메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 6, Issue 1, 2010, Pages 65-86

Behavioral economics, consumer protection, and antitrust

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77951571303     PISSN: 15540189     EISSN: 15546853     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (11)

References (52)
  • 1
    • 0038548458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for "Asymmetric paternalism
    • The field of behavioral economics is quite vast and a complete survey of the literature is far beyond the scope of this article. For those seeking a more extensive review
    • The field of behavioral economics is quite vast and a complete survey of the literature is far beyond the scope of this article. For those seeking a more extensive review, see C. Camerer, S. Issacharoff, G. Loewenstein, T. O'Donoghue, & M. Rabin, Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism," 151 U. PA. L. REV. 1211 (2003);
    • (2003) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.151 , pp. 1211
    • Camerer, C.1    Issacharoff, S.2    Loewenstein, G.3    O'Donoghue, T.4    Rabin, M.5
  • 3
    • 84903035283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the Diamond & Vartiainen volume, the chapter by Bernheim & Rangel provides a clear and succinct summary of ways in which individual behavior has been documented to deviate from rationality and the issues in how to incorporate such behavioral factors into economic models
    • and R. Thaler & C. Sunstein, NUDGE: IMPROVING DECISIONS ABOUT HEALTH,WEALTH, AND HAPPINESS (2008). In the Diamond & Vartiainen volume, the chapter by Bernheim & Rangel provides a clear and succinct summary of ways in which individual behavior has been documented to deviate from rationality and the issues in how to incorporate such behavioral factors into economic models.
    • (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness
    • Thaler, R.1    Sunstein, C.2
  • 4
    • 44249108400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral public economics: Welfare and policy analysis with nonstandard decision-makers
    • (P. Diamond & H Vartiainen eds.
    • See B.D. Bernheim & A. Rangel, Behavioral Public Economics: Welfare and Policy Analysis with Nonstandard Decision-Makers, BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS AND ITS APPLICATIONS (P. Diamond & H Vartiainen eds.) (2007).
    • (2007) Behavioral Economics and its Applications
    • Bernheim, B.D.1    Rangel, A.2
  • 6
    • 0004192228 scopus 로고
    • Predictive accuracy was one of the justifications Cyert & March gave for their behavioral theory of a firm
    • Predictive accuracy was one of the justifications Cyert & March gave for their behavioral theory of a firm. See R.M. CYERT & J.G. MARCH, A BEHAVIORAL THEORY OF THE FIRM (1963).
    • (1963) A Behavioral Theory of the Firm
    • Cyert, R.M.1    March, J.G.2
  • 9
    • 84903035283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The observation that the behavior is technically consistent with revealed preference and a strong taste for looking to the left is due to Bernheim & Rangel. See B.D. Bernheim & A. Rangel, supra note 1. Thaler & Sunstein also discuss the London pedestrian example
    • The observation that the behavior is technically consistent with revealed preference and a strong taste for looking to the left is due to Bernheim & Rangel. See B.D. Bernheim & A. Rangel, supra note 1. Thaler & Sunstein also discuss the London pedestrian example. See R. THALER & C. SUNSTEIN, NUDGE: IMPROVING DECISIONS ABOUT HEALTH,WEALTH, AND HAPPINESS 90 (2008).
    • (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness , pp. 90
    • Thaler, R.1    Sunstein, C.2
  • 10
    • 77951533402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Governments are still needed to provide public goods like defense and they can have a role in correcting externalities that arise when a transaction between two parties affects others that are not party to the transaction. The efficiency of market outcomes does not necessarily imply a distribution of income that society would consider ideal or even satisfactory, so there might be a role for government in redistributing income
    • Governments are still needed to provide public goods like defense and they can have a role in correcting externalities that arise when a transaction between two parties affects others that are not party to the transaction. The efficiency of market outcomes does not necessarily imply a distribution of income that society would consider ideal or even satisfactory, so there might be a role for government in redistributing income.
  • 11
    • 0002734011 scopus 로고
    • The economics of information
    • G.J. Stigler, The Economics of Information, 69, J. POL. ECON. 213 (1961).
    • (1961) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.69 , pp. 213
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 12
    • 84959835849 scopus 로고
    • Equilibrium distribution of sales and advertising prices
    • G.R. Butters, Equilibrium Distribution of Sales and Advertising Prices 44 REV. ECON. STUD. 465 (1977).
    • (1977) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.44 , pp. 465
    • Butters, G.R.1
  • 13
    • 77951597224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • P. Diamond & H. Vartiainen (eds.) supra note 1
    • P. Diamond & H. Vartiainen, Introduction, P. Diamond & H. Vartiainen (eds.) supra note 1 at 2.
    • Introduction , pp. 2
    • Diamond, P.1    Vartiainen, H.2
  • 14
    • 77951603769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more complete elaboration of deviations from rationality, supra note 1
    • For a more complete elaboration of deviations from rationality, see Thaler & Sunstein, supra note 1
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 15
  • 16
    • 0001248680 scopus 로고
    • Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulats et axiomes de l'école Américaine
    • M. Allais, Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque: critique des postulats et axiomes de l'école Américaine, 21 ECONOMETRICA 503 (1953).
    • (1953) Econometrica , vol.21 , pp. 503
    • Allais, M.1
  • 17
    • 77951566912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although the probabilities do not match up exactly, suppose that the choice is made at the start of the Major League Baseball season in United States and Canada. Think of the 10 percent occurrence as the New York Yankees winning the World Series, the 1 percent chance being the Cincinnati Reds winning the World Series, and the 89 percent chance being any team besides the Yankees or Reds winning the World Series. In the first choice, the individual either takes $1 million for sure or, alternatively, $5 million if the Yankees win, $0 if the Reds win, and $1 million otherwise. The choice is between getting $1 million if either the Yankees or Reds win the World Series as opposed to $5 million if just the Yankees win. For both choices, the individual's decision only matters if the Reds or Yankees win. The amount one gets if someone other than the Yankees or Reds wins does not rationally affect this choice
    • Although the probabilities do not match up exactly, suppose that the choice is made at the start of the Major League Baseball season in United States and Canada. Think of the 10 percent occurrence as the New York Yankees winning the World Series, the 1 percent chance being the Cincinnati Reds winning the World Series, and the 89 percent chance being any team besides the Yankees or Reds winning the World Series. In the first choice, the individual either takes $1 million for sure or, alternatively, $5 million if the Yankees win, $0 if the Reds win, and $1 million otherwise. The choice is between getting $1 million if either the Yankees or Reds win the World Series as opposed to $5 million if just the Yankees win. For both choices, the individual's decision only matters if the Reds or Yankees win. The amount one gets if someone other than the Yankees or Reds wins does not rationally affect this choice.
  • 18
    • 77951600444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When behavioral economists say that "framing" affects decisions, they mean that people make different choices when the same information is presented in different ways
    • When behavioral economists say that "framing" affects decisions, they mean that people make different choices when the same information is presented in different ways.
  • 19
    • 77951599382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tversky died in 1996. Nobel Prizes are not awarded posthumously
    • Tversky died in 1996. Nobel Prizes are not awarded posthumously.
  • 20
    • 0016264378 scopus 로고
    • Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases
    • (New Series
    • D. Kahneman & H. Tversky, Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, 185 (New Series) SCIENCE 1124 (1974).
    • (1974) Science , vol.185 , pp. 1124
    • Kahneman, D.1    Tversky, H.2
  • 21
    • 77951584386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, they gave respondents a description of a person with characteristics that matched the stereotype of a librarian and asked for the relative probabilities that the person was farmer, physician, salesman, airline pilot, or librarian. Research has shown that on average, respondents give too little weight to the fact that some professions are far more common than others
    • For example, they gave respondents a description of a person with characteristics that matched the stereotype of a librarian and asked for the relative probabilities that the person was farmer, physician, salesman, airline pilot, or librarian. Research has shown that on average, respondents give too little weight to the fact that some professions are far more common than others.
  • 22
    • 77951588837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 1
    • Thaler & Sunstein, supra note 1, at 23.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 24
    • 77951540645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Status quo bias can be understood as a way in which framing matters
    • Status quo bias can be understood as a way in which framing matters.
  • 25
    • 0038969032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting
    • D. Laibson, Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting, 112 Q. J. ECON. 861 (1997).
    • (1997) Q. J. Econ. , vol.112 , pp. 861
    • Laibson, D.1
  • 27
    • 0004110659 scopus 로고
    • The insight that humans sometimes give in to short-run temptation with disproportionately severe long-term consequences dates back at least to the story of the Garden of Eden. Restricting attention to people considered to be economists, consider the following quote: "The man who acts according to the rules of perfect prudence, of strict justice, and of proper benevolence, may be said to be perfectly virtuous. But the most perfect knowledge of these rules will not alone enable him to act in this manner: his own passions are very apt to mislead him; sometimes to drive him and sometimes to seduce him to violate all the rules which he himself, in all his sober and cool hours, approves of.", (The reference is to a Clarendon Press edition. The book was originally published in 1759
    • The insight that humans sometimes give in to short-run temptation with disproportionately severe long-term consequences dates back at least to the story of the Garden of Eden. Restricting attention to people considered to be economists, consider the following quote: "The man who acts according to the rules of perfect prudence, of strict justice, and of proper benevolence, may be said to be perfectly virtuous. But the most perfect knowledge of these rules will not alone enable him to act in this manner: his own passions are very apt to mislead him; sometimes to drive him and sometimes to seduce him to violate all the rules which he himself, in all his sober and cool hours, approves of." See A. SMITH, THE THEORY OF MORAL SENTIMENTS (1976). (The reference is to a Clarendon Press edition. The book was originally published in 1759.)
    • (1976) The Theory of Moral Sentiments
    • Smith, A.1
  • 28
    • 46549099071 scopus 로고
    • The equity premium puzzle
    • The equity premium puzzle is that the average return to equities so far exceeded the return to bonds that it was hard to reconcile investors' willingness to hold bonds with plausible degrees of risk aversion, (With the S&P 500 now roughly 20 percent below its value a decade ago, the puzzle may not be as pronounced as it once was
    • The equity premium puzzle is that the average return to equities so far exceeded the return to bonds that it was hard to reconcile investors' willingness to hold bonds with plausible degrees of risk aversion. See R. Mehra & E.C. Prescott, The Equity Premium Puzzle, 15 J. MONETARY ECON. 145 (1985). (With the S&P 500 now roughly 20 percent below its value a decade ago, the puzzle may not be as pronounced as it once was.)
    • (1985) J. Monetary Econ. , vol.15 , pp. 145
    • Mehra, R.1    Prescott, E.C.2
  • 29
    • 0000893807 scopus 로고
    • Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends
    • See, for example
    • See, for example, R.J. Schiller, Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends, 71 AM. ECON. REV. 421 (1981)
    • (1981) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 421
    • Schiller, R.J.1
  • 30
    • 0001843717 scopus 로고
    • The present value relations: Tests based on implied variance bounds
    • S.F. LeRoy & R.D. Porter, The Present Value Relations: Tests Based on Implied Variance Bounds, 49 ECONOMETRICA 551 (1981).
    • (1981) Econometrica , vol.49 , pp. 551
    • LeRoy, S.F.1    Porter, R.D.2
  • 31
    • 77951528325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See comments of P. Diamond in P. Diamond & H.Vartiainen (eds.), supra note 1
    • See comments of P. Diamond in P. Diamond & H.Vartiainen (eds.), supra note 1, at 303.
  • 33
    • 84959809412 scopus 로고
    • Bargains and ripoffs: A model of monopolistically competitive price dispersion
    • S. Salop & J. Stiglitz, Bargains and Ripoffs: A Model of Monopolistically Competitive Price Dispersion, 44 REV. ECON. STUD. 493 (1977).
    • (1977) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.44 , pp. 493
    • Salop, S.1    Stiglitz, J.2
  • 34
    • 33646375435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shrouded attributes, consumer myopia, and information suppression in competitive markets
    • X. Gabaix & D. Laibson, Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets, 121 Q. J. ECON. 505 (2006).
    • (2006) Q. J. Econ. , vol.121 , pp. 505
    • Gabaix, X.1    Laibson, D.2
  • 35
    • 77951553658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The customers who end up paying the late fuel charges may not literally be uninformed. The group would include those with strong preferences not to refuel and little concern for the cost and those who, due to the unfolding of travel-day events, end up not having the time to refuel
    • The customers who end up paying the late fuel charges may not literally be uninformed. The group would include those with strong preferences not to refuel and little concern for the cost and those who, due to the unfolding of travel-day events, end up not having the time to refuel.
  • 36
    • 77951549722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sometimes they do. As is discussed below, Southwest Airlines advertises its competitors' shrouded charges
    • Sometimes they do. As is discussed below, Southwest Airlines advertises its competitors' shrouded charges.
  • 37
    • 77951613399 scopus 로고
    • The FTC as national nanny
    • March 1
    • The FTC as National Nanny, THE WASH. POST, March 1, 1978.
    • (1978) The Wash. Post
  • 38
    • 0348173832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The federal trade commission's use of unfairness authority: Its rise, fall, and resurrection
    • J.H. Beales, III, The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection, 22 J. PUB. POL. AND MKTG 192, (2003).
    • (2003) J. Pub. Pol. And Mktg , vol.22 , pp. 192
    • Beales III, J.H.1
  • 39
    • 77951542549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 1
    • Camerer et al., supra note 1.
    • Camerer1
  • 40
    • 77951598858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • define a successful asymmetrically paternalistic policy as one for which: (p*B) - (1 - p) C - I + Δπ > 0, where p is the fraction of boundedly rational individuals, (1 - p) is the fraction of fully rational individuals, B is the benefit of the policy to the boundedly rational individuals, C is the cost to the fully rational consumers, I is the implementation costs, and π is the economic profits of companies supplying the market in question
    • Camerer et al. define a successful asymmetrically paternalistic policy as one for which: (p*B) - (1 - p) C - I + Δπ > 0, where p is the fraction of boundedly rational individuals, (1 - p) is the fraction of fully rational individuals, B is the benefit of the policy to the boundedly rational individuals, C is the cost to the fully rational consumers, I is the implementation costs, and π is the economic profits of companies supplying the market in question.
    • Camerer1
  • 41
    • 77951617748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • consider disclosure requirements more intrusive than defaults because they might be more costly
    • Cameron et al. consider disclosure requirements more intrusive than defaults because they might be more costly.
    • Cameron1
  • 42
  • 43
    • 77951536483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • the Bureau of Economics at the FTC held a conference on the application of behavioral economics to consumer protection regulation, available at
    • In 2007, the Bureau of Economics at the FTC held a conference on the application of behavioral economics to consumer protection regulation, available at http://www.ftc.gov/be/consumerbehavior/ index.shtml.
    • (2007)
  • 45
    • 77951542048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An important part of the explanation is that many of the FTC consumer protection actions entail fraudulent activities by "judgment-proof" parties. Liability is not a close call requiring a careful weighing of costs and benefits, and penalties are driven more by the financial resources of defendants than by a measure of economic damages
    • An important part of the explanation is that many of the FTC consumer protection actions entail fraudulent activities by "judgment-proof" parties. Liability is not a close call requiring a careful weighing of costs and benefits, and penalties are driven more by the financial resources of defendants than by a measure of economic damages.
  • 46
    • 77951587746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Christine Jolls, Behavioral Law and Economics, Diamond and Varitainen (eds), supra note 1
    • Christine Jolls, Behavioral Law and Economics, Diamond and Varitainen (eds), supra note 1 at 115.
  • 47
    • 77951571070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As noted above, the need for consumer protection may lie more in some consumers making some very bad decisions than in ways in which consumer decisions are wrong (but only slightly so) on average
    • As noted above, the need for consumer protection may lie more in some consumers making some very bad decisions than in ways in which consumer decisions are wrong (but only slightly so) on average.
  • 48
    • 77951595013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is interesting to consider why there has been little interest in behavioral economics approaches in industrial economics. A possible explanation is that one of the factors that drives interest in behavioral approaches is anomalies that seem hard to explain with a model of rational behavior.With the decline in interest in cross-market empirical analysis in industrial economics, industrial economists have not done the sort of work that might be expected to yield anomalies. Anomalies may exist, however. For example, continued investment in the airline industry despite a history of massive losses should arguably be considered a major anomaly in the industrial economics literature
    • It is interesting to consider why there has been little interest in behavioral economics approaches in industrial economics. A possible explanation is that one of the factors that drives interest in behavioral approaches is anomalies that seem hard to explain with a model of rational behavior.With the decline in interest in cross-market empirical analysis in industrial economics, industrial economists have not done the sort of work that might be expected to yield anomalies. Anomalies may exist, however. For example, continued investment in the airline industry despite a history of massive losses should arguably be considered a major anomaly in the industrial economics literature.
  • 49
    • 0002537125 scopus 로고
    • The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers
    • R. Roll, The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers, 59 J. BUS. 197 (1986).
    • (1986) J. Bus. , vol.59 , pp. 197
    • Roll, R.1
  • 52
    • 77951580246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I do not mean to suggest that there are no implications. I am not aware of any analysis of them, however, and they are not transparent without analysis
    • I do not mean to suggest that there are no implications. I am not aware of any analysis of them, however, and they are not transparent without analysis.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.