메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 97, Issue 6, 2009, Pages 1651-1686

Libertarian welfarism

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77950179397     PISSN: 00081221     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (35)

References (186)
  • 1
    • 0042409519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and behavioral science: Removing the rationality assumption from law and economics
    • See, &, 1060-66
    • See Russell Korobkin & Thomas S. Ulen, Law and Behavioral Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics, 88 CALIF. L. REV. 1051, 1060-66 (2000).
    • (2000) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 1051
    • Korobkin, R.1    Ulen, T.S.2
  • 2
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics
    • Christine Jolls, Cass Sunstein, and Richard Thaler described this evidence as supporting "anti-antipaternalism-a skepticism about antipaternalism, but not an affirmative defense of paternalism." Christine Jolls et al., A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471, 1541 (1998). (Pubitemid 128421723)
    • (1998) Stanford Law Review , vol.50 , Issue.5 , pp. 1471
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 3
    • 33645781946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paternalism & Psychology
    • See, e.g., 134, claiming that government decision making "is likely to be particularly erroneous" because lawmakers are subject to the same biases as the individual but lack the incentive that individuals have to make optimal decisions
    • See, e.g., Edward L. Glaeser, Paternalism & Psychology, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 133, 134 (2006) (claiming that government decision making "is likely to be particularly erroneous" because lawmakers are subject to the same biases as the individual but lack the incentive that individuals have to make optimal decisions) ;
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 133
    • Glaeser, E.L.1
  • 4
    • 33645279705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The uncertain psychological case for paternalism
    • cf, 1168, "The psychological case for paternalism... must rest on a relative assessment of the cognitive costs of improved decision against the costs of supplanting individual choice."
    • cf. Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, The Uncertain Psychological Case for Paternalism, 97 NW. U. L. REV. 1165, 1168 (2003) ("The psychological case for paternalism... must rest on a relative assessment of the cognitive costs of improved decision against the costs of supplanting individual choice.").
    • (2003) NW. U. L. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1165
    • Rachlinski, J.J.1
  • 5
    • 0038548458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for "asymmetric paternalism"
    • Colin F. Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism", 151 U. PA. L. REV. 1211 (2003).
    • (2003) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.151 , pp. 1211
    • Camerer, C.F.1
  • 6
    • 77950113263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1219.
  • 7
    • 77950113739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economist as therapist: Methodological ramifications of "light" paternalism
    • &, in, Andrew Caplin & Andrew Schotter eds.
    • George Loewenstein & Emily Haisley, The Economist as Therapist: Methodological Ramifications of "Light" Paternalism, in THE FOUNDATIONS OF POSITIVE AND NORMATIVE ECONOMICS: A HANDBOOK 210 (Andrew Caplin & Andrew Schotter eds., 2008).
    • (2008) The Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics: A Handbook , pp. 210
    • Loewenstein, G.1    Haisley, E.2
  • 8
    • 0742306363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Libertarian paternalism is not an oxymoron
    • &, hereinafter Sunstein & Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism
    • Cass R. Sunstein & Richard H. Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1159 (2003) [hereinafter Sunstein & Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism].
    • (2003) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1159
    • Sunstein, C.R.1    Thaler, R.H.2
  • 9
    • 77950119746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are subtle differences between the policy visions laid out by Camerer et al. and Sunstein & Thaler. The former do not absolutely rule out coercion, as long as the cost of coercion is substantially outweighed by the welfare benefits enjoyed by individuals who are less than fully rational. The latter support only regulations that do not prevent any individuals from pursuing their desired course of action and impose no more than a small amount of inconvenience on those who wish to avoid the intervention
    • There are subtle differences between the policy visions laid out by Camerer et al. and Sunstein & Thaler. The former do not absolutely rule out coercion, as long as the cost of coercion is substantially outweighed by the welfare benefits enjoyed by individuals who are less than fully rational. The latter support only regulations that do not prevent any individuals from pursuing their desired course of action and impose no more than a small amount of inconvenience on those who wish to avoid the intervention.
  • 11
    • 77950110953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Guiding forces
    • See, e.g., Aug. 24, at BR, book review
    • See, e.g., Benjamin M. Friedman, Guiding Forces, N. Y. TIMES, Aug. 24, 2008, at BR 13 (book review) ;
    • (2008) N. Y. Times , pp. 13
    • Friedman, B.M.1
  • 12
    • 77649247359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What was I thinking?
    • Feb. 25, at, book review
    • Elizabeth Kolbert, What Was I Thinking?, NEW YORKER, Feb. 25, 2008, at 77 (book review) ;
    • (2008) New Yorker , pp. 77
    • Kolbert, E.1
  • 13
    • 77950156036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lured toward the right choice
    • Apr. 14, at, book review
    • Barbara Kiviat, Lured Toward the Right Choice, TIME, Apr. 14, 2008, at 76 (book review) ;
    • (2008) Time , pp. 76
    • Kiviat, B.1
  • 14
    • 77950100456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Special ideas report: Get rid of polls
    • Jul. 8
    • Conor Clarke, Special Ideas Report: Get Rid of Polls, ATLANTIC, Jul. 8, 2009, http://ideas.theatlantic.com/2009/07/get-rid-of-polls.php;
    • (2009) Atlantic
    • Clarke, C.1
  • 15
    • 77950177328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goldman should pay paulson a fat bonus
    • July 20
    • Paul B. Farrell, Goldman Should Pay Paulson a Fat Bonus, FOX BUSINESS, July 20, 2009, http://www.foxbusiness.com/story/markets/industries/finance/ goldman-pay-paulson-fat-bonus/;
    • (2009) Fox Business
    • Farrell, P.B.1
  • 16
    • 77950134566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A political plan to help save you more
    • July 24
    • Stephen Gandel, A Political Plan to Help Save You More, CNN MONEY MAGAZINE, July 24, 2008, http://money.cnn. com/2008/07/24/magazines/moneymag/ 105711588.moneymag/index.htm;
    • (2008) Cnn Money Magazine
    • Gandel, S.1
  • 17
    • 77950144808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taming your inner homer simpson
    • May 12
    • Dahlia Lithwick, Taming Your Inner Homer Simpson, SLATE, May 12, 2008, http://www.slate.com/id/2191156.
    • (2008) Slate
    • Lithwick, D.1
  • 18
    • 77950125009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • the article version of Libertarian Paternalism although, oddly, not in Nudge, Sunstein and Thaler briefly note the possibility that libertarian paternalism could be complemented by or distinguished from an approach that considers vulnerable third parties rather than the utility of the targeted actors themselves, &, supra note 7, at, 1185, 1193. As such, I do not wish to suggest that I have discovered something that these authors, or the other leading proponents of libertarian paternalism, failed to notice. However, Sunstein and Thaler neither flesh out the contours of a distinct complementary category nor compare its merits to those of libertarian paternalism. This article attempts to accomplish these two goals
    • In the article version of Libertarian Paternalism (although, oddly, not in Nudge), Sunstein and Thaler briefly note the possibility that libertarian paternalism could be complemented by or distinguished from an approach that considers vulnerable third parties rather than the utility of the targeted actors themselves. Sunstein & Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism, supra note 7, at 1162, 1185, 1193. As such, I do not wish to suggest that I have discovered something that these authors, or the other leading proponents of libertarian paternalism, failed to notice. However, Sunstein and Thaler neither flesh out the contours of a distinct complementary category nor compare its merits to those of libertarian paternalism. This article attempts to accomplish these two goals.
    • Libertarian Paternalism , pp. 1162
    • Sunstein1    Thaler2
  • 19
    • 77950113262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thaler and Sunstein put the point this way: "In our understanding, a policy is 'paternalistic' if it tries to influence choices in a way that will make choosers better off, as judged by themselves.", &, supra note 9, at
    • Thaler and Sunstein put the point this way: "In our understanding, a policy is 'paternalistic' if it tries to influence choices in a way that will make choosers better off, as judged by themselves." THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 5.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 20
    • 70049095588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For some common examples of paternalistic policies enacted into law, see, §, West, requiring drivers and passengers of motorcycles to wear a safety helmet
    • For some common examples of paternalistic policies enacted into law, see CAL. VEH. CODE § 27803 (West 2000) (requiring drivers and passengers of motorcycles to wear a safety helmet) ;
    • (2000) Cal. Veh. Code , pp. 27803
  • 21
    • 1542420400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §, West, requiring persons age 6 to 18 to enroll in and attend a full-time school
    • CAL. EDUC. CODE § 48201 (West 2006) (requiring persons age 6 to 18 to enroll in and attend a full-time school) ;
    • (2006) Cal. Educ. Code , pp. 48201
  • 22
    • 1542420400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §, West, establishing monetary penalties against parents or guardians who do not comply with compulsory education requirements
    • CAL. EDUC. CODE § 48293 (West 2006) (establishing monetary penalties against parents or guardians who do not comply with compulsory education requirements) ;
    • (2006) Cal. Educ. Code , pp. 48293
  • 23
    • 0348147575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §, West, preventing individuals under the age of 21 years from entering gambling establishments
    • CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 19921 (West 2008) (preventing individuals under the age of 21 years from entering gambling establishments).
    • (2008) Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code , pp. 19921
  • 24
    • 77950164660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 5-6.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 25
    • 77950158481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at, "The intervention must be easy and cheap to avoid.". Some critics have criticized the concept of libertarian paternalism on the grounds that it is inconsistent with a particular understanding of libertarian philosophy. This criticism misses the point of Thaler and Sunstein, whose argument is that the non-coercive nature of their paradigm should appeal to people who consider themselves libertarians
    • Id. at 6 ("[T]he intervention must be easy and cheap to avoid."). Some critics have criticized the concept of libertarian paternalism on the grounds that it is inconsistent with a particular understanding of libertarian philosophy. This criticism misses the point of Thaler and Sunstein, whose argument is that the non-coercive nature of their paradigm should appeal to people who consider themselves libertarians.
  • 26
    • 77950130678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the various conceptions of rational choice theory, as used in legal scholarship, see, &, supra note 1, at
    • For a discussion of the various conceptions of rational choice theory, as used in legal scholarship, see Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 1, at 1060-66.
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 27
    • 77950113740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See. e.g., &, supra note 1
    • See. e.g., Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 1;
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 28
    • 77950166500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2
    • Jolls et al., supra note 2;
    • Jolls1
  • 29
    • 0348098747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral theories of judgment and decision making in legal scholarship: A literature review
    • Donald C. Langevoort, Behavioral Theories of Judgment and Decision Making in Legal Scholarship: A Literature Review, 51 VAND. L. REV. 1499 (1998).
    • (1998) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1499
    • Langevoort, D.C.1
  • 30
    • 0016264378 scopus 로고
    • Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases
    • See, &, 1128
    • See Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, 185 science 1124, 1128 (1974).
    • (1974) Science , vol.185 , pp. 1124
    • Tversky, A.1    Kahneman, D.2
  • 31
    • 77950112224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • likelihood of any two events occurring cannot be greater than the likelihood of one of the events occurring on its own, &, supra note 9, at
    • The likelihood of any two events occurring cannot be greater than the likelihood of one of the events occurring on its own. THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 26-27.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 32
    • 77950152954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 17, at
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 17, at 1128-30.
    • Tversky1    Kahneman2
  • 33
    • 77950156872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, studies have shown that laypeople's estimate of the number of African countries in the United Nations is affected by whether a large or small number comes up on the spin of a wheel, id. at, and that real estate agents' estimates of the value of a house is biased by the only partially relevant anchor of the house's asking price
    • For example, studies have shown that laypeople's estimate of the number of African countries in the United Nations is affected by whether a large or small number comes up on the spin of a wheel, id. at 1128, and that real estate agents' estimates of the value of a house is biased by the (only partially relevant) anchor of the house's asking price.
  • 36
    • 0001371817 scopus 로고
    • Biased assimilation and attitude polarization: The effects of prior theories on subsequently considered evidence
    • See, e.g.
    • See, e.g., Charles G. Lord et al., Biased Assimilation and Attitude Polarization: The Effects of Prior Theories on Subsequently Considered Evidence, 37 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 2098 (1979).
    • (1979) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.37 , pp. 2098
    • Lord, C.G.1
  • 37
    • 30544450169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ambiguity and self-evaluation: The role of idiosyncratic trait definitions in self-serving assessments of ability
    • See, e.g., in, supra note 20, at
    • See, e.g., David Dunning et al., Ambiguity and Self-Evaluation: The Role of Idiosyncratic Trait Definitions in Self-Serving Assessments of Ability, in hEURISTICS AND BIASES: THE PSYCHOLOGY OF INTUITIVE JUDGMENT, supra note 20, at 324.
    • Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment , pp. 324
    • Dunning, D.1
  • 38
    • 12044256982 scopus 로고
    • Support theory: A nonextensional representation of subjective probability
    • See, &
    • See Amos Tversky & Derek J. Koehler, Support Theory: A Nonextensional Representation of Subjective Probability, 101 PSYCHOL. REV. 547 (1994) ;
    • (1994) Psychol. Rev. , vol.101 , pp. 547
    • Tversky, A.1    Koehler, D.J.2
  • 39
    • 0036551032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Forecasting trial outcomes: Lawyers assign higher probability to possibilities that are described in greater detail
    • &
    • Craig R. Fox & Richard Birke, Forecasting Trial Outcomes: Lawyers Assign Higher Probability to Possibilities That are Described in Greater Detail, 26 L. & HUM. BEHAV. 159 (2002).
    • (2002) L. & Hum. Behav. , vol.26 , pp. 159
    • Fox, C.R.1    Birke, R.2
  • 40
    • 77950124171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, &, supra note 23
    • See Tversky & Koehler, supra note 23;
    • Tversky1    Koehler2
  • 41
    • 77950147242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 23
    • Fox & Birke, supra note 23.
    • Fox1    Birke2
  • 42
    • 0003808669 scopus 로고
    • On the mathematics of rationally updating probability assessments when new information becomes available in accordance with "Bayes's Law, " see, e.g., &, 3d ed
    • On the mathematics of rationally updating probability assessments when new information becomes available in accordance with "Bayes's Law, " see, e.g., ROBERT V. HOGG & ALLEN T. CRAIG, INTRODUCTION TO MATHEMATICAL STATISTICS 208-09 (3d ed. 1995).
    • (1995) Introduction to Mathematical Statistics , pp. 208-209
    • Hogg, R.V.1    Craig, A.T.2
  • 43
    • 77950184272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • term "bounded rationality" is usually attributed to Herbert Simon
    • The term "bounded rationality" is usually attributed to Herbert Simon.
  • 44
    • 84959810873 scopus 로고
    • A behavioral model of rational choice
    • See
    • See Herbert A. Simon, A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, 69 Q. J. ECON. 99 (1955) ;
    • (1955) Q. J. Econ , vol.69 , pp. 99
    • Simon, H.A.1
  • 45
    • 77953466760 scopus 로고
    • Rational choice and the structure of the environment
    • in
    • HERBERT A. SIMON, Rational Choice and the Structure of the Environment, in MODELS OF MAN: SOCIAL AND RATIONAL 261 (1957).
    • (1957) Models of Man: Social and Rational , pp. 261
    • Herbert, A.S.1
  • 46
    • 20744456629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neuroeconomics: How neuroscience can inform economics
    • See, e.g., 11, 26
    • See, e.g., Colin Camerer et al., Neuroeconomics: How Neuroscience Can Inform Economics, 43 J. ECON. LITERATURE 9, 11, 26 (2005) ;
    • (2005) J. Econ. Literature , vol.43 , pp. 9
    • Camerer, C.1
  • 47
    • 0001621463 scopus 로고
    • Systematic errors and the theory of natural selection
    • 483
    • Michael Waldman, Systematic Errors and the Theory of Natural Selection, 84 AM. ECON. REV. 482, 483 (1994).
    • (1994) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 482
    • Waldman, M.1
  • 48
    • 52149119759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The case for mindless economics
    • See, e.g., &, in, supra note 6, at, 8 "As its welfare criterion, standard economics uses the individual's choice behavior, that is, revealed preferences.... Hence, welfare is defined to be synonymous with choice behavior."
    • See, e.g., Faruk Gul & Wolfgan Pesendorfer, The Case for Mindless Economics, in THE FOUNDATIONS OF POSITIVE AND NORMATIVE ECONOMICS, supra note 6, at 3, 8 ("As its welfare criterion, standard economics uses the individual's choice behavior, that is, revealed preferences.... Hence, welfare is defined to be synonymous with choice behavior.").
    • The Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics , pp. 3
    • Gul, F.1    Pesendorfer, W.2
  • 49
    • 33645786491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wanting, liking, and learning: Neuroscience and paternalism
    • Cf, 90-92, criticizing the familiar "revealed-preferences view that basically equates welfare experienced utility with choice decision utility, as a matter of the definition of welfare"
    • Cf. Colin F. Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning: Neuroscience and Paternalism, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 87, 90-92 (2006) (criticizing the familiar "revealed-preferences view [that] basically equates welfare (experienced utility) with choice (decision utility), as a matter of the definition of welfare").
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 87
    • Camerer, C.F.1
  • 50
    • 21344483676 scopus 로고
    • New challenges to the rationality assumption
    • Daniel Kahneman, New Challenges to the Rationality Assumption, 150 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL ECON. 18 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ , vol.150 , pp. 18
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 51
    • 77950135028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf, Ill. Pub. Law Research Paper No. 08-31, available at, arguing that "well-being" is better understood as "happiness or positive affect" than as preference satisfaction
    • Cf. John Bronsteen et al., Weil-Being Analysis 2 (Ill. Pub. Law Research Paper No. 08-31, 2009), available at http://ssrn. com/abstract=1397843 (arguing that "well-being" is better understood as "happiness or positive affect" than as preference satisfaction) ;
    • (2009) Weil-Being Analysis , vol.2
    • Bronsteen, J.1
  • 52
    • 77950141567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, Univ. of Pa. Inst, for Law & Econ. Research Paper No. 07-15, available at, arguing that individual wellbeing "consists in those things that individuals, with full information and deliberating rationally... converge in self-interestedly preferring, " rather than a consequence of preference satisfaction
    • Matthew Adler & Eric Posner, Happiness Research and Cost-Benefit Analysis 5 (Univ. of Pa. Inst, for Law & Econ. Research Paper No. 07-15, 2007), available at http://ssrn. com/abstract=999928 (arguing that individual wellbeing "consists in those things that individuals, with full information and deliberating rationally... converge in self-interestedly preferring, " rather than a consequence of preference satisfaction).
    • (2007) Happiness Research and Cost-benefit Analysis , vol.5
    • Adler, M.1    Posner, E.2
  • 53
    • 33645299546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Debiasing through law
    • See generally, &, 230-31, discussing the problem of "overshooting"
    • See generally Christine Jolls & Cass R. Sunstein, Debiasing Through Law, 35 J. LEGAL STUD. 199, 230-31 (2006) (discussing the problem of "overshooting").
    • (2006) J. Legal Stud , vol.35 , pp. 199
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 54
    • 75349111065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The construction of preference: An overview
    • &, in, Sarah Lichtenstein & Paul Slovic eds.
    • Sarah Lichtenstein & Paul Slovic, The Construction of Preference: An Overview, in THE CONSTRUCTION OF PREFERENCE 1 (Sarah Lichtenstein & Paul Slovic eds., 2006).
    • (2006) The Construction of Preference , pp. 1
    • Lichtenstein, S.1    Slovic, P.2
  • 55
    • 0000125532 scopus 로고
    • Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk
    • &, 274
    • Daniel Kahneman & Amos Tversky, Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk, 47 ECONOMETRICA 263, 274 (1979).
    • (1979) Econometrica , vol.47 , pp. 263
    • Kahneman, D.1    Tversky, A.2
  • 56
    • 0001595741 scopus 로고
    • Reference points, anchors, norms, and mixed feelings
    • See, 298
    • See Daniel Kahneman, Reference Points, Anchors, Norms, and Mixed Feelings, 51 ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAV. & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 296, 298 (1992).
    • (1992) Organizational Behav. & Hum. Decision Processes , vol.51 , pp. 296
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 58
    • 0041906953 scopus 로고
    • Toward a positive theory of consumer choice
    • This term was coined by Thaler, 44
    • This term was coined by Thaler. Richard H. Thaler, Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice, 1 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 39, 44 (1980) ;
    • (1980) J. Econ. Behav. & Org , vol.1 , pp. 39
    • Thaler, R.H.1
  • 59
    • 10044298804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The endowment effect and legal analysis
    • see also
    • see also Russell Korobkin, The Endowment Effect and Legal Analysis, 97 NW. U. L. REV. 1227 (2003).
    • (2003) NW. U. L. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1227
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 60
    • 0000704093 scopus 로고
    • Choice based on reasons: The case of attraction and compromise effects
    • See, 171-72
    • See Itamar Simonson, Choice Based on Reasons: The Case of Attraction and Compromise Effects, 16 J. CONSUMER RES. 158, 171-72 (1989).
    • (1989) J. Consumer Res , vol.16 , pp. 158
    • Simonson, I.1
  • 62
    • 0007016194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mixing virtue and vice: Combining the immediacy effect and the diversification heuristic
    • Daniel Read et al., Mixing Virtue and Vice: Combining the Immediacy Effect and the Diversification Heuristic, 12 J. BEHAV. DECISION MAKING 257 (1999) ;
    • (1999) J. Behav. Decision Making , vol.12 , pp. 257
    • Read, D.1
  • 63
    • 0007935565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Naïve diversification strategies in defined contribution savings plans
    • &
    • Shlomo Benartzi & Richard h. Thaler, Naïve Diversification Strategies in Defined Contribution Savings Plans, 91 AM. ECON. REV. 79 (2001).
    • (2001) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 79
    • Benartzi, S.1    Thaler, R.H.2
  • 65
    • 77950149965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stumble, predict, nudge: How behavioral economics informs law and policy
    • On Amir and Orly Lobel provide an interesting discussion of how the compromise and contrast effects might result from very different mental processes. On, &, 2110-12
    • On Amir and Orly Lobel provide an interesting discussion of how the compromise and contrast effects might result from very different mental processes. On Amir & Orly Lobel, Stumble, Predict, Nudge: How Behavioral Economics Informs Law and Policy, 108 COLUM. L. REV. 2098, 2110-12 (2008).
    • (2008) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.108 , pp. 2098
    • Amir1    Lobel, O.2
  • 67
    • 77950123226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Different theories of the power of social norms suggest slightly different motivational bases. Robert Cooter theorizes the power of norms comes from their internalization
    • Different theories of the power of social norms suggest slightly different motivational bases. Robert Cooter theorizes the power of norms comes from their internalization.
  • 68
    • 0041862208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Normative failure theory of law
    • See Robert Cooter, Normative Failure Theory of Law, 82 CORNELL L. REV. 947, 954-55 (1997). Richard McAdams argues that people comply with norms to earn the esteem of others. (Pubitemid 127445879)
    • (1997) Cornell Law Review , vol.82 , Issue.5 , pp. 947
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 69
    • 0001695934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The origin, development and regulation of norms
    • See, Eric Posner believes that norms have power because conformance with them generally signals that one is responsible and cooperative, which is valued by others
    • See Richard H. McAdams, The Origin, Development and Regulation of Norms, 96 MICH. L. REV. 338 (1997). Eric Posner believes that norms have power because conformance with them generally signals that one is responsible and cooperative, which is valued by others.
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 338
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 71
    • 77950160775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rationality of preference construction (and the irrationality of rational choice)
    • See, 707, "People form their preferences in many situations based on how they come to understand the choice they are making.... The choice made at a particular time is context-specific. In a different context, the choice may be different.... It is not clear why as a normative matter such preferences should be undesirable."
    • See Claire A. Hill, The Rationality of Preference Construction (and the Irrationality of Rational Choice), 9 MINN. J. L. SCI. & TECH. 689, 707 (2008) ("[P]eople form their preferences [in many situations] based on how they come to understand the choice they are making.... The choice made at a particular time is context-specific. In a different context, the choice may be different.... [I]t is not clear why as a normative matter such preferences should be undesirable.").
    • (2008) Minn. J. L. Sci. & Tech , vol.9 , pp. 689
    • Hill, C.A.1
  • 72
    • 0041109884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Time discounting and time preference: A critical review
    • See, 360-63
    • See Shane Frederick et al., Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review, 40 J. ECON. LITERATURE 351, 360-63 (2002).
    • (2002) J. Econ. Literature , vol.40 , pp. 351
    • Frederick, S.1
  • 73
    • 77950166961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 361.
  • 74
    • 77950142464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is essentially the position of Loewenstein and Haisley
    • This is essentially the position of Loewenstein and Haisley.
  • 75
    • 77950118221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, &, supra note 6, at
    • See Loewenstein & Haisley, supra note 6, at 201-05.
    • Loewenstein1    Haisley2
  • 76
    • 0030100132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior
    • See, e.g., 272-73, intense visceral factors drive a wedge between decisions and self-interest
    • See, e.g., George Loewenstein, Out of Control: Visceral Influences on Behavior, 65 ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAV. & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 272, 272-73 (1996) (intense visceral factors drive a wedge between decisions and self-interest).
    • (1996) Organizational Behav. & Hum. Decision Processes , vol.65 , pp. 272
    • Loewenstein, G.1
  • 78
    • 77950178249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Introspection about reasons can reduce post-choice satisfaction
    • See, in, supra note 33, at, 472-73
    • See Timothy D. Wilson et al., Introspection About Reasons Can Reduce Post-Choice Satisfaction, in THE CONSTRUCTION OF PREFERENCE, supra note 33, at 471, 472-73.
    • The Construction of Preference , pp. 471
    • Wilson, T.D.1
  • 79
    • 77950147241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lay rationalism and inconsistency between predicted experience and decision
    • in, supra note 33, at, 533
    • Christopher K. Hsee et al., Lay Rationalism and Inconsistency Between Predicted Experience and Decision, in THE CONSTRUCTION OF PREFERENCE, supra note 33, at 532, 533.
    • The Construction of Preference , pp. 532
    • Hsee, C.K.1
  • 80
    • 77950155240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 474-78.
  • 81
    • 77950130677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • authors conclude their study with the warning that "unbridled claims about the value of introspection need to be tempered." Id. at
    • The authors conclude their study with the warning that "unbridled claims about the value of introspection need to be tempered." Id. at 485.
  • 83
    • 0026110450 scopus 로고
    • Thinking Too much: Introspection can reduce the quality of preferences and decisions
    • See, &, 181
    • See T. D. Wilson & J. W. Schooler, Thinking Too Much: Introspection Can Reduce the Quality of Preferences and Decisions, 60 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 181, 181 (1991).
    • (1991) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.60 , pp. 181
    • Wilson, T.D.1    Schooler, J.W.2
  • 84
    • 34250785546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The functions of affect in the construction of preferences
    • Cf, in, supra note 33, at, 463 "Affect sometimes may help and other times hurt decision processes.... The presence of affect does not guarantee good or bad decisions, only different information processing."
    • Cf. Ellen Peters, The Functions of Affect in the Construction of Preferences, in THE CONSTRUCTION OF PREFERENCE, supra note 33, at 454, 463 ("[Affect] sometimes may help and other times hurt decision processes.... [T]he presence of affect does not guarantee good or bad decisions, only different information processing.") ;
    • The Construction of Preference , pp. 454
    • Peters, E.1
  • 85
    • 21144472942 scopus 로고
    • Introspecting about reasons can reduce post-choice satisfaction
    • 339, "More work is needed to specify the conditions under which introspecting about reasons will have deleterious consequences."
    • Timothy D. Wilson et al., Introspecting About Reasons Can Reduce Post-Choice Satisfaction, 19 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 331, 339 (1993) ("[M]ore work is needed to specify the conditions under which introspecting about reasons will have deleterious consequences.").
    • (1993) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.19 , pp. 331
    • Wilson, T.D.1
  • 86
    • 77950144369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 85.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 87
    • 77950134110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 92.
  • 88
    • 77950173200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 68-69.
  • 89
    • 77950144368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at, The authors propose similar requirements for mortgage lenders, cell phone service providers, and providers of Medicare prescription drug benefits
    • Id. at 145. The authors propose similar requirements for mortgage lenders, cell phone service providers, and providers of Medicare prescription drug benefits.
  • 90
    • 77950140640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 4, at
    • See Camerer et al., supra note 4, at 1231.
    • Camerer1
  • 91
    • 77950180173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 112-13.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 92
    • 77950167881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 4, at
    • Camerer et al., supra note 4, at 1227.
    • Camerer1
  • 93
    • 0039888638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The power of suggestion: Inertia in 401 (k) participation and savings behavior
    • See, e.g., &, 1184
    • See, e.g., Brigitte C. Madrian & Dennis F. Shea, The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401 (k) Participation and Savings Behavior, 116 Q. J. ECON. 1149, 1184 (2001).
    • (2001) Q. J. Econ , vol.116 , pp. 1149
    • Madrian, B.C.1    Shea, D.F.2
  • 94
    • 1842832021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase employee saving
    • &, s166
    • Richard H. Thaler & Shlomo Benartzi, Save More Tomorrow: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee Saving, 112 J. POL. ECON. s164, s166 (2004).
    • (2004) J. Pol. Econ , vol.112
    • Thaler, R.H.1    Benartzi, S.2
  • 95
    • 77950179721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 96
    • 77950143363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 116-21.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 97
    • 77950151342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 6, at
    • Loewenstein & Haisley, supra note 6, at 227-28.
    • Loewenstein1    Haisley2
  • 98
    • 77950185601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, &, supra note 9, at
    • See THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 253-54;
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 100
    • 77950131991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 4
    • Camerer et al., supra note 4, 1238-47.
    • Camerer1
  • 101
    • 77950104554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §, requiring door-to-door sales contracts to provide a three business-day cancellation period
    • 16 C. F. R. § 429.1 (2009) (requiring door-to-door sales contracts to provide a three business-day cancellation period).
    • (2009) C. F. R. , vol.16 , pp. 4291
  • 102
    • 0347936732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., §, b 3 A West, imposing a 10-day waiting period before a firearm can be released to a buyer or transferee. Federal law no longer requires a cooling off period, having replaced a 5-day waiting period with a required background check that can be processed immediately
    • See, e.g., CAL. PENAL CODE § 12071 (b) (3) (A) (West 2007) (imposing a 10-day waiting period before a firearm can be released to a buyer or transferee). Federal law no longer requires a cooling off period, having replaced a 5-day waiting period with a required background check that can be processed immediately.
    • (2007) Cal. Penal Code , pp. 12071
  • 103
    • 85051126069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, §, t
    • See 18 U. S. C. § 922 (t).
    • U. S. C. , vol.18 , pp. 922
  • 104
    • 0347517747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., § 46.b-67 a West, requiring a 90-day predivorce waiting period
    • See, e.g., CONN. GEN. STAT. ANN. § 46.b-67 (a) (West 2009) (requiring a 90-day predivorce waiting period).
    • (2009) Conn. Gen. Stat. Ann
  • 105
    • 77950127273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 105.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 107
    • 77950180172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note, however, that such interventions often mandate behavior by the third party who is required to provide or disclose the information, a feature that might in itself be problematic to true libertarians
    • Note, however, that such interventions often mandate behavior by the third party who is required to provide or disclose the information, a feature that might in itself be problematic to true libertarians.
  • 108
    • 77950125912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 92.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 109
    • 77950178789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 93-94.
  • 110
    • 77950111396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf, &, supra note 41, at, observing that requiring merchants to provide clearer information might cause consumers to overemphasize those attributes
    • Cf. Amir & Lobel, supra note 41, at 2114-15 (observing that requiring merchants to provide clearer information might cause consumers to overemphasize those attributes).
    • Amir1    Lobel2
  • 111
    • 22644448880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking behavioralism seriously: The problem of market manipulation
    • See generally, &
    • See generally Jon D. Hanson & Douglas A. Kysar, Taking Behavioralism Seriously: The Problem of Market Manipulation, 74 N. Y. U. L. REV. 630 (1999).
    • (1999) N. Y. U. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 630
    • Hanson, J.D.1    Kysar, D.A.2
  • 112
    • 0742271634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded rationality, standard form contracts, and unconscionability
    • See generally, 1234-35
    • See generally, Russell Korobkin, Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1203, 1234-35 (2003).
    • (2003) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1203
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 113
    • 77950154350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, &, supra note 41, at, "Thaler and Sunstein's assumption that, absent irrationalities, every individual would agree that future savings and improved long-term health are better than immediate satisfaction and gratification seems problematic."
    • See Amir & Lobel, supra note 41, at 2120 ("Thaler and Sunstein's assumption that, absent irrationalities, every individual would agree that future savings and improved long-term health are better than immediate satisfaction and gratification seems problematic.") ;
    • Amir1    Lobel2
  • 114
    • 23844457021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Review essay, libertarian paternalism is an oxymoron
    • 1268-69, criticizing Thaler and Sunstein for assuming that central planners can identify objective welfare measures that will satisfy everyone
    • Gregory Mitchell, Review Essay, Libertarian Paternalism Is an Oxymoron, 99 NW. U. L. REV. 1245, 1268-69 (2005) (criticizing Thaler and Sunstein for assuming that central planners can identify objective welfare measures that will satisfy everyone).
    • (2005) NW. U. L. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 1245
    • Mitchell, G.1
  • 115
    • 77950140152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If these assumptions fail to hold, the analysis becomes slightly more complicated
    • If these assumptions fail to hold, the analysis becomes slightly more complicated.
  • 116
    • 84933492847 scopus 로고
    • Making a difference: The contractual contributions of easterbrook and fischel
    • See generally
    • See generally Ian Ayres, Making a Difference: The Contractual Contributions of Easterbrook and Fischel, 59 U. CHI. L. REV. 1391 (1992)
    • (1992) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.59 , pp. 1391
    • Ayres, I.1
  • 118
    • 77950147684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even in this case, one might object that the policy maker would need to make some adjustments for risk. If investment returns over a certain period are abnormally high or the average lifespan suddenly increases, savers might report greater happiness with their decision that they would have under the alternative possible circumstances i.e., disappointing investment returns and shorter lifespans
    • Even in this case, one might object that the policy maker would need to make some adjustments for risk. If investment returns over a certain period are abnormally high or the average lifespan suddenly increases, savers might report greater happiness with their decision that they would have under the alternative possible circumstances (i.e., disappointing investment returns and shorter lifespans).
  • 119
    • 77950183802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 6, at, "Even light paternalistic policies should only be put into play when welfare judgments tend to be relatively straightforward."
    • Loewenstein & Haisley, supra note 6, at 221 ("[E]ven light paternalistic policies should only be put into play when welfare judgments tend to be relatively straightforward.").
    • Loewenstein1    Haisley2
  • 120
    • 77950127739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at, 240, 246
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 10, 240, 246.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 121
    • 18844383012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., &, supra note 7, at, "We happily grant that planners are human.... Nevertheless,... these human planners are sometimes forced to make choices, and it is surely better to have them trying to improve people's welfare rather than the opposite."
    • See, e.g., Sunstein & Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism, supra note 7, at 1200 ("We happily grant that planners are human.... Nevertheless,... these human planners are sometimes forced to make choices, and it is surely better to have them trying to improve people's welfare rather than the opposite.").
    • Libertarian Paternalism , pp. 1200
    • Sunstein1    Thaler2
  • 122
    • 77950167418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 1.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 123
    • 77950133310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 4-5.
  • 124
    • 77950176855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 5.
  • 125
    • 77950127271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf, supra note 44, at, "That preferences are constructed suggests that there is no clear way for law to respect what people really want-and that trying to respect what people really want ought not to trump other legitimate societal aims."
    • Cf. Hill, supra note 44, at 733 ("That preferences are constructed suggests that there is no clear way for law to respect what people really want-and that trying to respect what people really want ought not to trump other legitimate societal aims.").
    • Hill1
  • 126
    • 77950103631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • what he calls a "libertarian approach to choice-framing paternalism, " Gregory Mitchell suggests a goal that is different than both libertarian paternalism and libertarian welfarism. Mitchell argues that the state should "frame choices in ways that push irrational persons in directions that maximize their liberty or help them retain the greatest degree of future freedom to contract;" for example, by favoring default rules like at-will employment, supra note 80, atp1262
    • In what he calls a "libertarian approach to choice-framing paternalism, " Gregory Mitchell suggests a goal that is different than both libertarian paternalism and libertarian welfarism. Mitchell argues that the state should "frame choices in ways that push irrational persons in directions that maximize their liberty or help them retain the greatest degree of future freedom to contract;" for example, by favoring default rules like at-will employment. Mitchell, supra note 80, atp1262.
    • Mitchell1
  • 127
    • 77950105489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because true freedom includes the freedom to commit oneself to future actions, I do not think that maximizing future freedom to contract is a normatively defensible objective, even if we assume the primacy of personal liberty on the value hierarchy
    • Because true freedom includes the freedom to commit oneself to future actions, I do not think that maximizing future freedom to contract is a normatively defensible objective, even if we assume the primacy of personal liberty on the value hierarchy.
  • 130
  • 131
    • 31544457686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond efficiency and procedure: A welfarist theory of regulation
    • See, 244-46 noting that this requirement of what he calls the "neoclassical" theory of regulation "is a matter of interpretation, or at least sometimes it is-since the neoclassicist's commitment to efficiency... is sometimes implicit or even obscured rather than laid plain to view."
    • See Matthew D. Adler, Beyond Efficiency and Procedure: A Welfarist Theory of Regulation, 28 FLA. ST. L. REV. 241, 244-46 (noting that this requirement of what he calls the "neoclassical" theory of regulation "is a matter of interpretation, or at least sometimes it is-since the neoclassicist's commitment to efficiency... is sometimes implicit or even obscured rather than laid plain to view.")
    • Fla. St. L. Rev. , vol.28 , pp. 241
    • Adler, M.D.1
  • 132
    • 77950180580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., supra note 92, at
    • See, e.g., POSNER, supra note 92, at 390;
    • Posner1
  • 134
    • 0014413249 scopus 로고
    • The tragedy of the commons
    • See
    • See Garrett Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 SCIENCE 1243 (1968).
    • (1968) Science , vol.162 , pp. 1243
    • Hardin, G.1
  • 135
    • 77950116437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wealth, utility, and the human dimension
    • See, &, 602, "Normative economics holds that a law should be judged by its effects in promoting social welfare...."
    • See Jonathan Klick & Francesco Parisi, Wealth, Utility, and the Human Dimension, 1 N. Y. U. J. L. & LIBERTY 590, 602 (2005) ("Normative economics holds that a law should be judged by its effects in promoting social welfare....").
    • (2005) N. Y. U. J. L. & Liberty , vol.1 , pp. 590
    • Klick, J.1    Parisi, F.2
  • 136
    • 77950147923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • proponents of liberal paternalism might claim that inherent in their specific policy proposals is the limiting condition that the state should not nudge actors to significantly reduce social welfare. The pure theory of liberal paternalism, however, is indifferent to social welfare
    • The proponents of liberal paternalism might claim that inherent in their specific policy proposals is the limiting condition that the state should not nudge actors to significantly reduce social welfare. The pure theory of liberal paternalism, however, is indifferent to social welfare.
  • 137
    • 77950140150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 600.306-08 to.307-08
    • 40 C. F. R. § 600.306-08 to.307-08 (2008).
    • (2008) C. F. R. , vol.40
  • 139
    • 77950121129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New calif. Cars to sport greenhouse gas labels
    • A score of 5 signifies that a car's emissions will have an impact on Global Warming equivalent to that of an average new vehicle. A higher score denotes a car that is "better for the environment." See, June 20
    • A score of 5 signifies that a car's emissions will have an impact on Global Warming equivalent to that of an average new vehicle. A higher score denotes a car that is "better for the environment." See New Calif. Cars to Sport Greenhouse Gas Labels, MSNBC, June 20, 2008, http://www.msnbc.msn. com/id/25284062/.
    • (2008) Msnbc
  • 140
    • 77950159437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charity begins at schedule a
    • See, &, Apr. 15, at
    • See Ian Ayres & Barry Nalebuff, Charity Begins at Schedule A, N. Y. TIMES, Apr. 15, 2003, at A17.
    • (2003) N. Y. Times
    • Ayres, I.1    Nalebuff, B.2
  • 141
    • 77950180581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Utilities turn their customers green with envy
    • Jan. 30, at
    • Leslie Kaufman, Utilities Turn Their Customers Green With Envy, N. Y. TIMES, Jan. 30, 2009, at A1.
    • (2009) N. Y. Times
    • Kaufman, L.1
  • 142
    • 77950176854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 143
    • 0346403980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recycling norms
    • See, e.g., 1265
    • See, e.g., Ann E. Carlson, Recycling Norms, 89 CALIF. L. REV. 1265 (2001).
    • (2001) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.89
    • Carlson, A.E.1
  • 144
    • 77950131987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • portion of solid waste recycled in the United States increased from 10 percent in 1990 to nearly 30 percent in 2000, and this is due, at least in part, to the advent of curbside recycling programs
    • The portion of solid waste recycled in the United States increased from 10 percent in 1990 to nearly 30 percent in 2000, and this is due, at least in part, to the advent of curbside recycling programs.
  • 145
    • 33947620017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Policy watch: Examining the justification for residential recycling
    • See, 219
    • See Thomas C. Kinnamon, Policy Watch: Examining the Justification for Residential Recycling, 20 J. ECON. PERSPECTIVES 219, 219 (2006)
    • (2006) J. Econ. Perspectives , vol.20 , pp. 219
    • Kinnamon, T.C.1
  • 147
    • 58249084796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The state of garbage in america
    • see also, Dec, at, available at
    • see also Ljupka Arsova et al., The State Of Garbage In America, BIOCYCLE, Dec. 2008, at 22-23, available at http://www.jgpress.com/archives/-free/001782. html.
    • (2008) Biocycle , pp. 22-23
    • Arsova, L.1
  • 148
    • 77950123716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 104, at
    • Carlson, supra note 104, at 1275-78.
    • Carlson1
  • 149
    • 77950120196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1266.
  • 150
    • 77950176367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1290.
  • 151
    • 34447134151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "no compensation " or "pro compensation "
    • Moore v. Regents and Default Rules for Human Tissue Donations, 18
    • Russell Korobkin, "No Compensation " or "Pro Compensation ": Moore v. Regents and Default Rules for Human Tissue Donations, 40 J. HEALTH L. 1, 18 (2007).
    • (2007) J. Health L. , vol.40 , pp. 1
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 152
    • 33847234641 scopus 로고
    • Cal
    • 793 P.2d 479 (Cal. 1990).
    • (1990) P.2d , vol.793 , pp. 479
  • 153
    • 77950117309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 480-85.
  • 154
    • 84870578538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • National Organ Transplant Act, §, e a
    • National Organ Transplant Act, 42 U. S. C. § 274 e (a) (2006).
    • (2006) U. S. C. , vol.42 , pp. 274
  • 155
  • 156
    • 84875616998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. D. Fla
    • 264 F. Supp. 2d 1064 (S. D. Fla. 2003).
    • (2003) F. Supp. 2d , vol.264 , pp. 1064
  • 157
    • 77950140638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 37, at
    • See Korobkin, Endowment Effect, supra note 37, at 1228-29.
    • Endowment Effect , pp. 1228-1229
    • Korobkin1
  • 159
    • 77950148380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • plaintiffs' goal was to ensure affordable access to diagnostic tests, at
    • The plaintiffs' goal was to ensure affordable access to diagnostic tests. Greenberg, 264 F. Supp. 2d at 1066-67.
    • F. Supp. 2d , vol.264 , pp. 1066-1067
    • Greenberg1
  • 160
    • 77950167879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 177-84.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 161
    • 77950100914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When the truth is not enough: Tissue donation, altruism, and the market
    • See, e.g., 938
    • See, e.g., Michelle Oberman, When the Truth is Not Enough: Tissue Donation, Altruism, and the Market, 55 DEPAUL L. REV. 903, 938 (2006).
    • (2006) Depaul L. Rev. , vol.55 , pp. 903
    • Oberman, M.1
  • 162
    • 0642284005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do defaults save lives?
    • See, &
    • See Eric J. Johnson & Daniel Goldstein, Do Defaults Save Lives?, 302 SCIENCE 1338 (2003).
    • (2003) Science , vol.302 , pp. 1338
    • Johnson, E.J.1    Goldstein, D.2
  • 163
    • 77950184725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • &, supra note 9, at
    • THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 9, at 179-81.
    • Thaler1    Sunstein2
  • 164
    • 77950168340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As of September 7, 2009, the exact number was 103, 247
    • As of September 7, 2009, the exact number was 103, 247.
  • 165
    • 77950152950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United Network for Organ Sharing UNOS, National Data Reports, last visited Sept. 7
    • See United Network for Organ Sharing (UNOS), National Data Reports, http://optn. transplant.hrsa.gov/latestData/step2.asp (last visited Sept. 7, 2009).
    • (2009)
  • 166
    • 33646244013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recommendations implicit in policy defaults
    • 414
    • Craig R. M. McKenzie et al., Recommendations Implicit in Policy Defaults, 17 PSYCHOL. SCI. 414, 414 (2006).
    • (2006) Psychol. Sci , vol.17 , pp. 414
    • McKenzie, C.R.M.1
  • 167
    • 0031086655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Psychological aspects of organ donation: A critical review and synthesis of individual and next-of-kin donation decisions
    • See, &, 183, noting that beliefs about organ donation are influenced by the consequences of choosing to donate, including confronting the issue of mortality
    • See Carmen M. Radecki & James Jaccard, Psychological Aspects of Organ Donation: A Critical Review and Synthesis of Individual and Next-of-Kin Donation Decisions, 16 HEALTH PSYCHOL. 183, 183 (1997) (noting that beliefs about organ donation are influenced by the consequences of choosing to donate, including confronting the issue of mortality).
    • (1997) Health Psychol. , vol.16 , pp. 183
    • Radecki, C.M.1    Jaccard, J.2
  • 168
    • 0028354755 scopus 로고
    • Attitudes toward organ donation and transplantation: A model for understanding reactions to medical procedures after death
    • 1146, discussing discomfort with a dead body being cut and the organs removed as a motive for individuals' reticence towards organ donation
    • Margareta Sanner, Attitudes Toward Organ Donation and Transplantation: A Model for Understanding Reactions to Medical Procedures After Death, 38 SOC. SCI. & MED. 1141, 1146 (1994) (discussing discomfort with a dead body being cut and the organs removed as a motive for individuals' reticence towards organ donation).
    • (1994) Soc. Sci. & Med , vol.38 , pp. 1141
    • Sanner, M.1
  • 169
    • 77950181575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at, discussing individuals' fear that death will be hastened for the sake of someone more highly regarded who is in need of organs
    • Id. at 1148 (discussing individuals' fear that death will be hastened for the sake of someone more highly regarded who is in need of organs).
  • 170
    • 77950177326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Death in san louis obispo organ donor case is ruled natural
    • Cf, &, Mar. 9, at, discussing allegation that an organ donor's death was hastened by doctors for the benefit of the presumptive donee
    • Cf. Tracy Weber & Charles Ornstein, Death in San Louis Obispo Organ Donor Case is Ruled Natural, L. A. TIMES, Mar. 9, 2007, at B5 (discussing allegation that an organ donor's death was hastened by doctors for the benefit of the presumptive donee).
    • (2007) L. A. Times
    • Weber, T.1    Ornstein, C.2
  • 172
    • 77950110070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To be fair, Thaler and Sunstein recognize in the article-version of their argument that the organ donation example is inconsistent with many of their other policy examples in that the benefits of a presumed consent default flow to third parties rather than the choosers and call the consequence of organ donation "libertarian benevolence.", &, supra note 7, at, Puzzlingly, this distinction is not made when they elaborate on organ donation and recommend a presumed consent default in Nudge
    • To be fair, Thaler and Sunstein recognize in the article-version of their argument that the organ donation example is inconsistent with many of their other policy examples (in that the benefits of a presumed consent default flow to third parties rather than the choosers) and call the consequence of organ donation "libertarian benevolence." Sunstein & Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism, supra note 7, at 1192-93. Puzzlingly, this distinction is not made when they elaborate on organ donation and recommend a presumed consent default in Nudge.
    • Libertarian Paternalism , pp. 1192-1193
    • Sunstein1    Thaler2
  • 175
    • 33847032406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §, West, The calorie-posting requirement in California doesn't take effect until in 2011
    • CAL. HEALTH & SAFETY CODE § 114094 (West 2009). The calorie-posting requirement in California doesn't take effect until in 2011.
    • (2009) Cal. Health & Safety Code , pp. 114094
  • 176
    • 77950126794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Editorial, chewing the fat
    • July 25, at
    • Editorial, Chewing the Fat, WASH. POST, July 25, 2009, at A16;
    • (2009) Wash. Post
  • 177
    • 60549102415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conflict on the menu
    • Feb. 16, at
    • Stephanie Saul, Conflict on the Menu, N. Y. TIMES, Feb. 16, 2008, at C1.
    • (2008) N. Y. Times
    • Saul, S.1
  • 178
    • 77950113737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nanny nation
    • Aug. 6
    • Timothy Egan, Nanny Nation, N. Y. TIMES OUTPOSTS, Aug. 6, 2008, http://egan. blogs.nytimes.com/2008/08/06/nanny-nation/.
    • (2008) N. Y. Times Outposts
    • Egan, T.1
  • 179
    • 33645778708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "we can do this the easy way or the hard way": Negative emotions, self-regulation, and the law
    • See, &, 186, 190
    • See George Loewenstein & Ted O'Donoghue, "We Can Do This the Easy Way or the Hard Way": Negative Emotions, Self-Regulation, and the Law, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 183, 186, 190 (2006).
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 183
    • Loewenstein, G.1    O'Donoghue, T.2
  • 180
    • 34247851021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The epidemiology of obesity
    • 2090-91
    • Cynthia L. Ogden et al., The Epidemiology of Obesity, 132 GASTROENTEROLOGY 2087, 2090-91 (2007).
    • (2007) Gastroenterology , vol.132 , pp. 2087
    • Ogden, C.L.1
  • 181
    • 33745592293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Obesity gets part of blame for care costs
    • Oct. 20, at
    • Ceci Connolly, Obesity Gets Part of Blame for Care Costs, WASH. POST, Oct. 20, 2004, at A03.
    • (2004) Wash. Post
    • Connolly, C.1
  • 182
    • 1642409225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • National medical spending attributable to overweight and obesity: How much, and who's paying?
    • According to one study, in 1998 the public sector was responsible for financing nearly half of medical spending attributable to excessive weight, May 14, at
    • According to one study, in 1998 the public sector was responsible for financing nearly half of medical spending attributable to excessive weight. Eric A. Finkelstein et al., National Medical Spending Attributable to Overweight and Obesity: How Much, and Who's Paying?, HEALTH AFF., May 14, 2003, at 223-24.
    • (2003) Health Aff. , pp. 223-224
    • Finkelstein, E.A.1
  • 183
    • 33749339052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rise in spending among medicare beneficiaries: The role of chronic disease prevalence and changes in treatment intensity
    • Another found that nearly one-fourth of Medicare spending in 2002 was attributable to obese patients, &, Aug. 22, 2006, at
    • Another found that nearly one-fourth of Medicare spending in 2002 was attributable to obese patients. Kenneth E. Thorpe & David H. Howard, The Rise in Spending Among Medicare Beneficiaries: The Role of Chronic Disease Prevalence and Changes in Treatment Intensity, HEALTH AFF., Aug. 22, 2006, at 384 (2006).
    • (2006) Health Aff. , pp. 384
    • Thorpe, K.E.1    Howard, D.H.2
  • 184
    • 77950169704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1995, Medicare and Medicaid paid $50 billion, or about 56 percent, of long-term care expenditures for the elderly. The Congressional Budget Office has projected this figure will rise to $126 billion in 2020, or about 61 percent of total long-term care expenditures for the elderly, available at
    • In 1995, Medicare and Medicaid paid $50 billion, or about 56 percent, of long-term care expenditures for the elderly. The Congressional Budget Office has projected this figure will rise to $126 billion in 2020, or about 61 percent of total long-term care expenditures for the elderly. CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE, CBO MEMORANDUM: PROJECTIONS OF EXPENDITURES FOR LONG-TERM CARE SERVICES FOR THE ELDERLY 2 (1999), available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/11xx/doc1123/Itcare.pdf.140.
    • (1999) Congressional Budget Office, Cbo Memorandum: Projections of Expenditures for Long-Term Care Services for the Elderly , pp. 2
  • 185
    • 77950180170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 44, at
    • See Hill, supra note 44, at 708.
    • Hill1
  • 186
    • 77950155238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 104, at, noting that so-called "bottle bills remain politically contentious" and that none have been enacted by a state since the mid-1980s
    • See Carlson, supra note 104, at 1294 (noting that so-called "bottle bills remain politically contentious" and that none have been enacted by a state since the mid-1980s).
    • Carlson1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.