메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 95, Issue 1, 2009, Pages 139-159

Essay evolutionary theory and the origin of property rights

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 73949120483     PISSN: 00108847     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (69)

References (154)
  • 1
    • 73949132499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. PAPERS & PROC. 347 (1967).
    • Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. PAPERS & PROC. 347 (1967).
  • 2
    • 0041669221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas W. Merrill, Introduction: The Demsetz Thesis and the Evolution of Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S331, S331 (2002);
    • Thomas W. Merrill, Introduction: The Demsetz Thesis and the Evolution of Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S331, S331 (2002);
  • 4
    • 73949160833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350.
  • 7
    • 73949143137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 350, 354. He pictured three idealized forms of ownership - communal, private, and state.
    • Id. at 350, 354. He pictured three "idealized forms of ownership" - communal, private, and state.
  • 9
    • 73949148653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Demsetz, supra note 1, at 351 n.3 (citing Eleanor Leacock, The Montagnais Hunting Territory and the Fur Trade, AM. ANTHROPOLOGIST, Oct 1954, at 1). As Demsetz noted, Leacock was in essence building upon, and to some extent disagreeing with, an earlier work, Frank G. Speck, Basis of American Indian Ownership of the Land, OLD PENN WKLY. REV., Jan. 16, 1915, at 491.
    • See Demsetz, supra note 1, at 351 n.3 (citing Eleanor Leacock, The Montagnais "Hunting Territory" and the Fur Trade, AM. ANTHROPOLOGIST, Oct 1954, at 1). As Demsetz noted, Leacock was in essence building upon, and to some extent disagreeing with, an earlier work, Frank G. Speck, Basis of American Indian Ownership of the Land, OLD PENN WKLY. REV., Jan. 16, 1915, at 491.
  • 10
    • 84868051037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 351-53. Regarding trespass, Demsetz misread the evidence. Leacock's memoir emphasized that trespass meant one thing only, namely an intrusion arising when hunting for meat or fur to sell⋯. [A] man finding himself in need of food on another's land may kill the beaver - even all the beavers in a lodge - although he cannot kill them to sell the fur. Leacock, supra note 5, at 2 (footnote omitted). Notice the perverse incentive that resulted from this narrow prohibition on trespass: tribe members could use their own hunting territories to hunt beaver for sale and use their neighbors' hunting territories to hunt beaver for private consumption.
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 351-53. Regarding trespass, Demsetz misread the evidence. Leacock's memoir emphasized that trespass meant one thing only, namely an intrusion arising "when hunting for meat or fur to sell⋯. [A] man finding himself in need of food on another's land may kill the beaver - even all the beavers in a lodge - although he cannot kill them to sell the fur." Leacock, supra note 5, at 2 (footnote omitted). Notice the perverse incentive that resulted from this narrow prohibition on trespass: tribe members could use their own hunting territories to hunt beaver for sale and use their neighbors' hunting territories to hunt beaver for private consumption.
  • 11
    • 84868081016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THRÁINN EGGERTSSON, ECONOMIC BEHAVIOR AND INSTITUTIONS 251-52 (1990)
    • See THRÁINN EGGERTSSON, ECONOMIC BEHAVIOR AND INSTITUTIONS 251-52 (1990)
  • 12
    • 0012631454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing John C. McManus, An Economic Analysis of Indian Behavior in the North American Fur Trade, 32 J. ECON. HIST. 36 (1972)). McManus learned from historians of the fur trade that beaver populations were sharply reduced after the introduction of the fur trade into an area, McManus, supra, at 39, and that the Hudson Bay Company, the only buyer of furs for a time, had to take its own measures to conserve the beaver population,
    • (discussing John C. McManus, An Economic Analysis of Indian Behavior in the North American Fur Trade, 32 J. ECON. HIST. 36 (1972)). McManus learned from historians of the fur trade "that beaver populations were sharply reduced after the introduction of the fur trade into an area," McManus, supra, at 39, and that the Hudson Bay Company, the only buyer of furs for a time, had to take its own measures to conserve the beaver population,
  • 14
    • 73949132113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 51
    • Id. at 51.
  • 15
    • 0041669218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion Versus Governance: Two Strategies for Delineating Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S453, S457 n.9 (2002) (noting that the problem of overuse characteristic of a commons was first systematically studied in 1911, citing literature). But one can go back much further, to Aristotle and Aquinas, for instance, both of whom understood that common ownership promotes not just overuse of the resource in question but also underproduction.
    • See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion Versus Governance: Two Strategies for Delineating Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S453, S457 n.9 (2002) (noting that the "problem of overuse characteristic of a commons was first systematically studied" in 1911, citing literature). But one can go back much further, to Aristotle and Aquinas, for instance, both of whom understood that common ownership promotes not just overuse of the resource in question but also underproduction.
  • 16
    • 73949115726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ARISTOTLE, POLITICS, bk. 2, pt. 5, at 1262-64 (Trevor J. Saunders trans., Oxford Univ. Press 1995) (c. 350 B.C.);
    • See, e.g., ARISTOTLE, POLITICS, bk. 2, pt. 5, at 1262-64 (Trevor J. Saunders trans., Oxford Univ. Press 1995) (c. 350 B.C.);
  • 17
    • 73949155878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 THOMAS AQUINAS, SUMMA THEOLOGICA, IIa, IIae, Q. 66, art. 2 (Fathers of the English Dominican Province trans., 2d & rev. ed. 1920) (c. 1265-74).
    • 2 THOMAS AQUINAS, SUMMA THEOLOGICA, IIa, IIae, Q. 66, art. 2 (Fathers of the English Dominican Province trans., 2d & rev. ed. 1920) (c. 1265-74).
  • 18
    • 73949111655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz's argument built on R. H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960), which demonstrated that in the absence of transaction costs, all spillover effects of an activity will be taken into account through negotiations among the affected parties.
    • Demsetz's argument built on R. H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960), which demonstrated that in the absence of transaction costs, all spillover effects of an activity will be taken into account through negotiations among the affected parties.
  • 19
    • 84868051034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hume seems to have anticipated Demsetz's point by several centuries. See DAVID HUME, A TREATISE OF HUMAN NATURE, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 7, at 538 L.A. Selby-Bigge ed, Oxford Univ. Press 2d ed. 1978, 1740, Two neighbours may agree to drain a meadow, which they possess in common; because 'tis easy for them to know each others mind; and each must perceive, that the immediate consequence of his failing in his part, is, the abandoning the whole project. But 'tis very difficult, and indeed impossible, that a thousand persons shou'd agree in any such action; it being difficult for them to concert so complicated a design, and still more difficult for them to execute it; while each seeks a pretext to free himself of the trouble and expence, and wou'd lay the whole burden on others
    • Hume seems to have anticipated Demsetz's point by several centuries. See DAVID HUME, A TREATISE OF HUMAN NATURE, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 7, at 538 (L.A. Selby-Bigge ed., Oxford Univ. Press 2d ed. 1978) (1740): Two neighbours may agree to drain a meadow, which they possess in common; because 'tis easy for them to know each others mind; and each must perceive, that the immediate consequence of his failing in his part, is, the abandoning the whole project. But 'tis very difficult, and indeed impossible, that a thousand persons shou'd agree in any such action; it being difficult for them to concert so complicated a design, and still more difficult for them to execute it; while each seeks a pretext to free himself of the trouble and expence, and wou'd lay the whole burden on others.
  • 20
    • 73949122584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I note in passing the oddness of Demsetz citing the development of Indian hunting territories as a relevant example of his argument. Those hunting territories were held by families, not single individuals, and family ownership could give rise to high transaction costs even if the owners were few in number, thanks especially to opportunistic behavior (freeriders, holdouts) that provokes costly haggling, as in bilateral monopoly situations. This is why modern property law grants tenants in common and joint tenants the unilateral right to partition their holdings and convert them into ownership in severalty. In this connection, a close reading of the anthropological evidence cited by Demsetz suggests that the family territories were eventually partitioned off to individual family members, perhaps for the reasons just suggested. See Leacock, supra note 5, at 1 noting that there was continual readjustment of band lands to fit the needs of band members. Each Indian has
    • I note in passing the oddness of Demsetz citing the development of Indian hunting territories as a relevant example of his argument. Those hunting territories were held by families, not single individuals, and family ownership could give rise to high transaction costs even if the owners were few in number, thanks especially to opportunistic behavior (freeriders, holdouts) that provokes costly haggling, as in bilateral monopoly situations. This is why modern property law grants tenants in common and joint tenants the unilateral right to partition their holdings and convert them into ownership in severalty. In this connection, a close reading of the anthropological evidence cited by Demsetz suggests that the family territories were eventually partitioned off to individual family members - perhaps for the reasons just suggested. See Leacock, supra note 5, at 1 (noting that there was "continual readjustment of band lands to fit the needs of band members. Each Indian has a right to trapping lands of his own ⋯." (emphasis added) (footnote omitted)). That the hunting territories were, prior to partition, a commons, though one limited to family members (which could be few or many), might be another reason the beaver stock was overhunted, as discussed supra note 7.
  • 21
    • 73949150802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350. In a later article, Demsetz asserted that a right-defining and conflict-resolving institution, such as the court system, the legislature, or some community authority, is inevitably part of any property right system.
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350. In a later article, Demsetz asserted that "a right-defining and conflict-resolving institution, such as the court system, the legislature, or some community authority, is inevitably part of any property right system."
  • 22
    • 73949084298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harold Demsetz, Property Rights, in 3 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW 144, 144 (Peter Newman ed., 1998).
    • Harold Demsetz, Property Rights, in 3 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW 144, 144 (Peter Newman ed., 1998).
  • 23
    • 73949139623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merrill, supra note 2, at S333 (quoting Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350).
    • Merrill, supra note 2, at S333 (quoting Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350).
  • 24
    • 43149083314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harold Demsetz, Frischmann's View of Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 4 REV. L. & ECON. 127, 128 2008, I thank Brett Frischmann for calling this item to my attention
    • Harold Demsetz, Frischmann's View of "Toward a Theory of Property Rights", 4 REV. L. & ECON. 127, 128 (2008). I thank Brett Frischmann for calling this item to my attention.
  • 25
    • 73949160966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 26
    • 73949149969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 129. It is strange that Demsetz waited so long to set the record straight. He had a perfect opportunity to do so at a 2001 conference convened particularly to reexamine Toward a Theory of Property Rights. The title of the conference was The Evolution of Property Rights. Conference papers were subsequently published in Symposium, The Evolution of Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S331 (2002). Virtually all of the papers take Demsetz's article as an evolutionary account. Demsetz himself participated in the conference and contributed a paper.
    • Id. at 129. It is strange that Demsetz waited so long to set the record straight. He had a perfect opportunity to do so at a 2001 conference convened particularly to reexamine Toward a Theory of Property Rights. The title of the conference was "The Evolution of Property Rights." Conference papers were subsequently published in Symposium, The Evolution of Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S331 (2002). Virtually all of the papers take Demsetz's article as an evolutionary account. Demsetz himself participated in the conference and contributed a paper.
  • 27
    • 0041669214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights II: The Competition Between Private and Collective Ownership, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S653 (2002). Nowhere in that paper did he comment on the misapprehensions of his work.
    • See Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights II: The Competition Between Private and Collective Ownership, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S653 (2002). Nowhere in that paper did he comment on the misapprehensions of his work.
  • 28
    • 73949152481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JEREMY BENTHAM, THE THEORY OF LEGISLATION 112 (Richard Hildreth trans., 1975) (1802);
    • JEREMY BENTHAM, THE THEORY OF LEGISLATION 112 (Richard Hildreth trans., 1975) (1802);
  • 29
    • 73949106444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. at 113 (Property and law are born together, and the together. Before laws were made there was no property; take away laws, and property ceases.).
    • see also id. at 113 ("Property and law are born together, and the together. Before laws were made there was no property; take away laws, and property ceases.").
  • 30
    • 73949090012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., SAMUEL BOWLES, M ICROECONOMICS: BEHAVIOR, INSTITUTIONS, AND EVOLUTION (2004). Bowles points out that individual claims on property preceded the development of agriculture about eleven millennia ago and became more extensive thereafter; the rights emerged and proliferated without the assistance of states or other centralized enforcement agencies.
    • See, e.g., SAMUEL BOWLES, M ICROECONOMICS: BEHAVIOR, INSTITUTIONS, AND EVOLUTION (2004). Bowles points out that individual claims on property preceded the development of agriculture about eleven millennia ago and became more extensive thereafter; the rights "emerged and proliferated without the assistance of states or other centralized enforcement agencies."
  • 32
    • 73949116384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion supra note 4
    • See discussion supra note 4.
  • 33
    • 0041734597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carol M. Rose, The Several Futures of Property: Of Cyberspace and Folk Tales, Emission Trades and Ecosystems, 83 MINN. L. REV. 129, 155 (1998) (referring to commons on the inside, property on the outside). This usage is consistent with everyday lay usage. Suppose you and I own Ouracre as tenants in common. Is it not our private property? And so too if we join with twenty more, or one hundred, or one thousand? Still, some property scholars subscribe to a view that private property refers only to ownership by one person or a small number of persons.
    • See Carol M. Rose, The Several Futures of Property: Of Cyberspace and Folk Tales, Emission Trades and Ecosystems, 83 MINN. L. REV. 129, 155 (1998) (referring to "commons on the inside, property on the outside"). This usage is consistent with everyday lay usage. Suppose you and I own Ouracre as tenants in common. Is it not our private property? And so too if we join with twenty more, or one hundred, or one thousand? Still, some property scholars subscribe to a view that "private property" refers only to ownership by "one person or a small number of persons."
  • 34
    • 0037678339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property and the Right to Exclude, 77
    • using that definition, I regard this as not quite correct, though I suppose it matters little so long as everybody agrees on what everybody is talking about. But, as I have already suggested, everybody does not; hence the muddle. See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Thomas W. Merrill, Property and the Right to Exclude, 77 NEB. L. REV. 730, 733 (1998) (using that definition). I regard this as not quite correct, though I suppose it matters little so long as everybody agrees on what everybody is talking about. But, as I have already suggested, everybody does not; hence the muddle.
    • (1998) NEB. L. REV , vol.730 , pp. 733
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 35
    • 73949110647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the centrality of the exclusion right to the conception of property, see, for example, Merrill, supra note 20 passim
    • On the centrality of the exclusion right to the conception of property, see, for example, Merrill, supra note 20 passim.
  • 36
    • 84923946034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5 OXFORD ENGLISH DICTIONARY 476-77 2d ed. 1989, indicating sixteen meanings within three general significative categories
    • See, e.g., 5 OXFORD ENGLISH DICTIONARY 476-77 (2d ed. 1989) (indicating sixteen meanings within three general significative categories).
    • See, e.g
  • 37
    • 73949156326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBERT NOZICK, ANARCHY, STATE, AND UTOPIA 19 (1974);
    • ROBERT NOZICK, ANARCHY, STATE, AND UTOPIA 19 (1974);
  • 38
    • 73949130322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also BOWLES, supra note 18, at 57 (using the same terminology). Nozick cited a number of examples of invisible-hand explanations, most of which would be unfamiliar to legal scholars.
    • see also BOWLES, supra note 18, at 57 (using the same terminology). Nozick cited a number of examples of invisible-hand explanations, most of which would be unfamiliar to legal scholars.
  • 39
    • 73949091036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See NOZICK, supra, at 20-21. An example he did not provide, but which might be familiar, is the body of literature arguing that common law rules are pushed in the direction of efficiency because inefficient rules are litigated more often man efficient ones, thus increasing the probability that the inefficient rules will be filtered out over time. For discussion and criticism, see RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 604 (7th ed. 2007).
    • See NOZICK, supra, at 20-21. An example he did not provide, but which might be familiar, is the body of literature arguing that common law rules are pushed in the direction of efficiency because inefficient rules are litigated more often man efficient ones, thus increasing the probability that the inefficient rules will be filtered out over time. For discussion and criticism, see RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 604 (7th ed. 2007).
  • 40
    • 84868073781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Jack Hirshleifer, Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation Versus Conflict Strategies, 4 RES. L. & ECON. 1, 10 1982, The inventor of the bow had an intention, but it was only to help himself or his band; the spread of a new technique of hunting ⋯ was surely beyond his purpose
    • See, e.g., Jack Hirshleifer, Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation Versus Conflict Strategies, 4 RES. L. & ECON. 1, 10 (1982) ("The inventor of the bow had an intention, but it was only to help himself or his band; the spread of a new technique of hunting ⋯ was surely beyond his purpose.").
  • 41
    • 73949150340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ADAM SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONS 423 (Edwin Cannan ed., Random House 1937) (1776);
    • ADAM SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONS 423 (Edwin Cannan ed., Random House 1937) (1776);
  • 42
    • 73949096760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, e.g., Robert Sugden, Spontaneous Order, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DUGTIONARV OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 485, 493 (contrasting individual motivation and unintended collective consequence).
    • see also, e.g., Robert Sugden, Spontaneous Order, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DUGTIONARV OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 485, 493 (contrasting "individual motivation and unintended collective consequence").
  • 43
    • 73949129237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CHARLES DARWIN, ON THE ORIGIN OF SPECIES BY MEANS OF NATURAL SELECTION (6th rev. ed. 1888).
    • See CHARLES DARWIN, ON THE ORIGIN OF SPECIES BY MEANS OF NATURAL SELECTION (6th rev. ed. 1888).
  • 44
    • 73949136782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PERCIVAL DAVIS & DEAN H. KENYON, OF PANDAS AND PEOPLE: THE CENTRAL QUESTION OF BIOLOGICAL ORIGINS (1989), for the first comprehensive (and controversial) account of Intelligent Design in a high-school textbook explaining the origin of new organisms.
    • See PERCIVAL DAVIS & DEAN H. KENYON, OF PANDAS AND PEOPLE: THE CENTRAL QUESTION OF BIOLOGICAL ORIGINS (1989), for the first comprehensive (and controversial) account of Intelligent Design in a high-school textbook explaining the origin of new organisms.
  • 45
    • 73949114876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ROBERT C. ELLICKSON, ORDER WITHOUT LAW: HOW NEIGHBORS SETTLE DISPUTES (1991) (discussing the governance of relations among neighboring cattle ranchers by reference to informal norms and developing a theory of norm formation);
    • See, e.g., ROBERT C. ELLICKSON, ORDER WITHOUT LAW: HOW NEIGHBORS SETTLE DISPUTES (1991) (discussing the governance of relations among neighboring cattle ranchers by reference to informal norms and developing a theory of norm formation);
  • 46
    • 0042170036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard A. Epstein, The Allocation of the Commons: Parking on Public Roads, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S515, S528-33 (2002) (discussing the spontaneous emergence of snow-parking property rights in contemporary Chicago);
    • Richard A. Epstein, The Allocation of the Commons: Parking on Public Roads, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S515, S528-33 (2002) (discussing the spontaneous emergence of snow-parking property rights in contemporary Chicago);
  • 47
    • 18844435142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From Fur to Fish: Reconsidering the Evolution of Private Property, 80
    • presenting a case study that takes account of the role of government and the political process in the development of property rights
    • Katrina Miriam Wyman, From Fur to Fish: Reconsidering the Evolution of Private Property, 80 N.Y.U. L. REV. 117 (2005) (presenting a case study that takes account of the role of government and the political process in the development of property rights).
    • (2005) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.117
    • Miriam Wyman, K.1
  • 48
    • 84886342665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying note 17
    • See supra text accompanying note 17.
    • See supra
  • 49
    • 73949088480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350.
  • 50
    • 84886342665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying note 12
    • See supra text accompanying note 12.
    • See supra
  • 51
    • 73949130739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 12 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 12 and accompanying text
  • 52
    • 73949103730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350
    • Demsetz, supra note 1, at 350.
  • 53
    • 73949137267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (asserting that changes in property rights result from the desires of the interacting persons).
    • See id. (asserting that changes in property rights result from "the desires of the interacting persons").
  • 54
    • 73949115201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 352
    • Id. at 352.
  • 55
    • 73949160057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 353 n.7.
    • Id. at 353 n.7.
  • 56
    • 73949114511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RICHARD DAWKINS, THE ANCESTOR'S TALE: A PILGRIMAGE TO THE DAWN OF EVOLUTION 602 (2004).
    • RICHARD DAWKINS, THE ANCESTOR'S TALE: A PILGRIMAGE TO THE DAWN OF EVOLUTION 602 (2004).
  • 57
    • 73949099294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unless, of course, the account obviously takes for granted the existence of the designer and is interested only in how things developed from there on. A study of how the Federal Communications Commission allocates spectrum would not be rightly criticized for failing to explain how the Commission came to be created, how the authority that created it came to be authorized, etc
    • Unless, of course, the account obviously takes for granted the existence of the designer and is interested only in how things developed from there on. A study of how the Federal Communications Commission allocates spectrum would not be rightly criticized for failing to explain how the Commission came to be created, how the authority that created it came to be authorized, etc.
  • 58
    • 73949109962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., James E. Krier, The Tragedy of the Commons, Part Two, 15 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'V 325, 337-39 (1992).
    • See, e.g., James E. Krier, The Tragedy of the Commons, Part Two, 15 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'V 325, 337-39 (1992).
  • 59
    • 73949090639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kicking [the problem] upstairs, to use Carol Rose's nice expression. See Carol M. Rose, Evolution of Property Rights, in 2 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 93, 94.
    • "Kicking [the problem] upstairs," to use Carol Rose's nice expression. See Carol M. Rose, Evolution of Property Rights, in 2 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 93, 94.
  • 60
    • 73949152959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A governing authority might have come into power by force, but still the collective action problem persists; the challenge becomes one of explaining how any group managed to organize itself into a force
    • A governing authority might have come into power by force, but still the collective action problem persists; the challenge becomes one of explaining how any group managed to organize itself into a force.
  • 61
    • 0042671093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Stuart Banner, Transitions Between Property Regimes, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S359, S362 n.8 (2002) (collecting citations);
    • See, e.g., Stuart Banner, Transitions Between Property Regimes, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S359, S362 n.8 (2002) (collecting citations);
  • 62
    • 73949160036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Krier, supra note 39, at 338 n.44 (collecting citations);
    • Krier, supra note 39, at 338 n.44 (collecting citations);
  • 63
    • 73949127145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also EGGERTSSON, supra note 7, at 254 (discussing the failure of various accounts to deal with the free-riding problems that plague group decision);
    • see also EGGERTSSON, supra note 7, at 254 (discussing the failure of various accounts to "deal with the free-riding problems that plague group decision");
  • 64
    • 84868056544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 250 (finding this a characteristic feature of the naive theory of property rights, which seek[s] to explain the development of exclusive property rights without explicitly modeling social and political institutions. Demsetz's 1967 paper ⋯ is the classic reference for the naive theory of property rights. (emphasis omitted));
    • id. at 250 (finding this a characteristic feature of the "naive theory of property rights," which "seek[s] to explain the development of exclusive property rights without explicitly modeling social and political institutions. Demsetz's 1967 paper ⋯ is the classic reference for the naive theory of property rights." (emphasis omitted));
  • 65
    • 73949101742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ITAI SEKED, THE POLITICAL INSTITUTION OF PRIVATE PROPERTY 16 (1997) (observing that the flaw is typical of social contract accounts);
    • ITAI SEKED, THE POLITICAL INSTITUTION OF PRIVATE PROPERTY 16 (1997) (observing that the flaw is typical of social contract accounts);
  • 67
    • 73949087966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rose, note 40, at, referring to the argument and noting some of the leading literature
    • See Rose, supra note 40, at 95 (referring to the argument and noting some of the leading literature).
    • supra , pp. 95
  • 68
    • 73949149968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THOMAS HOBBES, LEVIATHAN (Michael Oakeshott ed., Oxford Univ. Press 1960) (1651);
    • See THOMAS HOBBES, LEVIATHAN (Michael Oakeshott ed., Oxford Univ. Press 1960) (1651);
  • 69
    • 73949125608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHN LOCKE, TWO TREATISES OF GOVERNMENT (Peter Laslett ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1960) (1690).
    • JOHN LOCKE, TWO TREATISES OF GOVERNMENT (Peter Laslett ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1960) (1690).
  • 70
    • 73949127783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rose, supra note 40, at 94
    • Rose, supra note 40, at 94.
  • 71
    • 73949136117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 44, ch. 13, at
    • HOBBES, supra note 44, ch. 13, at 81-84.
    • supra , pp. 81-84
    • HOBBES1
  • 72
    • 84868079593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 44, bk. 2, § 27, at
    • LOCKE, supra note 44, bk. 2, § 27, at 306;
    • supra , pp. 306
    • LOCKE1
  • 73
    • 84868056545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. bk. 2, § 28, at 307 ('[T]is the taking any part of what is common, and removing it out of the state Nature leaves it in, which begins the Property ⋯.). Locke's view is reflected in the rule of capture familiar to modern property law, according to which wild animals in their natural condition belong to the first person to kill them, capture them in hand, trap them, or mortally wound them.
    • see also id. bk. 2, § 28, at 307 ("'[T]is the taking any part of what is common, and removing it out of the state Nature leaves it in, which begins the Property ⋯."). Locke's view is reflected in the rule of capture familiar to modern property law, according to which wild animals in their natural condition belong to the first person to kill them, capture them in hand, trap them, or mortally wound them.
  • 74
    • 73949152957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Pierson v. Post, 3 Cai. 175, 179 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1805).
    • See, e.g., Pierson v. Post, 3 Cai. 175, 179 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1805).
  • 75
    • 73949083100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The dissent in Pierson argued for an alternative rule whereby ownership would vest in the first person to pursue with a reasonable prospect of capture, id. at 182, and Locke might well have agreed.
    • The dissent in Pierson argued for an alternative rule whereby ownership would vest in the first person to pursue with a reasonable prospect of capture, id. at 182, and Locke might well have agreed.
  • 76
    • 84868073758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LOCKE, supra note 44, bk. 2, § 30, at 308 ([T]he Hare that any one is Hunting, is thought his who pursues her during the Chase. For being a Beast that is still looked upon as common,⋯ whoever has imploy'd so much labour about any of that kind, as to find and pursue her, has thereby removed her from the state of Nature, wherein she was common, and hath begun a Property.).
    • See LOCKE, supra note 44, bk. 2, § 30, at 308 ("[T]he Hare that any one is Hunting, is thought his who pursues her during the Chase. For being a Beast that is still looked upon as common,⋯ whoever has imploy'd so much labour about any of that kind, as to find and pursue her, has thereby removed her from the state of Nature, wherein she was common, and hath begun a Property.").
  • 77
    • 84868079593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 44, bk. 2, § 17, at
    • LOCKE, supra note 44, bk. 2, § 17, at 297.
    • supra , pp. 297
    • LOCKE1
  • 78
    • 73949134289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOBBES, supra note 44, ch. 15, at 94 (need for a governing authority), ch. 18, at 109-13 (governing authority established by mutual agreement), ch. 18, at 112 (power of governing authority to make and enforce rules);
    • HOBBES, supra note 44, ch. 15, at 94 (need for a governing authority), ch. 18, at 109-13 (governing authority established by mutual agreement), ch. 18, at 112 (power of governing authority to make and enforce rules);
  • 79
    • 84868073759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LOCKE, supra note 44, §§ 18-20, at 297-300 (need for a governing authority), § 211, at 424 (governing authority established by mutual agreement), § 222, at 430 (power of governing authority to make Rules set as Guards and Fences to the Properties of all the Members of the Society).
    • LOCKE, supra note 44, §§ 18-20, at 297-300 (need for a governing authority), § 211, at 424 (governing authority established by mutual agreement), § 222, at 430 (power of governing authority to make "Rules set as Guards and Fences to the Properties of all the Members of the Society").
  • 80
    • 84888494968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 35-36
    • See supra text accompanying notes 35-36.
    • See supra
  • 81
    • 73949143123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz had to assume such a practice or his argument would have lost its anchor. If sharing persisted after severance, incentives to overwork the common stock - a central premise in the logic of Demsetz's account - would be much reduced, replaced by the problem of shirking in the maintenance of the common resources.
    • Demsetz had to assume such a practice or his argument would have lost its anchor. If sharing persisted after severance, incentives to overwork the common stock - a central premise in the logic of Demsetz's account - would be much reduced, replaced by the problem of shirking in the maintenance of the common resources.
  • 82
    • 84868073761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 2, at 490.
    • HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 2, at 490.
  • 83
    • 73949118371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 84
    • 73949136781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert Sugden, Conventions, in 1 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 453, 454.
    • See Robert Sugden, Conventions, in 1 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 453, 454.
  • 85
    • 84868080947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SENED, supra note 42, at 19 (Hume's logical analysis preceded by two centuries similar contemporary game theoretic arguments ⋯.). Sened probably had in mind evolutionary game theory in particular. Evolutionary game theory is an instance of non-cooperative game theory; it focuses on the formation of norms and conventions, meaning patterns of behavior that emerge spontaneously and are self-enforcing. For a quick overview,
    • See SENED, supra note 42, at 19 ("Hume's logical analysis preceded by two centuries similar contemporary game theoretic arguments ⋯."). Sened probably had in mind evolutionary game theory in particular. Evolutionary game theory is an instance of non-cooperative game theory; it focuses on the formation of norms and conventions, meaning patterns of behavior that emerge spontaneously and are self-enforcing. For a quick overview,
  • 86
    • 73949090410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see George J. Mailath, Evolutionary Game Theory, in 2 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 84, 84. As applied to humans, the approach stresses rule-of-thumb behaviors that are updated by a backward-looking learning process, that is, in light of one's own or ohters' recent experience.
    • see George J. Mailath, Evolutionary Game Theory, in 2 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note 12, at 84, 84. As applied to humans, the approach "stresses rule-of-thumb behaviors that are updated by a backward-looking learning process, that is, in light of one's own or ohters' recent experience."
  • 87
    • 84900225389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 18, at, It assumes that individuals are boundedly rational but not quite so cognitively gifted as the people who populate classical game theory
    • BOWLES, supra note 18, at 33. It assumes that individuals are boundedly rational but not quite so cognitively gifted as the people who populate classical game theory.
    • supra , pp. 33
    • BOWLES1
  • 88
    • 73949131725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BOWLES, supra note 18, at 43
    • BOWLES, supra note 18, at 43.
  • 89
    • 84868073756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 2, at 487-88.
    • HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 2, at 487-88.
  • 90
    • 73949144597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 490
    • Id. at 490.
  • 91
    • 73949141515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 489
    • Id. at 489.
  • 92
    • 73949101166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 490
    • Id. at 490.
  • 93
    • 84868050975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. bk. 2, pt. 1, § 12, at 326.
    • Id. bk. 2, pt. 1, § 12, at 326.
  • 94
    • 84868056531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Hanna Kokko et al., From Hawks and Doves to Self-Consistent Games of Territorial Behavior, 167 AM. NATURALIST 901, 901 (2006) (The animal kingdom provides coundess examples of the 'prior-residence effect'⋯.). For a very accessible introductory discussion, see JOHN ALCOCK, ANIMAL BEHAVIOR: AN EVOLUTIONARY APPROACH 264-73 (8th ed. 2005).
    • See generally Hanna Kokko et al., From Hawks and Doves to Self-Consistent Games of Territorial Behavior, 167 AM. NATURALIST 901, 901 (2006) ("The animal kingdom provides coundess examples of the 'prior-residence effect'⋯."). For a very accessible introductory discussion, see JOHN ALCOCK, ANIMAL BEHAVIOR: AN EVOLUTIONARY APPROACH 264-73 (8th ed. 2005).
  • 95
    • 73949112448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHN MAYNARD SMITH, EVOLUTION AND THE THEORY OF GAMES (1982). Much of Maynard Smith's discussion in the book owes to earlier work by him and others dating back several decades.
    • JOHN MAYNARD SMITH, EVOLUTION AND THE THEORY OF GAMES (1982). Much of Maynard Smith's discussion in the book owes to earlier work by him and others dating back several decades.
  • 96
    • 73949154860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11-12
    • Id. at 11-12.
  • 97
    • 73949142306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 22
    • Id. at 22.
  • 98
    • 73949144598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maynard Smith's analysis and conclusions, given his assumptions, appear to be uncontested. For the mathematical details of his treatment, see id. at
    • Maynard Smith's analysis and conclusions, given his assumptions, appear to be uncontested. For the mathematical details of his treatment, see id. at 11-23, 94-96;
  • 99
    • 73949131726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hirsh-leifer, supra note 24, at 20-24
    • Hirsh-leifer, supra note 24, at 20-24.
  • 100
    • 73949110646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chris Meredith, Tit for Tat, http://www.abc.net.au/science/slab/tittat/ story.htm (last visited Sept. 7, 2009).
    • Chris Meredith, Tit for Tat, http://www.abc.net.au/science/slab/tittat/ story.htm (last visited Sept. 7, 2009).
  • 101
    • 84976010866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 63, at, citation and internal quotation marks omitted
    • MAYNARD SMITH, supra note 63, at 23 (citation and internal quotation marks omitted).
    • supra , pp. 23
    • MAYNARD, S.1
  • 102
    • 73949117447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10
    • Id. at 10.
  • 103
    • 73949083543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 23. In a case where possession of a territory does confer an actual advantage in defending it, or where possessors are commonly larger or stronger, the asymmetry is said to be correlated. An uncorrelated strategy can be evolutionarily stable even when there is a correlated strategy also available. Jeffrey Evans Stake, The Property Instinct, 359 PHIL. TRANSACTIONS: BIOLOGICAL SCI. 1763, 1764 (2004, citing Peter Hammerstein, The Role of Asymmetries in Animal Contests, 29 ANIMAL BEHAV. 193 1981, Moreover, a strategy might be correlated early on, because possession is sometimes a defensive advantage, or because stronger individuals generally appear as first occupants, yet become uncorrelated later on, as the mere fact of possession becomes a proxy for advantages that in fact no longer hold. Just as the Bourgeois strategy is an ESS, so is its opposite, if possessor, play Dove, if
    • Id. at 23. In a case where possession of a territory does confer an actual advantage in defending it, or where possessors are commonly larger or stronger, the asymmetry is said to be correlated. "An uncorrelated strategy can be evolutionarily stable even when there is a correlated strategy also available." Jeffrey Evans Stake, The Property "Instinct", 359 PHIL. TRANSACTIONS: BIOLOGICAL SCI. 1763, 1764 (2004) (citing Peter Hammerstein, The Role of Asymmetries in Animal Contests, 29 ANIMAL BEHAV. 193 (1981)). Moreover, a strategy might be correlated early on - because possession is sometimes a defensive advantage, or because stronger individuals generally appear as first occupants - yet become uncorrelated later on, as the mere fact of possession becomes a proxy for advantages that in fact no longer hold. Just as the Bourgeois strategy is an ESS, so is its opposite - if possessor, play Dove, if intruder, play Hawk. This ESS is regarded as "paradoxical" because evolutionary theory would seem to rule it out. Animals behaving in anti-Bourgeois fashion would end up constantly moving around, looking for territory and occupying it, only to be quickly displaced. There would be no time for breeding. Maynard Smith was aware of the problem (and of the case of a type of spider that seems to exhibit the paradoxical strategy).
  • 104
    • 73949156324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MAYNARD SMITH, supra note 63, at 96-97. A resolution of the paradox is suggested by Kokko et al., supra note 62, at 909.
    • See MAYNARD SMITH, supra note 63, at 96-97. A resolution of the paradox is suggested by Kokko et al., supra note 62, at 909.
  • 105
    • 84868073743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maynard Smith's model shows that the Bourgeois strategy can evolve, not that it invariably will. See Hirshleifer, supra note 24, at 23 (asserting that the development of the strategy depends on individuals able to distinguish between owner and interloper situations, and ⋯ able to execute the appropriate behavioral maneuvers of both Hawk and Dove). Still, Maynard Smith's analysis shows that respect for ownership is a possible evolutionary emergence that need not call upon any force other than private advantage. ⋯ On the human level, a corresponding environmental situation might be expected to lead to a 'social ethic' supporting a system of property rights.
    • Maynard Smith's model shows that the Bourgeois strategy can evolve, not that it invariably will. See Hirshleifer, supra note 24, at 23 (asserting that the development of the strategy depends on individuals "able to distinguish between owner and interloper situations, and ⋯ able to execute the appropriate behavioral maneuvers of both Hawk and Dove"). Still, Maynard Smith's analysis "shows that respect for ownership is a possible evolutionary emergence that need not call upon any force other than private advantage. ⋯ On the human level, a corresponding environmental situation might be expected to lead to a 'social ethic' supporting a system of property rights."
  • 106
    • 73949130321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (citation omitted).
    • Id. (citation omitted).
  • 107
    • 73949094710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBERT SUGDEN, THE ECONOMICS OF RIGHTS, CO-OPERATION AND WELFARE (Palgrave Macmillan 2004) (1986). The second edition is virtually the same as the first, save for a new Introduction and Afterword.
    • ROBERT SUGDEN, THE ECONOMICS OF RIGHTS, CO-OPERATION AND WELFARE (Palgrave Macmillan 2004) (1986). The second edition is virtually the same as the first, save for a new Introduction and Afterword.
  • 111
    • 73949102882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Jack Hirshleifer, Privacy: Its Origin, Function, and Future, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 649, 657 (1980) (suggesting that evolution may have led to a hard-wired defensive attitude regarding possessions and a deferential attitude regarding the possessions of others);
    • see Jack Hirshleifer, Privacy: Its Origin, Function, and Future, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 649, 657 (1980) (suggesting that evolution may have led to a "hard-wired" defensive attitude regarding possessions and a deferential attitude regarding the possessions of others);
  • 112
    • 73949153913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stake, supra note 70, at 1763 (arguing that humans may share a hard-wired property instinct). Both Hirshleifer and Stake discuss the Maynard Smith model and consider its relevance to the development of property and other rights. A commentary on Hirshleifer also briefly discusses respect for possession from the standpoint of evolutionary theory.
    • Stake, supra note 70, at 1763 (arguing that humans may share a "hard-wired" property "instinct"). Both Hirshleifer and Stake discuss the Maynard Smith model and consider its relevance to the development of property and other rights. A commentary on Hirshleifer also briefly discusses respect for possession from the standpoint of evolutionary theory.
  • 113
    • 0041362171 scopus 로고
    • A Taste far Privacy? Evolution and the Emergence of a Naturalistic Ethic, 9
    • See
    • See Richard A. Epstein, A Taste far Privacy? Evolution and the Emergence of a Naturalistic Ethic, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 665, 672-73 (1980).
    • (1980) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.665 , pp. 672-673
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 114
    • 73949110961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sugden considered several other games as well (the war-of-attrition game - also considered by Maynard Smith - the division game, and games of commitment). I omit that part of his discussion because he found the other games led to results matching those of the Hawk-Dove-Bourgeois game. For the curious, the relevant pages are SUGDEN, supra note 72, at 65-86.
    • Sugden considered several other games as well (the war-of-attrition game - also considered by Maynard Smith - the division game, and games of commitment). I omit that part of his discussion because he found the other games led to results matching those of the Hawk-Dove-Bourgeois game. For the curious, the relevant pages are SUGDEN, supra note 72, at 65-86.
  • 115
    • 34447527897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Several commentators have argued that deference to possessors might have evolved because of an endowment effect, according to which an individual puts a systematically higher value on something possessed than on an opportunity to possess the very same thing. See Herbert Gintis, The Evolution of Private Property, 64 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 1, passim (2007);
    • Several commentators have argued that deference to possessors might have evolved because of an endowment effect, according to which an individual puts a systematically higher value on something possessed than on an opportunity to possess the very same thing. See Herbert Gintis, The Evolution of Private Property, 64 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 1, passim (2007);
  • 116
    • 73949160810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stake, supra note 70, at 1767. The argument is plausible, but so is its opposite. Rather than generating the convention of deference to possessors, the endowment effect could just as well owe to it, in that deference to possession adds to the value of possession.
    • Stake, supra note 70, at 1767. The argument is plausible, but so is its opposite. Rather than generating the convention of deference to possessors, the endowment effect could just as well owe to it, in that deference to possession adds to the value of possession.
  • 117
    • 84868050965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SUGDEN, supra note 72, at 97 (discussing HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt 2, § 3, at 504 n.1: As property forms a relation betwixt a person and an object, 'tis natural to found it on some preceding relation ⋯.). Hume extended the convention of possession to property acquired by prescription, accession, and succession.
    • SUGDEN, supra note 72, at 97 (discussing HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt 2, § 3, at 504 n.1: "As property forms a relation betwixt a person and an object, 'tis natural to found it on some preceding relation ⋯."). Hume extended the convention of possession to property acquired by prescription, accession, and succession.
  • 118
    • 84868050966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. bk. 3, pt. 2, § 3, at 509-13.
    • See id. bk. 3, pt. 2, § 3, at 509-13.
  • 119
    • 73949088262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In this connection, it is interesting to recall that the majority decision in Pierson v. Post, discussed supra note 47, opted for first capture of a wild animal, as opposed to the dissent's approach of first pursuit, as the act needed to give rise to ownership. The court selected capture for the sake of certainty, noting that the alternative of first pursuit, given its ambiguity, would prove a fertile source of quarrels and litigation. 3 Cai. 175, 179 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1805).
    • In this connection, it is interesting to recall that the majority decision in Pierson v. Post, discussed supra note 47, opted for first capture of a wild animal, as opposed to the dissent's approach of first pursuit, as the act needed to give rise to ownership. The court selected capture "for the sake of certainty," noting that the alternative of first pursuit, given its ambiguity, "would prove a fertile source of quarrels and litigation." 3 Cai. 175, 179 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1805).
  • 120
    • 73949114875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SUGDEN, supra note 72, at 100-01.
    • See SUGDEN, supra note 72, at 100-01.
  • 121
    • 73949118642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 107;
    • Id. at 107;
  • 122
    • 73049085297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 73 and accompanying text
    • see also supra note 73 and accompanying text.
    • see also supra
  • 123
    • 84888494968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 65-66
    • See supra text accompanying notes 65-66.
    • See supra
  • 124
    • 84976010866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 63, at
    • MAYNARD SMITH, supra note 63, at 95.
    • supra , pp. 95
    • MAYNARD, S.1
  • 125
    • 58149367837 scopus 로고
    • The Logic of Divisively Asymmetric Contests: Respect for Ownership and the Desperado Effect, 35
    • See
    • See Alan Grafen, The Logic of Divisively Asymmetric Contests: Respect for Ownership and the Desperado Effect, 35 ANIMAL BEHAV. 462, 463 (1987);
    • (1987) ANIMAL BEHAV , vol.462 , pp. 463
    • Grafen, A.1
  • 126
    • 73949102881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also MAYNARD SMITH, supra note 63, at 95 (stating that when v > c, it is worth risking injury to gain the resource and ownership will be ignored).
    • see also MAYNARD SMITH, supra note 63, at 95 (stating that when v > c, "it is worth risking injury to gain the resource" and "ownership will be ignored").
  • 127
    • 84868073740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 8, at 539.
    • HUME, supra note 10, bk. 3, pt. 2, § 8, at 539.
  • 128
    • 73949084750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is some suggestion in the literature that third-party enforcement might develop spontaneously under certain conditions, thanks to the appearance of punishers who keep defectors in line. Models leading to this result can be found in BOWLES, supra note 18, at 381-90, and Christoph Hauert et al.,
    • There is some suggestion in the literature that third-party enforcement might develop spontaneously under certain conditions, thanks to the appearance of punishers who keep defectors in line. Models leading to this result can be found in BOWLES, supra note 18, at 381-90, and Christoph Hauert et al.,
  • 130
    • 73949091034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 76-77. It is worth noting that while a convention of deference to possessors can account for only simple property rules, still the simple rules can amount to the rights to exclude, use, and transfer, which are usually regarded as the core elements of property. If there is a practice of deferring to possessors, that is equivalent to saying that possessors are empowered to exclude, to use what they possess, and to transfer their rights (the transferee becomes the new possessor and hence enjoys deference). All of this follows especially if possession earns deference even when actual constant physical possession is not required, on which see infra notes 92-93 and accompanying text
    • See supra text accompanying notes 76-77. It is worth noting that while a convention of deference to possessors can account for only simple property rules, still the simple rules can amount to the rights to exclude, use, and transfer, which are usually regarded as the core elements of property. If there is a practice of deferring to possessors, that is equivalent to saying that possessors are empowered to exclude, to use what they possess, and to transfer their rights (the transferee becomes the new possessor and hence enjoys deference). All of this follows especially if possession earns deference even when actual constant physical possession is not required, on which see infra notes 92-93 and accompanying text
  • 131
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 6 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 6 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 132
    • 73949122234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Yet it has been largely ignored in the legal literature on the evolution of property rights, seldom earning more than a nod, if that. The few exceptions to that generalization have been noted in our discussion
    • Yet it has been largely ignored in the legal literature on the evolution of property rights, seldom earning more than a nod, if that. The few exceptions to that generalization have been noted in our discussion.
  • 133
    • 73949155112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The abbreviation B.P., commonly used in evolutionary studies, refers to before present, where present is taken to be the year 1950. On the emergence of Homo, see, for example, EDWARD O. WILSON, SOCIOBIOLOGY: THE NEW SYNTHESIS 564-65 (25th anniv. ed. 2000).
    • The abbreviation B.P., commonly used in evolutionary studies, refers to "before present," where "present" is taken to be the year 1950. On the emergence of Homo, see, for example, EDWARD O. WILSON, SOCIOBIOLOGY: THE NEW SYNTHESIS 564-65 (25th anniv. ed. 2000).
  • 135
    • 34248997229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Synthesis in Moral Psychology, 316
    • Jonathan Haidt et al., The New Synthesis in Moral Psychology, 316 SCI. 998 (2007).
    • (2007) SCI , vol.998
    • Haidt, J.1
  • 136
    • 73949129701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, WILSON, supra note 88, at 564-69
    • See, e.g., WILSON, supra note 88, at 564-69.
  • 137
    • 73949128498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koichi Kitanishi, Food Sharing Among the Aka Hunter-Gatherers in Northeastern Congo, 25 AFR. STUDY MONOGRAPHS SUPPLEMENT 3, 5 (1998), states that land and its resources were communally owned, whereas tools, weapon[s] and procured food were owned individually in hunter-gatherer societies.
    • Koichi Kitanishi, Food Sharing Among the Aka Hunter-Gatherers in Northeastern Congo, 25 AFR. STUDY MONOGRAPHS SUPPLEMENT 3, 5 (1998), states that "land and its resources were communally owned, whereas tools, weapon[s] and procured food were owned individually in hunter-gatherer societies."
  • 138
    • 73949122232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (citation omitted). He adds, however, that ownership of food carried with it an obligation to share by way of obligatory gifts.
    • Id. (citation omitted). He adds, however, that "ownership" of food carried with it an obligation to share by way of obligatory gifts.
  • 139
    • 73949096759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 22-24.
    • See id. at 22-24.
  • 140
    • 73949150339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BOWLES, supra note 18, at 389-90. Recall Demsetz's mention of Indians marking their hunting territories (which were in fixed locations).
    • See BOWLES, supra note 18, at 389-90. Recall Demsetz's mention of Indians marking their hunting territories (which were in fixed locations).
  • 141
    • 73949083099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 35. Elsewhere he notes that private rights in hunting territories would not be worthwhile in the case of grazing animals that roam over large tracts of land. Demsetz, supra note 1, at 353.
    • See supra text accompanying note 35. Elsewhere he notes that private rights in hunting territories would not be worthwhile in the case of grazing animals that roam over large tracts of land. Demsetz, supra note 1, at 353.
  • 142
    • 73949093012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BOWLES, supra note 18, at 388-90. This constructive possession effect could have reached beyond land to personal items, such as farming tools or crops stored on the farm plot.
    • See BOWLES, supra note 18, at 388-90. This "constructive possession" effect could have reached beyond land to personal items, such as farming tools or crops stored on the farm plot.
  • 143
    • 73949154858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 35. My reference to permanent and transient property echoes the words of another classic figure in the literature on the development of property rights.
    • See supra text accompanying note 35. My reference to "permanent" and "transient" property echoes the words of another classic figure in the literature on the development of property rights.
  • 144
    • 84868056518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *3-7. Blackstone used those adjectives in stating his view of how property developed over time: First there was an open commons; a commoner who took from it acquired a kind of transient property as to which the right of possession continued for the same time only that the act of possession lasted.
    • *3-7. Blackstone used those adjectives in stating his view of how property developed over time: First there was an open commons; a commoner who took from it acquired "a kind of transient property" as to which the "right of possession continued for the same time only that the act of possession lasted."
  • 145
    • 84868080927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *3. Then, later, there developed permanent rights that did not depend on constant physical possession.
    • *3. Then, later, there developed "permanent" rights that did not depend on constant physical possession.
  • 146
    • 84868080928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *4. These permanent rights were first in personal items such as food and clothing. Eventually, though, land came to be treated in the same fashion, coincident with the rise of agriculture.
    • *4. These permanent rights were first in personal items such as food and clothing. Eventually, though, land came to be treated in the same fashion, coincident with the rise of agriculture.
  • 147
    • 84868080923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *5-7. Finally, the government entered the picture to secure rights.
    • *5-7. Finally, the government entered the picture to secure rights.
  • 148
    • 84868050958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *8. So far as I am concerned, Blackstone's account was extraordinarily prescient, anticipating modern accounts (and not just mine) of the evolution of property rights by more than two hundred years.
    • *8. So far as I am concerned, Blackstone's account was extraordinarily prescient, anticipating modern accounts (and not just mine) of the evolution of property rights by more than two hundred years.
  • 149
    • 73949116211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WILSON, supra note 88, at 569
    • WILSON, supra note 88, at 569.
  • 150
    • 84888494968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 42-43
    • See supra text accompanying notes 42-43.
    • See supra
  • 151
    • 0001683669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert L. Carneiro, A Theory of the Origin of the State, 169 SCI. 733 (1970) (elaborating on circumscription theory as an explanation for the origin of a state).
    • See Robert L. Carneiro, A Theory of the Origin of the State, 169 SCI. 733 (1970) (elaborating on circumscription theory as an explanation for the origin of a state).
  • 152
    • 73949095356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Kingston-upon-Hull v. Horner, 98 Eng. Rep. 807, 815 (1774) (Lord Mansfield observing: Possession is very strong; rather more than nine points of the law.);
    • See, e.g., Kingston-upon-Hull v. Horner, 98 Eng. Rep. 807, 815 (1774) (Lord Mansfield observing: "Possession is very strong; rather more than nine points of the law.");
  • 153
    • 0041862980 scopus 로고
    • Possession as the Root of Title, 13
    • Richard A. Epstein, Possession as the Root of Title, 13 GA. L. REV. 1221 (1979);
    • (1979) GA. L. REV , vol.1221
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 154
    • 84867552776 scopus 로고
    • Possession as the Origin of Property, 52
    • Carol M. Rose, Possession as the Origin of Property, 52 U. CHI. L. REV. 73 (1985).
    • (1985) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.73
    • Rose, C.M.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.