-
2
-
-
84882321247
-
-
ed. Jonathan H. Adler (Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Insti tute
-
For my own contribution to this literature, see The Costs of Kyoto: Climate Change Policy and Its Implications, ed. Jonathan H. Adler (Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Insti tute, 1997). The present essay represents a substantial evolution of my views on climate change policy.
-
(1997)
The Costs of Kyoto: Climate Change Policy and Its Implications
-
-
-
3
-
-
84878146280
-
-
Jonathan H. Adler, ed. Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Institute
-
"No regrets" policies are policy measures that may reduce the risks posed by climate change but that could be justified independent of the risks posed by climate change. For examples of such policies, see Jonathan H. Adler, ed., Greenhouse Policy Without Regrets: A Free Market Approach to the Uncertain Risks of Climate Change (Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Institute, 2000).
-
(2000)
Greenhouse Policy Without Regrets: A Free Market Approach to the Uncertain Risks of Climate Change
-
-
-
4
-
-
77749242204
-
What to Do about Climate Change
-
Washington, DC: Cato Institute, February 5, 2008); and Bjørn Lomborg, Cool It: The Skeptical Environmentalist?s Guide to Global Warming (New York: Alfred A. Knopf
-
See, for example, Indur M. Goklany, "What to Do about Climate Change," Policy Analy sis, no. 609 (Washington, DC: Cato Institute, February 5, 2008); and Bjørn Lomborg, Cool It: The Skeptical Environmentalist?s Guide to Global Warming (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 2007).
-
(2007)
Policy Analy Sis
, Issue.609
-
-
Indur, M.1
Goklany2
-
6
-
-
84860303180
-
-
Jonathan H. Adler, ed. Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Insti tute
-
Jonathan H. Adler, ed., Ecology, Liberty, and Property: A Free Market Environmental Reader (Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Insti tute, 2000);
-
(2000)
Ecology, Liberty, and Property: A Free Market Environmental Reader
-
-
-
7
-
-
84933494480
-
A Free-Market Environmental Program
-
and Fred L. Smith, Jr., "A Free-Market Environmental Program," Cato Journal 11, no. 3 (1992): 457-75.
-
(1992)
Cato Journal
, vol.11
, Issue.3
, pp. 457-75
-
-
Fred, L.1
Smith, Jr.2
-
10
-
-
0003359245
-
The Firm, the Market, and the Law
-
Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
It is worth noting that Nobel laureate economist Ronald H. Coase, whose work on social costs has been very influential in environmental law and economics, takes a slightly differ ent view, arguing that the mere existence of externalities, in and of itself, does not demon strate any failure at all, as many externalities are too insignificant to address profitably. As Coase explained, the existence of "externalities" does not imply that there is a prima facie case for governmental intervention, if by this statement is meant that, when we find "externalities," there is a presumption that governmental intervention (taxation or regulation) is called for rather than the other courses of action which could be taken (including inaction, the abandonment of earlier governmental action, or the facilitating of market transactions). The fact that governmental intervention also has its costs makes it very likely that most "externalities" should be allowed to continue if the value of prodion is to be maximized. The ubiquitous nature of "externalities" suggests to me that there is a prima facie case against intervention. R. H. Coase, "The Firm, the Market, and the Law," in Coase, The Firm, the Market, and the Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988), 24, 26.
-
(1988)
Coase, the Firm, the Market, and the Law
, vol.24
, pp. 26
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
11
-
-
0000843939
-
Externality
-
See also James M. Buchanan and William Craig Stubblebine, "Externality," Economica 29 (1962): 371-84 (noting that externalities are only relevant in a limited set of circumstances).
-
(1962)
Economica
, vol.29
, pp. 371-84
-
-
Buchanan, J.M.1
Craig Stubblebine, W.2
-
12
-
-
70349211665
-
Economics, Ethics, and Ecology
-
ed. Roger Meiners and Bruce Yandle (Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield
-
As economist Paul Heyne counsels, "Ardent environmentalists need to discover and acknowledge that the same limitations which made economic central planning impossible will make it impossible to establish a comprehensive system of central environmental plan ning." Heyne, "Economics, Ethics, and Ecology," in Taking the Environment Seriously, ed. Roger Meiners and Bruce Yandle (Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, 1993), 47.
-
(1993)
Taking the Environment Seriously
, pp. 47
-
-
Heyne1
-
13
-
-
0003931255
-
United States Environmental Regulation: A Failing Paradigm
-
Richard B. Stewart, "United States Environmental Regulation: A Failing Paradigm," Journal of Law and Commerce 15 (1996): 587.
-
(1996)
Journal of Law and Commerce
, vol.15
, pp. 587
-
-
Richard, B.1
Stewart2
-
14
-
-
70349203751
-
Conclusion: Environmental Policy at the Crossroads
-
ed. Michael S. Greve and Fred L. Smith, Jr. (New York: Praeger
-
Fred L. Smith, Jr., "Conclusion: Environmental Policy at the Crossroads," in Environ mental Politics: Public Costs, Private Rewards, ed. Michael S. Greve and Fred L. Smith, Jr. (New York: Praeger, 1992), 192.
-
(1992)
Environ Mental Politics: Public Costs, Private Rewards
, pp. 192
-
-
Fred, L.1
Smith, Jr.2
-
15
-
-
0014413249
-
The Tragedy of the Commons
-
December 13
-
Garrett Hardin, "The Tragedy of the Commons," Science 162 (December 13, 1968): 1243.
-
(1968)
Science
, vol.162
, pp. 1243
-
-
Hardin, G.1
-
16
-
-
0001418901
-
The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery
-
Two qualifications should be noted with regard to Hardin?s essay. First, while Hardin was responsible for popularizing the notion of the commons problem, he was hardly the first to make these observations. The commons problem with regard to ocean fisheries was iden tified several years earlier in H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery," Journal of Political Economy 62 (1954): 124;
-
(1954)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.62
, pp. 124
-
-
Scott Gordon, H.1
-
17
-
-
0001109955
-
The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership
-
Anthony Scott, "The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership," Journal of Political Economy 63 (1955): 116.
-
(1955)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.63
, pp. 116
-
-
Scott, A.1
-
18
-
-
70349220845
-
-
The general phenomenon was also identified some time earlier by Aristotle in Politics 1261b32, ed. Trevor J. Saunders, trans. T. A. Sinclair (New York: Penguin Books, 1981)
-
The general phenomenon was also identified some time earlier by Aristotle in Politics 1261b32, ed. Trevor J. Saunders, trans. T. A. Sinclair (New York: Penguin Books, 1981).
-
-
-
-
19
-
-
70349220843
-
-
note
-
Second, Hardin?s analysis applies to open-access commons and should not be taken as a historical account of the actual conditions of commonly owned pastures, which were often protected by common property rules or social norms.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
70349220850
-
-
note
-
While all, or perhaps nearly all, environmental problems can be analyzed as variants of the commons problem, it is often useful to draw finer analytical distinctions among different types of environmental concerns, ranging from pollution spillovers to the provision of public goods, among others.
-
-
-
-
23
-
-
33444474402
-
Gains from Private Property: The Empirical Evidence
-
ed. Terry L. Anderson and Fred S. McChesney (Prince ton, NJ: Princeton University Press
-
Louis De Alessi, "Gains from Private Property: The Empirical Evidence," in Property Rights: Cooperation, Conflict, and Law, ed. Terry L. Anderson and Fred S. McChesney (Prince ton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003), 108.
-
(2003)
Property Rights: Cooperation, Conflict, and Law
, pp. 108
-
-
De Alessi, L.1
-
24
-
-
84925930963
-
Resolving the Tragedy of the Commons by Creating Private Property Rights in Wildlife
-
Fall
-
R. J. Smith, "Resolving the Tragedy of the Commons by Creating Private Property Rights in Wildlife," Cato Journal 1 (Fall 1981), 456-57.
-
(1981)
Cato Journal
, vol.1
, pp. 456-57
-
-
Smith, R.J.1
-
25
-
-
70349207127
-
Legal Obstacles to Private Ordering in Marine Fisheries
-
Fall
-
This research is summarized in Jonathan H. Adler, "Legal Obstacles to Private Ordering in Marine Fisheries," Roger Williams University Law Review 8 (Fall 2002): 19-22.
-
(2002)
Roger Williams University Law Review
, vol.8
, pp. 19-22
-
-
Jonathan, H.1
Adler2
-
26
-
-
70349203750
-
-
Adler, ed., Ecology, Liberty, and Property
-
Jonathan H. Adler, "Poplar Front: The Rebirth of America?s Forests," in Adler, ed., Ecology, Liberty, and Property;
-
Poplar Front: The Rebirth of America?s Forests
-
-
Jonathan, H.1
Adler2
-
27
-
-
0008120362
-
Forests: Conflicting Signals
-
Ronald Bailey, ed. New York: The Free Press
-
see also Roger A. Sedjo, "Forests: Conflicting Signals," in Ronald Bailey, ed., The True State of the Planet (New York: The Free Press, 1995).
-
(1995)
The True State of the Planet
-
-
Roger, A.1
Sedjo2
-
29
-
-
3042686410
-
Property Rights, the Environment, and Economic Well-Being
-
Peter J. Hill and Roger E. Meiners, eds. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield
-
Seth W. Norton, "Property Rights, the Environment, and Economic Well-Being," in Peter J. Hill and Roger E. Meiners, eds., Who Owns the Environment? (Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, 1998), 51.
-
(1998)
Who Owns the Environment?
, pp. 51
-
-
Seth, W.1
Norton2
-
30
-
-
70349226739
-
The Green Costs of Kelo: Economic Development Takings and Environmental Protection
-
For instance, the excessive use of the eminent domain power could come at the expense of environmental conservation. See Ilya Somin and Jonathan H. Adler, "The Green Costs of Kelo: Economic Development Takings and Environmental Protection," Washington University Law Review 84, no. 3 (2006): 623-66.
-
(2006)
Washington University Law Review
, vol.84
, Issue.3
, pp. 623-66
-
-
Somin, I.1
Adler, J.H.2
-
32
-
-
0005826748
-
Wetlands, Waterfowl, and the Menace of Mr. Wilson: Commerce Clause Jurisprudence and the Limits of Federal Wetland Regulation
-
On early twentieth-century views of wetlands, and governmental efforts to make more "productive use" of such lands, see Jonathan H. Adler, "Wetlands, Waterfowl, and the Menace of Mr. Wilson: Commerce Clause Jurisprudence and the Limits of Federal Wetland Regulation," Environmental Law 29 (1999): 19-20.
-
(1999)
Environmental Law
, vol.29
, pp. 19-20
-
-
Jonathan, H.1
Adler2
-
33
-
-
70349205455
-
Where the Buffalo Roam, and Why
-
January/February
-
Ike C. Sugg, "Where the Buffalo Roam, and Why," Exotic Wildlife, January/February 1999. Sugg quotes wildlife conservationist Valerius Geist saying, "Bison were initially saved by six individuals who either saw business opportunities in the existence of bison or simply wanted to save a vanishing species."
-
(1999)
Exotic Wildlife
-
-
Ike, C.1
Sugg2
-
34
-
-
70349218016
-
Special Report: The Public Benefits of Private Conservation
-
U.S. Council on Environmental Quality Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1984
-
U.S. Council on Environmental Quality, "Special Report: The Public Benefits of Private Conservation," in Environmental Quality, 1984 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1984), 387-94.
-
(1984)
Environmental Quality
, pp. 387-94
-
-
-
36
-
-
0003461703
-
-
Toronto, Ontario: Earthscan Publications Ltd.
-
For FME accounts of the common law?s capacity to protect private property rights, see Elizabeth Brubaker, Property Rights in the Defence of Nature (Toronto, Ontario: Earthscan Publications Ltd., 1995);
-
(1995)
Property Rights in the Defence of Nature
-
-
Brubaker, E.1
-
38
-
-
0032331416
-
Common Law Environmentalism
-
Roger Meiners and Bruce Yandle, "Common Law Environmentalism," Public Choice 94 (1998);
-
(1998)
Public Choice
, vol.94
-
-
Meiners, R.1
Yandle, B.2
-
39
-
-
0039776806
-
Protecting English and Welsh Rivers: The Role of the Anglers? Conservation Association
-
Roger E. Meiners and Andrew P. Morriss, eds. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield
-
Roger Bate, "Protecting English and Welsh Rivers: The Role of the Anglers? Conservation Association," in Roger E. Meiners and Andrew P. Morriss, eds., The Common Law and the Environment: Rethinking the Statutory Basis for Modern Environmental Law (Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, 2000);
-
(2000)
Common Law and the Environment: Rethinking the Statutory Basis for Modern Environmental Law
-
-
Bate, R.1
-
40
-
-
70349216426
-
Climbing out of the Hole: Sunsets, Subjective Value, the Environment, and English Common Law
-
Spring
-
Julian Morris, "Climbing Out of the Hole: Sunsets, Subjective Value, the Environment, and English Common Law," Fordham Environmental Law Journal 14 (Spring 2003): 343-73.
-
(2003)
Fordham Environmental Law Journal
, vol.14
, pp. 343-73
-
-
Morris, J.1
-
41
-
-
0005890056
-
The Common Law and the Environment: The Canadian Experi ence
-
Hill and Meiners, eds.
-
Elizabeth Brubaker, "The Common Law and the Environment: The Canadian Experi ence," in Hill and Meiners, eds., Who Owns the Environment?, 88-89.
-
Who Owns the Environment?
, pp. 88-89
-
-
Brubaker, E.1
-
42
-
-
70349192779
-
-
Whalen v. Union Bag & Paper Co., 208 N.Y. 1 (1913)
-
Whalen v. Union Bag & Paper Co., 208 N.Y. 1 (1913).
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
0003304997
-
Coase, Pigou, and Environmental Rights
-
Hill and Meiners, eds.
-
Bruce Yandle, "Coase, Pigou, and Environmental Rights," in Hill and Meiners, eds., Who Owns the Environment?, 138.
-
Who Owns the Environment?
, pp. 138
-
-
Yandle, B.1
-
44
-
-
70349195910
-
Law, Property Rights, and Air Pollution
-
Spring
-
Typically, civil actions only require that the plaintiff show the existence of a tort by a preponderance of the evidence. Some theorists, however, such as the late libertarian economist Murray N. Rothbard, would go much further, requiring property owners to demonstrate the existence of harm from pollution "beyond a reasonable doubt," even if that renders most forms of pollution nonactionable. See Rothbard, "Law, Property Rights, and Air Pollution," Cato Journal 3, no. 1 (Spring 1982): 87-88.
-
(1982)
Cato Journal
, vol.3
, Issue.1
, pp. 87-88
-
-
Rothbard1
-
45
-
-
70349195910
-
Law, Property Rights, and Air Pollution
-
Even though the imposition of a higher burden of proof would mean that fewer individuals harmed by pollution would be able to achieve recompense in court, Rothbard argued that such a high standard of proof is necessary because "it is far better to let an aggressive act slip through than to impose coercion and commit aggression ourselves." Ibid., 70.
-
Cato Journal
, vol.3
, Issue.70
-
-
Rothbard1
-
46
-
-
0002071502
-
The Problem of Social Cost
-
Such bargaining over the allocation of property rights is often referred to as "Coasean bargaining," after the economist Ronald H. Coase, who argued that, in the absence of transaction costs, property rights will be transferred to their highest and best use through voluntary transactions among property owners. See R. H. Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3, no. 1 (1960): 1-44.
-
(1960)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.3
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-44
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
49
-
-
70349220844
-
The Progressive Era?s Derailment of Classical-Liberal Evolution
-
June 30
-
For example, Competitive Enterprise Institute president Fred Smith argues that pro gressive thought undermined classical liberal principles that had been embodied in the common law and had the potential to provide greater environmental protection: Progressives believed that markets and private property slowed progress, and that collective management of resources would more surely advance the public interest. Thus they blocked the extension of private property to resources that had not yet been privatized (indeed, in the case of the electromagnetic spectrum and some arid western lands, rolling back fledgling homesteading efforts). Progressives also transformed the rule of law, making it more utilitarian, more willing to ignore individual values to advance the "common good." Social concerns trumped individual rights. Earlier common-law defenses of individual property rights that might have encouraged economic development along more environmentally sensitive paths were weakened or abandoned. The gradual emergence of the environment as a valued aspect of life occurred in a world bereft of classical-liberal institutions. Older property-rights defenses were slowly eroded, and their newer adaptations were blocked. The result was that when environmental values became majority values, few realized that they might better be protected privately via a creative program of ecological privatization. Fred L. Smith, Jr., "The Progressive Era?s Derailment of Classical-Liberal Evolution," The Freeman: Ideas on Liberty (June 2004): 28, 30.
-
(2004)
The Freeman: Ideas on Liberty
, pp. 28
-
-
Fred, L.1
Smith, Jr.2
-
50
-
-
70349211661
-
-
For example, in an essay on property rights and air pollution, Murray N. Rothbard explained: If the law is a set of normative principles, it follows that whatever positive or customary law has emerged cannot simply be recorded and blindly followed. All such law must be subject to a thorough critique grounded on such principles. Then, if there are discrepancies between actual law and just principles, as there almost always are, steps must be taken to make the law conform with correct legal principles. Rothbard, "Law, Property Rights, and Air Pollution," 60. Similarly, economist Paul Heyne argues that the protection of private property rights is as much about justice as efficiency. See Heyne, "Economics, Ethics, and Ecology," 34.
-
Economics, Ethics, and Ecology
, pp. 34
-
-
Heyne1
-
51
-
-
34548104942
-
The Physical Science behind Climate Change
-
August
-
For a brief and accessible summary of the science of global climate change, see William Collins et al., "The Physical Science behind Climate Change," Scientific American (August 2007).
-
(2007)
Scientific American
-
-
Collins, W.1
-
52
-
-
70349226738
-
-
note
-
Overall, global mean surface temperatures have risen over the past century, but not consistently. Surface temperatures warmed from 1911 to 1944, cooled from 1944 to 1976, and have warmed again since. The mid-century cooling is generally attributed to the emission of sulfates and other industrial pollutants.
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
70349208538
-
-
For example, climatologists Patrick J. Michaels and Robert C. Balling, Jr., two promi nent warming skeptics, have predicted that there will be 0.65-0.75 degrees Celsius warming by 2050. Michaels and Balling, The Satanic Gases, 210-11. They have also predicted a warming- induced sea-level rise of five to eleven inches over the next century. Ibid., 162.
-
Climate Change 2007: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group i to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
, pp. 162
-
-
Michaels, P.J.1
Balling Jr., R.C.2
-
55
-
-
36549049375
-
-
Solomon et al., Climate Change 2007. There is some controversy and uncertainty sur rounding the IPCC?s estimates of projected sea-level rise due to the failure to include the potential effects of rapid ice sheet collapse.
-
Climate Change 2007
-
-
Solomon, E.1
-
56
-
-
34548696816
-
The Limits of Consensus
-
See Michael Oppenheimer et al., "The Limits of Consensus," Science 317 (2007): 1505; and
-
(2007)
Science
, vol.317
, pp. 1505
-
-
Oppenheimer, M.1
-
57
-
-
38549157998
-
A Closer Look at the IPCC Report
-
Susan Solomon et al., "A Closer Look at the IPCC Report," Science 319 (2008): 409.
-
(2008)
Science
, vol.319
, pp. 409
-
-
Solomon, S.1
-
61
-
-
33645135987
-
The Distribu tional Impact of Climate Change on Rich and Poor Countries
-
see also Robert Mendelsohn, Ariel Dinar, and Larry Williams, "The Distribu tional Impact of Climate Change on Rich and Poor Countries," Environment and Development Economics 11 (2006): 159.
-
(2006)
Environment and Development Economics
, vol.11
, pp. 159
-
-
Mendelsohn, R.1
Dinar, A.2
Williams, L.3
-
62
-
-
70349195908
-
Global Warming: A Dialogue-Should Victims Receive Compensation?
-
March
-
For an exchange on this question among self-professed FME advocates, see "Global Warming: A Dialogue-Should Victims Receive Compensation?" PERC Reports (March 2005).
-
(2005)
PERC Reports
-
-
-
64
-
-
70349207120
-
Clouds over Kyoto: The Debate over Global Warming
-
Jerry Taylor, "Clouds Over Kyoto: The Debate Over Global Warming," Regulation, 21, no. 1 (1998).
-
(1998)
Regulation
, vol.21
, Issue.1
-
-
Taylor, J.1
-
66
-
-
77749242204
-
What to Do about Climate Change
-
Washington, DC: Cato Institute, February 5
-
Indur M. Goklany, "What to Do about Climate Change," Policy Analysis, no. 609 (Washington, DC: Cato Institute, February 5, 2008).
-
(2008)
Policy Analysis
, Issue.609
-
-
Indur, M.1
Goklany2
-
73
-
-
34548119870
-
Basic Compensation for Victims of Climate Change
-
Daniel A. Farber, "Basic Compensation for Victims of Climate Change," University of Pennsylvania Law Review 155 (2007): 1644-45.
-
(2007)
University of Pennsylvania Law Review
, vol.155
, pp. 1644-45
-
-
Daniel, A.1
Farber2
-
74
-
-
70349194458
-
-
note
-
For the purposes of this thought experiment, intranational effects of climate change are being ignored. In actuality, however, such intranational effects could be significant. In the United States, for example, sea-level rise might impose substantial costs on coastal states, whereas states with substantial agricultural production may benefit significantly from a modest warming and a consequent expansion of growing seasons.
-
-
-
-
75
-
-
70349214783
-
-
Morris reports on cases in which "multiple sources have been held jointly liable for harms," even in cases where "individually their actions would not have constituted a nuisance." See Morris, "Climbing Out of the Hole," 358.
-
Climbing out of the Hole
, pp. 358
-
-
Morris1
-
76
-
-
70349203746
-
-
Farber also discusses precedents for apportioning liability among multiple defendants who may all have contributed to a given harm. See Farber, "Basic Compensation," 1639-40.
-
Basic Compensation
, pp. 1639-40
-
-
Farber1
-
77
-
-
70349195909
-
-
note
-
This assumption may be particularly unrealistic insofar as some apparent sea-level rise may actually be due to subsidence of coastal areas, and because some subsidence may be due to various human activities in affected nations. Nonetheless, there is little disagreement that anthropogenic climate change should produce some increase in mean global sea level.
-
-
-
-
78
-
-
70349218013
-
Global Warming and Social Justice
-
As Eric Posner and Cass Sunstein point out, "emission reductions are an in-kind ben efit," and poor people in less-developed nations would almost certainly prefer a "cash transfer" or other compensation in lieu of emission reductions. Eric A. Posner and Cass R. Sunstein, "Global Warming and Social Justice," Regulation 31, no. 1 (2008): 17.
-
(2008)
Regulation
, vol.31
, Issue.1
, pp. 17
-
-
Posner, E.A.1
Sunstein, C.R.2
-
79
-
-
70349192778
-
-
note
-
There are precedents for such Coasean bargains under international law. As part of the Montreal Protocol, the international agreement to phase out the use and production of substances that deplete the stratospheric ozone layer that took effect in 1989, those nations most at risk from ozone depletion agreed to compensate other nations for giving up their right to produce and use such substances in the future. This exchange shows that such bargains are possible, even on an international scale, but that does not mean that this bargain was consistent with FME principles.
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
70349207121
-
-
note
-
This is a reasonable assumption, since the contemporary customary international law of transboundary pollution disputes is largely based upon the law of interstate pollution disputes in the United States, which, in turn, is based upon traditional common law principles.
-
-
-
-
81
-
-
70349203746
-
-
As Farber notes, effects such as sea-level rise "are readily identifiable, do not raise the complicated causation issues that plague other potential forms of damages, and can be measured (at least roughly) in a fairly straightforward way." Farber, "Basic Compensation," 1606-7.
-
Basic Compensation
, pp. 1606-7
-
-
Farber1
-
82
-
-
24344499924
-
-
Pub. L. No. 93-205, 87 Stat. 884 (codified as amended in 16 U.S.C. secs. 1531-43 and additional scattered sections of 16 U.S.C.). For commentary on the strength of the legislation Dale D. Goble, J. Michael Scott, and Frank W. Davis, eds. Washington, DC: Island Press
-
Pub. L. No. 93-205, 87 Stat. 884 (codified as amended in 16 U.S.C. secs. 1531-43 and additional scattered sections of 16 U.S.C.). For commentary on the strength of the legislation, see Dale D. Goble, J. Michael Scott, and Frank W. Davis, eds., The Endangered Species Act at Thirty, vol. 1, Renewing the Conservation Promise (Washington, DC: Island Press, 2006).
-
(2006)
The Endangered Species Act at Thirty, Vol. 1, Renewing the Conservation Promise
-
-
-
84
-
-
0032834823
-
Values, Ethics, and Attitudes Toward National Forests: An Empirical Study
-
June
-
Robert Manning, William Vallierre, and Ben Minteer, "Values, Ethics, and Attitudes Toward National Forests: An Empirical Study," Society and Natural Resources 12, no. 5 (June 1999): 421-36;
-
(1999)
Society and Natural Resources
, vol.12
, Issue.5
, pp. 421-36
-
-
Manning, R.1
Vallierre, W.2
Minteer, B.3
|