-
4
-
-
72049132252
-
-
Southeast Asia mainly consists of the countries that are now called Myanmar (Burma), Malaysia, Thailand, Laos, Cambodia, Vietnam, Indonesia and the Philippines
-
Southeast Asia mainly consists of the countries that are now called Myanmar (Burma), Malaysia, Thailand, Laos, Cambodia, Vietnam, Indonesia and the Philippines.
-
-
-
-
9
-
-
29744465984
-
Food crops and arable lands, Java 1815-1942
-
Detailed statistics have been collected (on an annual basis, and by unit of administration) on population, arable lands and (rice) harvests for nineteenth-century Java. (Amsterdam). The early-nineteenth-century figures are not as good as the data for the early twentieth century, as they are almost invariably too low. This was partly because data-gathering was linked to taxation, which made underreporting attractive, and partly because people, land and crops in out-of-the-way areas escaped notice. However, if one calculates yields per hectare or consumption per capita, the underestimates in numerator and denominator may be expected to cancel each other out. To date, figures for other Southeast Asian areas for the early nineteenth century have not yet been published. However, it may be assumed that production per hectare, for instance in the Red River Delta, northern Vietnam, was of the same order of magnitude as that in Java, while lower rates obtained in much of Southeast Asia
-
Detailed statistics have been collected (on an annual basis, and by unit of administration) on population, arable lands and (rice) harvests for nineteenth-century Java (see Peter Boomgaard and Jan Luiten van Zanden, Food crops and arable lands, Java 1815-1942, Changing economy in Indonesia, 10 (Amsterdam, 1990)). The early-nineteenth-century figures are not as good as the data for the early twentieth century, as they are almost invariably too low. This was partly because data-gathering was linked to taxation, which made underreporting attractive, and partly because people, land and crops in out-of-the-way areas escaped notice. However, if one calculates yields per hectare or consumption per capita, the underestimates in numerator and denominator may be expected to cancel each other out. To date, figures for other Southeast Asian areas for the early nineteenth century have not yet been published. However, it may be assumed that production per hectare, for instance in the Red River Delta, northern Vietnam, was of the same order of magnitude as that in Java, while lower rates obtained in much of Southeast Asia.
-
(1990)
Changing Economy in Indonesia
, pp. 10
-
-
Boomgaard, P.1
Zanden Van, J.L.2
-
10
-
-
72049095480
-
Production technology and comparative advantage in rice agriculture in Southeast Asia since 1870
-
Broadly similar conclusions can be drawn from, paper presented at. Honolulu, Hawai'i
-
Broadly similar conclusions can be drawn from Pierre van der Eng, 'Production technology and comparative advantage in rice agriculture in Southeast Asia since 1870', paper presented at the Association for Asian Studies Conference, Honolulu, Hawai'i, 1996, 23.
-
(1996)
The Association for Asian Studies Conference
, vol.23
-
-
Van Der Eng, P.1
-
14
-
-
72049095761
-
-
Boomgaard, Children, 111. In 1815 and 1850 almost 7 per cent of Java's population lived in towns of 20,000 inhabitants and over. The drop in the urbanization rate between 1850 and 1890 was partly caused by the fact that the so-called 'cultivation system' created jobs in the countryside more than in the cities. But even 7 per cent is very low in comparison with the more developed regions of Eurasia
-
Boomgaard, Children, 111. In 1815 and 1850 almost 7 per cent of Java's population lived in towns of 20,000 inhabitants and over. The drop in the urbanization rate between 1850 and 1890 was partly caused by the fact that the so-called 'cultivation system' created jobs in the countryside more than in the cities. But even 7 per cent is very low in comparison with the more developed regions of Eurasia.
-
-
-
-
15
-
-
37549057625
-
Technologies of a trading empire: Dutch introduction of water- and windmills in early modern Asia, 1650s-1800
-
Peter Boomgaard, 'Technologies of a trading empire: Dutch introduction of water- and windmills in early modern Asia, 1650s-1800', History and Technology 24:1 (2008), 43-60.
-
(2008)
History and Technology
, vol.24
, Issue.1
, pp. 43-60
-
-
Boomgaard, P.1
-
17
-
-
0012452801
-
Why work for wages? Free labour in Java, 1600-1900
-
But see for instance Reid, Southeast Asia, vol.I, 90-136, and (for Java)
-
But see for instance Reid, Southeast Asia, vol.I, 90-136, and (for Java) Peter Boomgaard, 'Why work for wages? Free labour in Java, 1600-1900', Economic and Social History in the Netherlands 2 (1990), 37-56.
-
(1990)
Economic and Social History in the Netherlands
, vol.2
, pp. 37-56
-
-
Boomgaard, P.1
-
18
-
-
33645882884
-
Wage labour in Southeast Asia since 1840: Globalisation
-
On labour around and after 1850 (Basingstoke)
-
On labour around and after 1850, see Amarjit Kaur, Wage labour in Southeast Asia since 1840: Globalisation, the international division of labour, and labour transformations (Basingstoke, 2004).
-
(2004)
The International Division of Labour, and Labour Transformations
-
-
Kaur, A.1
-
19
-
-
0039865277
-
-
There are three more or less recent collections on slavery that are partly or entirely dedicated to Southeast Asia: See Anthony Reid ed. (St Lucia)
-
There are three more or less recent collections on slavery that are partly or entirely dedicated to Southeast Asia: See Anthony Reid ed., Slavery, bondage and dependency in Southeast Asia (St Lucia, 1983);
-
(1983)
Slavery, Bondage and Dependency in Southeast Asia
-
-
-
23
-
-
84905893161
-
The causes of slavery or serfdom: A hypothesis
-
a revised version of his thesis is given by, see also the article by Gareth Austin in this issue
-
a revised version of his thesis is given by E. D. Domar, 'The causes of slavery or serfdom: A hypothesis', Journal of Economic History 30 (1970), 18-32; see also the article by Gareth Austin in this issue.
-
(1970)
Journal of Economic History
, vol.30
, pp. 18-32
-
-
Domar, E.D.1
-
24
-
-
72049086595
-
-
157, 180-3, 300, 303, 359, 410
-
Lieberman, Strange parallels, 95, 113, 157, 180-3, 300, 303, 359, 410;
-
Strange Parallels
, vol.95
, pp. 113
-
-
Lieberman1
-
26
-
-
4344706348
-
The coevolution of property rights regimes for land, man, and forests in Thailand, 1790-1990
-
John F. Richards ed. (Oakland)
-
David Feeny, 'The coevolution of property rights regimes for land, man, and forests in Thailand, 1790-1990', in John F. Richards ed., Land, property, and the environment (Oakland, 2002), 188-193
-
(2002)
Land, Property, and the Environment
, pp. 188-193
-
-
Feeny, D.1
-
32
-
-
0013082971
-
Strange company: Chinese settlers
-
(Dordrecht/Riverton), 52-5
-
Leonard Blusse, Strange company: Chinese settlers, mestizo women and the Dutch in VOC Batavia (Dordrecht/Riverton, 1986), 26-7, 52-5;
-
(1986)
Mestizo Women and the Dutch in VOC Batavia
, pp. 26-27
-
-
Blusse, L.1
-
35
-
-
72049094981
-
-
particularly
-
and Feeny, 'The coevolution', particularly pp. 189-193.
-
The Coevolution
, pp. 189-193
-
-
Feeny1
-
41
-
-
72049094981
-
-
For details see
-
For details see Feeny, 'The coevolution', 191.
-
The Coevolution
, pp. 191
-
-
Feeny1
-
47
-
-
72049113479
-
The making of a myth: John Leddy Phelan and the "hispani- zation" of land tenure in the Philippines
-
Glenn Anthony May, 'The making of a myth: John Leddy Phelan and the "hispani-zation" of land tenure in the Philippines', Philippine Studies 52:3 (2004), 275-307.
-
(2004)
Philippine Studies
, vol.52
, Issue.3
, pp. 275-307
-
-
May, G.A.1
-
49
-
-
72049112466
-
-
At a much earlier date (in the sixteenth century), the king of Spain had declared himself owner of all the lands in the Philippines by right of conquest. (Quezon City). Based on the same right the VOC regarded itself as the owner of Batavia and its environs (Java) after 1619
-
At a much earlier date (in the sixteenth century), the king of Spain had declared himself owner of all the lands in the Philippines by right of conquest (O. D. Corpuz, An economic history of the Philippines (Quezon City, 1997), 27). Based on the same right the VOC regarded itself as the owner of Batavia and its environs (Java) after 1619.
-
(1997)
An Economic History of the Philippines
, pp. 27
-
-
Corpuz, O.D.1
-
50
-
-
72049103066
-
-
This view was pioneered by the Dutch scholar Cornelis van Vollenhoven, founder of what is often called the Adat Law School. The term he used for such village rights was beschikkingsrecht (C. van Vollenhoven, De Indonesiër en zijn grond (Leiden, 1919), 8). This has been translated variously as 'rights of avail' and 'rights of disposal', but nowadays the term 'residual rights' appears to be used by most scholars
-
This view was pioneered by the Dutch scholar Cornelis van Vollenhoven, founder of what is often called the Adat Law School. The term he used for such village rights was beschikkingsrecht (C. van Vollenhoven, De Indonesiër en zijn grond (Leiden, 1919), 8). This has been translated variously as 'rights of avail' and 'rights of disposal', but nowadays the term 'residual rights' appears to be used by most scholars.
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
0003371701
-
Economic history of early Southeast Asia
-
For details see, Nicholas Tarling ed. (Cambridge)
-
For details see Kenneth R. Hall, 'Economic history of early Southeast Asia', in Nicholas Tarling ed., The Cambridge history of Southeast Asia, vol.1: From early times to circa 1500 (Cambridge, 1999), 268;
-
(1999)
The Cambridge History of Southeast Asia, Vol.1 : From Early Times to Circa 1500
, pp. 268
-
-
Hall, K.R.1
-
62
-
-
72049107088
-
Origins of the Burma rice boom, 1850-1880
-
Willem van Schendel, 'Origins of the Burma rice boom, 1850-1880', Journal of Comtemporary Asia 17:4 (1987), 461.
-
(1987)
Journal of Comtemporary Asia
, vol.17
, Issue.4
, pp. 461
-
-
Van Schendel, W.1
-
64
-
-
72049121368
-
-
In the Philippines, conversion of the local population to Catholicism had been one of the most important aims of the Spanish conquest, and the large friar estates should be seen in that light
-
In the Philippines, conversion of the local population to Catholicism had been one of the most important aims of the Spanish conquest, and the large friar estates should be seen in that light.
-
-
-
-
66
-
-
84972073743
-
Rice cultivation in Thailand: The development of an export economy by indigenous capital and labor
-
David B. Johnston, 'Rice cultivation in Thailand: The development of an export economy by indigenous capital and labor', Modern Asian Studies 15:1 (1981);
-
(1981)
Modern Asian Studies
, vol.15
, pp. 1
-
-
Johnston, D.B.1
-
69
-
-
72049099527
-
-
In the literature on landed tenure in Europe, 'customary tenure' usually has a different meaning
-
In the literature on landed tenure in Europe, 'customary tenure' usually has a different meaning.
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
72049117548
-
-
An example of this line of reasoning can be found in Toon van Meijl and Franz von Benda-Beckmann eds., Property rights and economic development: Land and natural resources in Southeast Asia and Oceania (London and New York, 1999)
-
An example of this line of reasoning can be found in Toon van Meijl and Franz von Benda-Beckmann eds., Property rights and economic development: Land and natural resources in Southeast Asia and Oceania (London and New York, 1999).
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
72049094182
-
-
In some areas of Borneo the longhouse was the basic community type, rather than any village. In the regions discussed here, land was still easily available and the sale of land was practically unknown until far into the twentieth century
-
In some areas of Borneo the longhouse was the basic community type, rather than any village. In the regions discussed here, land was still easily available and the sale of land was practically unknown until far into the twentieth century.
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
72049116468
-
-
This rule did not apply to the so-called 'private estates' (Particuliere Landerijen), mainly to be found around Batavia, where land had been given out to foreigners in full allodial property before about 1820, and to the 'principalities' (Vorstenlanden) of Central Java, where European entrepreneurs could lease land from the Javanese princes and the nobility
-
This rule did not apply to the so-called 'private estates' (Particuliere Landerijen), mainly to be found around Batavia, where land had been given out to foreigners in full allodial property before about 1820, and to the 'principalities' (Vorstenlanden) of Central Java, where European entrepreneurs could lease land from the Javanese princes and the nobility.
-
-
-
-
81
-
-
72049129853
-
The development of property rights to land in the Philippines, 1850-1930
-
Van Meijl and Von Benda-Beckmann
-
Willem G. Wolters, 'The development of property rights to land in the Philippines, 1850-1930', in Van Meijl and Von Benda-Beckmann, Property rights, 122
-
Property Rights
, pp. 122
-
-
Wolters, W.G.1
-
86
-
-
33845993239
-
Social and economic patterns of landlord-tenant relationships in the Chao Phraya delta, Thailand: An historical perspective
-
Francois Molle, 'Social and economic patterns of landlord-tenant relationships in the Chao Phraya delta, Thailand: An historical perspective', Journal of Southeast Asian Studies 33:3 (2002), 517-543
-
(2002)
Journal of Southeast Asian Studies
, vol.33
, Issue.3
, pp. 517-543
-
-
Molle, F.1
-
89
-
-
72049088423
-
-
A similar point, regarding urban land rights, is made by Hernando de Soto in The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else (New York, 2000)
-
A similar point, regarding urban land rights, is made by Hernando de Soto in The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else (New York, 2000).
-
-
-
-
90
-
-
84974220122
-
Buitenzorg in 1805: The role of money and credit in a colonial frontier society
-
This section is largely based on
-
This section is largely based on Peter Boomgaard, 'Buitenzorg in 1805: The role of money and credit in a colonial frontier society', Modern Asian Studies 20:1 (1986), 33-58
-
(1986)
Modern Asian Studies
, vol.20
, Issue.1
, pp. 33-58
-
-
Boomgaard, P.1
-
91
-
-
33847591301
-
Geld, Krediet, rente en Europeanen in Zuid- en Zuidoost-Azie in de ze-ventiende eeuw
-
C. A. Davids, W. Fritschy and L. A. van der Valk eds. (Amsterdam)
-
and 'Geld, krediet, rente en Europeanen in Zuid- en Zuidoost-Azie in de ze-ventiende eeuw', in C. A. Davids, W. Fritschy and L. A. van der Valk eds., Kapitaal, ondernemerschap en beleid: Studies over economie en politiek in Nederland, Europa en Azië van 1500 tot heden (Amsterdam, 1996), 483-510;
-
(1996)
Kapitaal, Ondernemerschap en Beleid: Studies over Economie en Politiek in Nederland, Europa en Azië Van 1500 Tot Heden
, pp. 483-510
-
-
-
93
-
-
79955717761
-
"Following the debt": Credit and debt in Southeast Asian legal theory and practice,1400-1800
-
David Henley and Peter Boomgaard eds. (Singapore)
-
and Peter Boomgaard, "'Following the debt": Credit and debt in Southeast Asian legal theory and practice, 1400-1800', in David Henley and Peter Boomgaard eds., Credit and debt in Indonesia, 860-1930: From peonage to pawnshop, from kongsi to cooperative (Singapore, 2008), 62-80.
-
(2008)
Credit and Debt in Indonesia, 860-1930: From Peonage to Pawnshop, from Kongsi to Cooperative
, pp. 62-80
-
-
Boomgaard, P.1
-
95
-
-
72049097829
-
Credit and the colonial state: The reform of capital markets on Java 1900-1930
-
Henley and Boomgaard, on pawnshop rates in the Netherlands Indies around
-
see also Jan Luiten van Zanden, 'Credit and the colonial state: The reform of capital markets on Java, 1900-1930', in Henley and Boomgaard, Credit and debt, 163-180, on pawnshop rates in the Netherlands Indies around 1900.
-
(1900)
Credit and Debt
, pp. 163-180
-
-
Van Zanden, J.L.1
-
96
-
-
84895042042
-
Credit and debt in Indonesian history: An introduction
-
This analysis is partly inspired by, Henley and Boomgaard
-
This analysis is partly inspired by David Henley, 'Credit and debt in Indonesian history: An introduction,' in Henley and Boomgaard, Credit and debt, 1-41.
-
Credit and Debt
, pp. 1-41
-
-
Henley, D.1
-
97
-
-
72049094980
-
-
Reid, Southeast Asia, vol.II, 109. This feature seems to be at odds with the above-mentioned display of wealth, but while the latter was practised mainly by royalty and nobles, the former applied to merchants and the peasantry. However, in case of war-a situation in which Southeast Asians often found themselves-even the ruling classes would resort to hoarding
-
Reid, Southeast Asia, vol.II, 109. This feature seems to be at odds with the above-mentioned display of wealth, but while the latter was practised mainly by royalty and nobles, the former applied to merchants and the peasantry. However, in case of war-a situation in which Southeast Asians often found themselves-even the ruling classes would resort to hoarding.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
85056006549
-
-
Regarding trust in Indonesia (New York)
-
Regarding trust in Indonesia, see Alice G. Dewey, Peasant marketing in Java (New York, 1962);
-
(1962)
Peasant Marketing in Java
-
-
Dewey, A.G.1
-
104
-
-
0344256714
-
Restraints on the development of merchant 'capitalism' in Southeast Asia before c.1800
-
See for instance. Anthony Reid ed., (Ithaca and London)
-
See for instance Jeyamalar Kathirithamby-Wells, 'Restraints on the development of merchant 'capitalism' in Southeast Asia before c. 1800', in Anthony Reid ed., Southeast Asia in the early modern era: Trade, power, and belief (Ithaca and London, 1993), 123-148
-
(1993)
Southeast Asia in the Early Modern Era: Trade, Power, and Belief
, pp. 123-148
-
-
Kathirithamby-Wells, J.1
-
107
-
-
72049096018
-
-
As there were no prisons, there were no jail sentences
-
As there were no prisons, there were no jail sentences.
-
-
-
-
110
-
-
72049101378
-
-
In the bridewealth areas the son-in-law had often to work for his father-in-law if his family was not sufficiently rich to pay the going brideprice
-
In the bridewealth areas the son-in-law had often to work for his father-in-law if his family was not sufficiently rich to pay the going brideprice.
-
-
-
|