85081523944
-
-
Solum, supra note 19
-
Solum, supra note 19.
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
85081512246
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
77953493368
-
Public goods
-
(David R. Henderson ed.), available at
-
Tyler Cowen, Public Goods, in The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics 431 (David R. Henderson ed., 2008), available at http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/ PublicGoods.html;
-
(2008)
The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics
, vol.431
-
-
Cowen, T.1
-
32
-
-
27644494986
-
Ideas artifacts and facilities: Information as a common-pool resource
-
Charlotte Hess & Elinor Ostrom, Ideas, Artifacts, and Facilities: Information as a Common-Pool Resource, 66 Law & Contemp. Probs. 1ll, 118-121 (2003)
-
(2003)
66 Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.111
, pp. 118-121
-
-
Hess, C.1
Ostrom, E.2
-
34
-
-
85081503174
-
-
Solum, supra note 19
-
Solum, supra note 19.
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
85081501296
-
-
See Savas, supra note 25, at 45, 51-53
-
See Savas, supra note 25, at 45, 51-53
-
-
-
-
36
-
-
85081522350
-
-
Ostrom & Ostrom, supra note 25, at 78-79
-
Ostrom & Ostrom, supra note 25, at 78-79
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
85081499941
-
-
Solum, supra note 19
-
Solum, supra note 19.
-
-
-
-
38
-
-
85081502330
-
-
See Savas, supra note 25, at 45, 50-51
-
See Savas, supra note 25, at 45, 50-51
-
-
-
-
39
-
-
85081518052
-
-
Ostrom & Ostrom, supra note 25, at 78-79
-
Ostrom & Ostrom, supra note 25, at 78-79
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
85081497363
-
-
Solum, supra note 19
-
Solum, supra note 19.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
85081509178
-
-
See Solum, supra note 19
-
See Solum, supra note 19;
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
85081501666
-
-
Ostrom & Ostrom, supra note 25, at 78 (discussing theater use
-
Ostrom & Ostrom, supra note 25, at 78 (discussing theater use).
-
-
-
-
44
-
-
85081506489
-
-
Maine Lobstermen's Association, (last visited Mar. 12, 2010)
-
I will use this gendered form throughout, reflecting usage among the community of lobster fishers. See, e.g., Maine Lobstermen's Association, http://www.mainelobstermen.org (last visited Mar. 12, 2010).
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
85081515431
-
-
Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 659
-
Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 659;
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
85081503427
-
-
See Acheson, supra note 13, at 71-83
-
See Acheson, supra note 13, at 71-83;
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
85081508295
-
-
Salz, supra note 31, at 7 (internal citation omitted
-
Salz, supra note 31, at 7 (internal citation omitted)
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
85081493453
-
-
see also Acheson, supra note 13, at 74-75
-
see also Acheson, supra note 13, at 74-75.
-
-
-
-
51
-
-
85081504602
-
Lobster dispute turns violent on maine Island
-
Sept. 13
-
Clarke Canfield, Lobster Dispute Turns Violent on Maine Island, Philadelphia Inquirer, Septl3, 2009, http://74.125.93.132/search?q=cache: Yq6FSArXLBEJ:www.philly.com/inquirer/world-m/20090913-Lobster-dispute- tams+philadelphia+inqmrer+maine+lobster&cd=l&hl=en&ct=clnk&gl= us&client=firefox-a.
-
(2009)
Philadelphia Inquirer
-
-
Canfield, C.1
-
52
-
-
85081507162
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
85081518161
-
-
Salz, supra note 31, at 8
-
Salz, supra note 31, at 8.
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
85081495152
-
-
Note
-
When I say that self-restraint is rational, I mean to invoke a conception of rationality that includes preferences that are shaped by social norms. On this conception of rationality, behavior that is not profit maximizing may nonetheless be individually rational because each individual prefers conformance with the social norm to profit maximization.
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
85081516745
-
-
I have used scare quotes around the word "property" to indicate that the lobsters are not de jure (legally sanctioned) property
-
I have used scare quotes around the word "property" to indicate that the lobsters are not de jure (legally sanctioned) property.
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
85081494472
-
-
Madison, Frischmann, and Strandburg describe the structure of Ostrom's framework in detail. See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 675-681
-
Madison, Frischmann, and Strandburg describe the structure of Ostrom's framework in detail. See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 675-681
-
-
-
-
58
-
-
85081527451
-
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 681
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 681.
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
85081524880
-
-
Id. at 675-683
-
Id. at 675-683
-
-
-
-
60
-
-
85081512358
-
-
See id. at 666, 672-73, 694-695
-
See id. at 666, 672-73, 694-695
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
2442532220
-
-
last visited Jan. 30, 2009
-
This fact is one source of the slogan, "Information wants to be free." Roger Clarke, "Information Wants to be Free. . .", http://www.rogerclarke.com/II/IWtbF.html (last visited Jan. 30, 2009).
-
Information Wants to Be Free. . .
-
-
Clarke, R.1
-
62
-
-
85081507486
-
-
The origin of the phrase is obscure. A precursor, "Information should be free," has been attributed to Peter Samson, a member of the MIT Tech Model Railroad Club. Id.
-
The origin of the phrase is obscure. A precursor, "Information should be free," has been attributed to Peter Samson, a member of the MIT Tech Model Railroad Club. Id.
-
-
-
-
63
-
-
85081512936
-
-
The slogan, "Information wants to be free," is usually attributed to Stewart Brand. Id.
-
The slogan, "Information wants to be free," is usually attributed to Stewart Brand. Id.
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
85081517556
-
-
To be more precise, wild lobsters are produced by nature. Farmed lobsters would be produced by human activity
-
To be more precise, wild lobsters are produced by nature. Farmed lobsters would be produced by human activity.
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
85081506131
-
-
See supra Part I.B
-
See supra Part I.B.
-
-
-
-
66
-
-
85081509654
-
-
Note
-
This interpretation of their core thesis-limiting the relationship of cultural commons and natural-resource commons to family resemblance-does not seem plausible. Although they acknowledge that they "adapt, extend, and distinguish [Ostrom's work] to account for important differences between constructed cultural commons and natural resource commons," that work would not even be relevant to their project if the relationship between the two types of commons were mere family resemblance. Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 660.
-
-
-
-
67
-
-
85081521516
-
-
See Hardin, supra note 14, at 1244-1245 (using the example of a group of herdsmen sharing a pasture to feed their respective cattle to illustrate the concept of the commons)
-
See Hardin, supra note 14, at 1244-1245 (using the example of a group of herdsmen sharing a pasture to feed their respective cattle to illustrate the concept of the commons).
-
-
-
-
68
-
-
85081526331
-
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 706
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 706.
-
-
-
-
69
-
-
85081500070
-
-
Government funding of research is usually understood as a public-good arrangement and not as a commons
-
Government funding of research is usually understood as a public-good arrangement and not as a commons.
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
85081520872
-
-
Id. at 659
-
Id. at 659.
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
85081524723
-
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 690-691
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 690-691
-
-
-
-
72
-
-
85081524002
-
-
See id. at 690-695
-
See id. at 690-695
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
0009811858
-
-
discussing the fact-value distinction
-
I use the fact-value distinction to mark the familiar dichotomy. By using scare quotes in the text, I mean to indicate that I do not endorse the claim that there cannot be "moral facts." See generally Hilary Putnam, The Collapse of the Fact/Value Dichotomy and Other Essays (2002) (discussing the fact-value distinction).
-
(2002)
The Collapse of the Fact/Value Dichotomy and Other Essays
-
-
Putnam, H.1
-
74
-
-
85081495260
-
-
Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 664-665
-
Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 664-665
-
-
-
-
76
-
-
85081524033
-
-
See id. at 5
-
See id. at 5.
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
26044477779
-
Siren songs and amish children: Autonomy, information, and law
-
SeeYochai Benkler, Siren Songs and Amish Children: Autonomy, Information, and Law, 76 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 23, 59 (2001)
-
(2001)
76 N.Y.U. L. Rev.
, vol.23
, pp. 59
-
-
Benkler, Y.1
-
79
-
-
85081507292
-
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 664-665
-
See Madison, Frischmann & Strandburg, supra note 1, at 664-665
-
-
-
-
81
-
-
77953532330
-
A property right in self-expression: Equality and individualism in the natural law of intellectual property
-
See Wendy J. Gordon, A Property Right in Self-Expression: Equality and Individualism in the Natural Law of Intellectual Property, 102 Yale LJ. 1533, 1549-1552 (1993);
-
(1993)
102 Yale LJ.
, vol.1533
, pp. 1549-1552
-
-
Gordon, W.J.1
-
82
-
-
33745678499
-
The making of a new copyright lockean
-
Lior Zemer, The Making of a New Copyright Lockean, 29 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 891, 892-893 (2006).
-
(2006)
29 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y
, vol.891
, pp. 892-893
-
-
Zemer, L.1
-
83
-
-
57849130652
-
Legislative intent: The use of positive political theory in statutory interpretation
-
16-21, ("McNollgast" is a hybrid pseudonym for Mathew D. McCubbins, Roger G. Noll, and Barry R. Weingast)
-
McNollgast, Legislative Intent: The Use of Positive Political Theory in Statutory Interpretation, 57 Law & Contemp. Probs. 3, 11, 16-21 (1994) ("McNollgast" is a hybrid pseudonym for Mathew D. McCubbins, Roger G. Noll, and Barry R. Weingast);
-
(1994)
57 Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.3
, pp. 11
-
-
McNollgast1
-
84
-
-
0003770005
-
-
presenting a study of vetoes in the federal system and analyzing how presidents use vetoes to prevent and alter legislation
-
see generally Charles M. Cameron, Veto Bargaining: Presidents and the Politics of Negative Power (2000) (presenting a study of vetoes in the federal system and analyzing how presidents use vetoes to prevent and alter legislation).
-
(2000)
Veto Bargaining: Presidents and the Politics of Negative Power
-
-
Cameron, C.M.1
|