메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 62, Issue 4, 2009, Pages 1217-1243

Arrow's theorem and the exclusive shareholder franchise

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 70149083457     PISSN: 00422533     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (8)

References (144)
  • 1
    • 0036977921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Director primacy in corporate takeovers: Preliminary reflections
    • ('Today, most corporate law scholars embrace some variant of shareholder primacy."). In some sense, shareholder primacy means nothing more than shareholder control of the corporation through the power to elect directors.
    • Shareholder primacy is generally viewed as the normative foundation for modern corporate law theory. See Stephen M. Bainbridge, Director Primacy in Corporate Takeovers: Preliminary Reflections, 55 STAN. L. REV. 791, 798 & n.35 (2002) ('Today, most corporate law scholars embrace some variant of shareholder primacy."). In some sense, shareholder primacy means nothing more than shareholder control of the corporation through the power to elect directors.
    • (2002) 55 Stan. L. Rev , vol.791 , Issue.35 , pp. 798
    • Bainbridge, S.M.1
  • 2
    • 0345873972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The shareholder primacy norm
    • ("The structure of corporate law ensures that corporations generally operate in the interests of shareholders. Shareholders exercise control over corporations by electing directors...."). However, shareholder primacy is generally seen as meaning something more: namely, that the corporation's directors should strive to run the corporation solely for the financial benefit of the shareholders in order to maximize social utility.
    • See D. Gordon Smith, The Shareholder Primacy Norm, 23 J. CORP. L. 277, 277 (1998) ("The structure of corporate law ensures that corporations generally operate in the interests of shareholders. Shareholders exercise control over corporations by electing directors...."). However, shareholder primacy is generally seen as meaning something more: namely, that the corporation's directors should strive to run the corporation solely for the financial benefit of the shareholders in order to maximize social utility.
    • (1998) 23 J. Corp L. , vol.277 , pp. 277
    • Smith, D.G.1
  • 3
    • 0347765234 scopus 로고
    • 50 Wash. & LEE L. rev. [hereinafter Bainbridge, In Defense]. For that reason, it is sometimes called the "shareholder wealth maximization" norm.
    • See Stephen M. Bainbridge, In Defense of the Shareholder Wealth Maximization Norm: A Reply to Professor Green, 50 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1423, 1423 (1993) [hereinafter Bainbridge, In Defense]. For that reason, it is sometimes called the "shareholder wealth maximization" norm.
    • (1993) Defense of the Shareholder Wealth Maximization Norm: A Reply to Professor Green , vol.1423 , pp. 1423
    • Bainbridge, S.M.1
  • 4
    • 70149112569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1423-25
    • Id. at 1423-25.
  • 5
    • 0012320703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For some prominent examples (arguing that shareholder wealth maximization keeps managers and stockholders focused on the short term
    • For some prominent examples, see lawrence e. mitchell, corporate irresponsibility: america's newest export 4-5 (2001) (arguing that shareholder wealth maximization keeps managers and stockholders focused on the short term);
    • (2001) Corporate Irresponsibility: America's Newest Export , pp. 4-5
    • Mitchell, L.E.1
  • 6
    • 84881731887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Directors' Duties in a post-enron world: Why language matters
    • (criticizing shareholder primacy's focus on the maximization of short-term value)
    • Margaret M. Blair, Directors' Duties in a Post-Enron World: Why Language Matters, 38 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 885, 891-95 (2003) (criticizing shareholder primacy's focus on the maximization of short-term value);
    • (2003) 38 Wake Forest L. Rev. , vol.885 , pp. 891-95
    • Blair, M.M.1
  • 7
    • 0036655428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bad and Not-So-Bad Arguments for Shareholder Primacy
    • (dismissing several key arguments for shareholder primacy and providing tepid support for one
    • Lynn a. Stout, Bad and Not-So-Bad Arguments for Shareholder Primacy, 75 S. cal. L. rev. 1189, 1208 (2002) (dismissing several key arguments for shareholder primacy and providing tepid support for one).
    • (2002) 75 S. Cal. L. Rev , vol.1189 , pp. 1208
    • Stout, L.A.1
  • 8
    • 70149092208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Gordon Smith might be considered one such observer. In an article examining the actual effects of the norm, Smith acknowledged that "[t]he assumption that the shareholder primacy norm is a major factor in the ordinary business decisions of boards of directors of modern, publicly traded corporations is pervasive in modern corporate law scholarship." Smith, supra note 1, at 280. However, he argued that "the shareholder primacy norm is nearly irrelevant to the ordinary business decisions of modern corporations" and that the norm may be "one of the most overrated doctrines in corporate law."
  • 9
    • 70149102680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 279, 323
    • Id. at 279, 323.
  • 10
    • 70149097789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Bainbridge, In Defense, supra note 1, at 1423-1425, 1446 (describing the shareholder wealth maximization norm as providing the basic logic from which modern corporate law rules have emerged).
    • See, e.g., Bainbridge, In Defense, supra note 1, at 1423-1425, 1446 (describing the shareholder wealth maximization norm as providing the basic logic from which modern corporate law rules have emerged).
  • 11
    • 48549106971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring efficiency in corporate Law: The role of shareholder primacy
    • Jill e. Fisch, Measuring Efficiency in Corporate Law: The Role of Shareholder Primacy, 31 J. CORP. L. 637, 639 (2006).
    • (2006) 31 J. Corp. L. , vol.637 , pp. 639
    • Fisch, J.E.1
  • 12
    • 70149122754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, §§ 211-212 (2002).
    • (2002) Del. Code Ann. Tit , vol.8 , pp. 211-212
  • 13
    • 70149095494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I. A
    • See infra Part I. A.
  • 15
    • 0004035764 scopus 로고
    • (summarizing the assumptions, conditions, and conclusions of the theorem
    • see also NORMAN FROHLICH & JOE A. OPPENHEIMER, MODERN POLITICAL ECONOMY 19-23 (1978) (summarizing the assumptions, conditions, and conclusions of the theorem);
    • (1978) Modern Political Economy , pp. 19-23
    • Frohlich, N.1    Oppenheimer, J.A.2
  • 17
    • 0000750050 scopus 로고
    • Voting in Corporate Law
    • See infra Part I.A (discussing, inter alia
    • See infra Part LA (discussing, inter alia, Frank H. Easterbrook & Daniel R. Fischel, Voting in Corporate Law, 26 J.L. & ECON. 395 (1983)).
    • (1983) 26 J.L. & ECON , vol.395
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1    Fischel, D.R.2
  • 18
    • 70149094781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405.
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405.
  • 19
    • 84869601461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., frohlich & oppenheimer, supra note 8, at 30-31 (stating that voting systems, according to the posits of social choice, "by themselves cannot lead to intuitively justifiable decisions," and, consequently, that corollary aspects of the decisionmaking process must be adjusted to achieve better group choices).
    • See, e.g., frohlich & oppenheimer, supra note 8, at 30-31 (stating that voting systems, according to the posits of social choice, "by themselves cannot lead to intuitively justifiable decisions," and, consequently, that corollary aspects of the decisionmaking process must be adjusted to achieve better group choices).
  • 20
    • 70149099365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One Share, One Vote and the False Promise of Shareholder Homogeneity
    • Grant M. Hayden & Matthew T. Bodie, One Share, One Vote and the False Promise of Shareholder Homogeneity, 30 cardozo L. rev. 445, 445-505 (2008).
    • (2008) 30 Cardozo L. Rev. , vol.445 , pp. 445-505
    • Hayden, G.M.1    Bodie, M.T.2
  • 21
    • 84869626456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Smith, supra note 1, at 299 (describing the development of the principle of shareholder primacy as deriving in part from the fact of "the exclusive right of shareholders to vote").
    • See Smith, supra note 1, at 299 (describing the development of the principle of shareholder primacy as deriving in part from the fact of "the exclusive right of shareholders to vote").
  • 22
    • 0001788578 scopus 로고
    • The social responsibility of business Is to increase Its profits
    • Sept 13 For a version of this argument 122-126 (arguing that shareholders are "the owners of the business" and, therefore, that the only "social responsibility of business is to increase its profits"
    • For a version of this argument, see, e.g., Milton Friedman, The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits, N.Y. times mag., Sept. 13, 1970, at 32-33, 122-126 (arguing that shareholders are "the owners of the business" and, therefore, that the only "social responsibility of business is to increase its profits").
    • (1970) N.Y. Times Mag. , pp. 32-33
    • Friedman, M.1
  • 24
    • 34250024408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Mythical Benefits of Shareholder Control
    • For a critique of the argument based on shareholder ownership
    • For a critique of the argument based on shareholder ownership, see Lynn A. Stout, The Mythical Benefits of Shareholder Control, 93 Va. L. rev. 789, 804-805 (2007).
    • (2007) 93 Va. L. Rev , vol.789 , pp. 804-805
    • Stout, L.A.1
  • 26
    • 70149107263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405.
  • 27
    • 70149088590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Easterbrook & fischel, supra note 15, at 70. Because the arguments in the article and book are identical, we will refer to the earlier article. Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9.
    • EASTERBROOK & FISCHEL, supra note 15, at 70. Because the arguments in the article and book are identical, we will refer to the earlier article. Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9.
  • 28
    • 0003598515 scopus 로고
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405 (citing arrow, supra note 8; [hereinafter Black, Theory])
    • DUNCAN BLACK, THE THEORY OF COMMITTEES AND ELECTIONS (1958) [hereinafter BLACK, THEORY]).
    • (1958) The Theory of Committees and Elections
    • Black, D.1
  • 29
    • 70149094537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 30
    • 70149121730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 31
    • 70149088175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is also, they mention, the reason why the law makes little effort to require firms to pursue goals other than profit maximization
    • This is also, they mention, the reason why the law makes little effort to require firms to pursue goals other than profit maximization.
  • 32
    • 70149109370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 405-06
    • Id. at 405-06.
  • 33
    • 0011674694 scopus 로고
    • Social choice theory and Arrow's theorem have mainly come into legal scholarship under the guise of public choice theory. For summaries of the literature
    • Social choice theory and Arrow's theorem have mainly come into legal scholarship under the guise of public choice theory. For summaries of the literature, see DANIEL A. FARBER & PHILIP P. FRICKEY, LAW AND PUBLIC CHOICE: A CRITICAL INTRODUCTION 38-42 (1991);
    • (1991) Law and Public Choice: A Critical Introduction , pp. 38-42
    • Farber, D.A.1    Frickey, P.P.2
  • 35
    • 70149116580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FROHLICH & OPPENHEIMER, supra note 8, at 16
    • See FROHLICH & OPPENHEIMER, SUPRA note 8, at 16.
  • 36
    • 70149116806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ARROW, supra note 8, at 22-23, 51-60
    • ARROW, supra note 8, at 22-23, 51-60.
  • 37
    • 70149095965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (laying out the logical foundations and conclusions for the theorem)
    • See id. (laying out the logical foundations and conclusions for the theorem);
  • 38
    • 70149113484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also FROHLICH & OPPENHEIMER, supra note 8, at 19-23 (summarizing the assumptions, conditions, and conclusions of the theorem)
    • see also FROHLICH & OPPENHEIMER, supra note 8, at 19-23 (summarizing the assumptions, conditions, and conclusions of the theorem)
  • 40
    • 0041653786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a good, recent summary of the state of social choice theory and Arrow's theorem, at ix Kenneth J. Arrow et al. eds
    • For a good, recent summary of the state of social choice theory and Arrow's theorem, see 1 handbook of social choice and welfare, at ix (Kenneth J. Arrow et al. eds., 2002) [hereinafter 1 handbook of social choice and welfare].
    • (2002) 1 Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare
  • 41
    • 70149120320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RIKER, supra note 25, at 295.
    • RIKER, supra note 25, at 295.
  • 42
    • 70149116349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 117-118
    • Id. at 117-118.
  • 43
    • 70149083923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 116-117, 297
    • Id. at 116-117, 297.
  • 44
    • 70149114825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 118
    • Id. at 118.
  • 45
    • 84869610480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Social Choice Theory: A Defense of the Voting Rights Act
    • The term "irrelevant" is not pejorative, but instead refers to an alternative outside the set from which a group must choose that does not alter the desirability of the other alternatives relative to each other
    • The term "irrelevant" is not pejorative, but instead refers to an alternative outside the set from which a group must choose that does not alter the desirability of the other alternatives relative to each other. Grant M. Hayden, The Limits of Social Choice Theory: A Defense of the Voting Rights Act, 74 TUL. L. REV. 87, 101 (1999).
    • (1999) 74 TUL. L. REV. , vol.87 , pp. 101
    • Hayden, G.M.1
  • 46
    • 70149114383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RIKER, supra note 25, at 119, 297
    • See RIKER, supra note 25, at 119, 297.
  • 47
    • 70149094326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hayden, supra note 29, at 101-102 (describing intransitivity as a voting cycle and explaining the problems with a system displaying this characteristic)
    • See Hayden, supra note 29, at 101-102 (describing intransitivity as a voting cycle and explaining the problems with a system displaying this characteristic);
  • 48
    • 70149098220 scopus 로고
    • Some implications of arrow's theorem for voting rights
    • [hereinafter Hayden, Note] (defining intransitivity and stating that it may in essence lead to dictatorial power being exercised in a social choice function by way of agenda control
    • Grant M. Hayden, Note, Some Implications of Arrow's Theorem for Voting Rights, 47 STAN. L. REV. 295, 299 (1995) [hereinafter Hayden, Note] (defining intransitivity and stating that it may in essence lead to dictatorial power being exercised in a social choice function by way of agenda control).
    • (1995) 47 STAN. L. REV , vol.295 , pp. 299
    • Grant, M.H.1
  • 49
    • 70149106376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405.
  • 50
    • 70149088177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 51
    • 70149099566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 405-06
    • Id. at 405-06.
  • 53
    • 70149122141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 41-42
    • Id. at 41-42.
  • 54
    • 70149110860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 42
    • Id. at 42.
  • 55
    • 0003350967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new institutional economics and employment regulation
    • 69 (Bruce E. Kaufman ed)
    • Gregory K. Dow, The New Institutional Economics and Employment Regulation, in GOVERNMENT REGULATION OF THE EMPLOYMENT RELATIONSHIP 57, 69 (Bruce E. Kaufman ed., 1997).
    • (1997) Government Regulation of the Employment Relationship , vol.57
    • Dow, G.K.1
  • 56
    • 70149087960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 57
    • 70149118768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Though he relies on Arrow's theorem as part of a general argument against opening up corporate elections to additional constituencies, Dow seems most worried about cycling at the level of board decisionmaking
    • Though he relies on Arrow's theorem as part of a general argument against opening up corporate elections to additional constituencies, Dow seems most worried about cycling at the level of board decisionmaking
  • 58
    • 70149094327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 59
    • 70149111077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id
    • See, e.g., id.
  • 60
    • 0346934193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A team production theory of corporate law
    • In their model, people who hope to profit from team production give up some of their rights to the corporation and, in return, the corporation coordinates the activities of the team members and allocates the resulting production in a way that minimizes shirking and rent-seeking
    • Margaret M. Blair & Lynn A. Stout, A Team Production Theory of Corporate Law, 85 va. L. rev. 247 (1999). In their model, people who hope to profit from team production give up some of their rights to the corporation and, in return, the corporation coordinates the activities of the team members and allocates the resulting production in a way that minimizes shirking and rent-seeking.
    • (1999) 85 Va. L. Rev. , vol.247
    • Blair, M.M.1    Stout, L.A.2
  • 61
    • 70149100422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 250-51
    • Id. at 250-51.
  • 62
    • 70149095716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 253
    • Id. at 253.
  • 63
    • 70149100205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 312-315
    • Id. at 312-315.
  • 64
    • 70149115671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 313. This is not, by the way, their only argument for this conclusion.
    • Id. at 313. This is not, by the way, their only argument for this conclusion.
  • 65
    • 70149111276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 314-15
    • Id. at 314-15.
  • 66
    • 70149120319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Introduction
    • Introduction to 1 handbook of social choice and welfare, supra note 25, at 1, 18-25 (describing decades of work attacking Arrow's theorem, but reiterating its continued vitality)
    • See Kotaro Suzumura, Introduction to 1 handbook of social choice and welfare, supra note 25, at 1, 18-25 (describing decades of work attacking Arrow's theorem, but reiterating its continued vitality).
    • 1 Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare
    • Suzumura, K.1
  • 68
    • 0346250710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The end of history for corporate law
    • Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, The End of History for Corporate Law, 89 GEO. L.J. 439, 447-449 (2001).
    • (2001) 89 GEO. L.J , vol.439 , pp. 447-449
    • Hansmann, H.1    Kraakman, R.2
  • 69
    • 0004197365 scopus 로고
    • The arguments are drawn, somewhat confusingly for our purposes, from Kenneth Arrow's other work on institutional design
    • The arguments are drawn, somewhat confusingly for our purposes, from Kenneth Arrow's other work on institutional design, THE limits OF organization (1974).
    • (1974) THE Limits of Organization
  • 70
    • 70349633622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Participatory Management Within a Theory of the Firm
    • See Stephen M. Bainbridge, Participatory Management Within a Theory of the Firm, 21 J. CORP. L. 657, 725 (1996).
    • (1996) 21 J. CORP. L. , vol.657 , pp. 725
    • Bainbridge, S.M.1
  • 71
    • 70149100421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blair & Stout, supra note 41, at 313
    • Blair & Stout, supra note 41, at 313.
  • 72
    • 70149111275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is certainly understandable because both arguments are related to potential breakdowns in collective decision making. This is not to say that the authors are conflating the two arguments, but just that it is difficult to see whether and to what degree they are relying upon the argument from Arrow's theorem when discussing reasons for limiting the franchise to shareholders.
    • This is certainly understandable because both arguments are related to potential breakdowns in collective decision making. This is not to say that the authors are conflating the two arguments, but just that it is difficult to see whether and to what degree they are relying upon the argument from Arrow's theorem when discussing reasons for limiting the franchise to shareholders.
  • 73
    • 70149089238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bainbridge, supra note 48, at 667 n.51, 725 n.409
    • See Bainbridge, supra note 48, at 667 n.51, 725 n.409.
  • 74
    • 84869633331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("The vote of the majority of the directors present at a meeting at which a quorum is present shall be the act of the board of directors unless the certificate of incorporation or the bylaws shall require a vote of a greater number."
    • See DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 141(b) (2002) ("The vote of the majority of the directors present at a meeting at which a quorum is present shall be the act of the board of directors unless the certificate of incorporation or the bylaws shall require a vote of a greater number.").
    • (2002) Del. Code Ann. Tit , vol.8 , pp. 141
  • 75
    • 70149114824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 305
    • See Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 305.
  • 76
    • 84869601453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ORDESHOOK, supra note 8, at 56-57 (discussing the Condorcet paradox and its argument that journalistic shorthand such as "the public interest" or "community goals" has no proper place in any adequate theory of political processes)
    • See ORDESHOOK, supra note 8, at 56-57 (discussing the Condorcet paradox and its argument that journalistic shorthand such as "the public interest" or "community goals" has no proper place in any adequate theory of political processes);
  • 77
    • 70149109371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RlKER, supra note 25, at 119
    • RlKER, supra note 25, at 119.
  • 78
    • 84869614470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405. One assumes this means choices that are inconsistent with each other, as opposed to inconsistent with some hypothetically "correct" choice (which, as we now know, would not be possible to discern)
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405. One assumes this means choices that are inconsistent with each other, as opposed to inconsistent with some hypothetically "correct" choice (which, as we now know, would not be possible to discern).
  • 79
    • 70149097559 scopus 로고
    • Manipulation of Voting Rules: A General Result
    • Alan G.A. Or subject to dictatorial control, a state of affairs that is no better in this context
    • Or subject to dictatorial control, a state of affairs that is no better in this context. See Alan Gibbard, Manipulation of Voting Rules: A General Result, 41 ECONOMETRICA 587, 587 (1973)
    • (1973) 41 Econometrica 587 , vol.587
  • 80
    • 49549141769 scopus 로고
    • Strategy-Proofness and Arrow's Conditions: Existence and Correspondence Theorems for Voting Procedures and Social Welfare Functions
    • Mark A. Satterthwaite, Strategy-Proofness and Arrow's Conditions: Existence and Correspondence Theorems for Voting Procedures and Social Welfare Functions, 10 J. econ. theory 187, 188 (1975).
    • (1975) 10 J. Econ. Theory 187 , vol.188
    • Satterthwaite, M.A.1
  • 81
    • 70149083922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HANSMANN, supra note 35, at 41-42
    • See HANSMANN, supra note 35, at 41-42.
  • 82
    • 0038354379 scopus 로고
    • Shareholder initiative: A social choice and game theoretic approach to corporate law
    • Jeffrey N. Gordon, Shareholder Initiative: A Social Choice and Game Theoretic Approach to Corporate Law, 60 U. CIN. L. REV. 347, 351-352 (1991).
    • (1991) 60 U. Cin. L. Rev. , Issue.347 , pp. 351-352
    • Gordon, J.N.1
  • 83
    • 70149099996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 359-360
    • Id. at 359-360.
  • 84
    • 70149115902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 359-363
    • See id. at 359-363.
  • 85
    • 70149096209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 363
    • See id. at 363.
  • 86
    • 70149104827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 373
    • Id. at 373.
  • 87
    • 70149124737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, Gordon makes some of these distinctions between the cycling problem with initiatives and the potential cycling problem that may arise in board elections with a more heterogeneous shareholder electorate
    • Indeed, Gordon makes some of these distinctions between the cycling problem with initiatives and the potential cycling problem that may arise in board elections with a more heterogeneous shareholder electorate.
  • 88
    • 70149089471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 372-373
    • See id. at 372-373.
  • 89
  • 90
    • 70149104590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hayden & Bodie, supra note 12, at 477-499 (cataloguing the ways in which shareholder interests diverge)
    • See Hayden & Bodie, supra note 12, at 477-499 (cataloguing the ways in which shareholder interests diverge).
  • 91
    • 70149123855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 477-480
    • See id. at 477-480.
  • 92
    • 70149121729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 486-488
    • See id. at 486-488.
  • 93
    • 70149089711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 492-494
    • See id. at 492-494.
  • 94
    • 70149096649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Martin & Partnoy, supra note 64, at 778 (quoting Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405)
    • Martin & Partnoy, supra note 64, at 778 (quoting Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405).
  • 95
    • 70149118552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bainbridge, supra note 48, at 665 (discussing various explanations, such as investment time and tax bracket, for disagreement over how best to achieve the goal of wealth maximization). If there was complete agreement, there would, of course, be no reason to have board elections in the first place because we could just ask one of the shareholders to report the shared preference ranking.
    • See Bainbridge, supra note 48, at 665 (discussing various explanations, such as investment time and tax bracket, for disagreement over how best to achieve the goal of wealth maximization). If there was complete agreement, there would, of course, be no reason to have board elections in the first place because we could just ask one of the shareholders to report the shared preference ranking.
  • 96
    • 70149111740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If the merger was a cash-out merger offering the highest current cash value of the three options, this preference set would correlate with shareholders interested in short-term profit maximization
    • If the merger was a cash-out merger offering the highest current cash value of the three options, this preference set would correlate with shareholders interested in short-term profit maximization.
  • 97
    • 70149112792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is not to say that it would be difficult to put together a scenario in which an expanded corporate electorate (that included constituencies other than shareholders) had a preference profile that led to an intransitive outcome. The point here is that devising such a scenario with shareholders alone is relatively easy, even assuming an identical interest in wealth maximization, and the burden is on those who advance the argument from Arrow's theorem that there is a marked difference in the probability of acyclic outcomes with an expanded electorate
    • This is not to say that it would be difficult to put together a scenario in which an expanded corporate electorate (that included constituencies other than shareholders) had a preference profile that led to an intransitive outcome. The point here is that devising such a scenario with shareholders alone is relatively easy, even assuming an identical interest in wealth maximization, and the burden is on those who advance the argument from Arrow's theorem that there is a marked difference in the probability of acyclic outcomes with an expanded electorate.
  • 98
    • 70149121931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 299-304 (providing examples of how the Condorcet method, the amendment procedure, the Borda count, and cumulative voting systems all fall prey to Arrow's theorem).
    • See Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 299-304 (providing examples of how the Condorcet method, the amendment procedure, the Borda count, and cumulative voting systems all fall prey to Arrow's theorem).
  • 99
    • 70149124313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Hayden, supra note 29, at 109-132 (arguing that the level of spectrum agreement required in Voting Rights Act claims, while not complete, is sufficient to reduce the incidence of cycling to near zero)
    • See, e.g., Hayden, supra note 29, at 109-132 (arguing that the level of spectrum agreement required in Voting Rights Act claims, while not complete, is sufficient to reduce the incidence of cycling to near zero);
  • 100
    • 84869632876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 312 (arguing that the racial bloc voting requirements of certain claims under the Voting Rights Act may represent a case of "naturally occurring" spectrum agreement that decreases the incidence of cycling). As will be discussed infra, many groups of people associated through a polity or a corporation may have sufficiently common reference points to greatly reduce the incidence of intransitivities
    • Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 312 (arguing that the racial bloc voting requirements of certain claims under the Voting Rights Act may represent a case of "naturally occurring" spectrum agreement that decreases the incidence of cycling). As will be discussed infra, many groups of people associated through a polity or a corporation may have sufficiently common reference points to greatly reduce the incidence of intransitivities.
  • 101
    • 0002581895 scopus 로고
    • Partial single-peakedness: An extension and clarification
    • explaining that "empirical observations of a wide variety of actual collective decisionmaking processes indicate that cyclical majorities are very rare"
    • See Scott L. Feld & Bernard Grofman, Partial Single-Peakedness: An Extension and Clarification, 51 PUB. CHOICE 71, 71 (1986) (explaining that "empirical observations of a wide variety of actual collective decisionmaking processes indicate that cyclical majorities are very rare");
    • (1986) 51 Pub. Choice 71 , vol.71
    • Feld, S.L.1    Grofman, B.2
  • 102
    • 85055296600 scopus 로고
    • Public choice, Civic republicanism, American politics: Perspectives of a "reasonable choice" modeler
    • (noting that cycles are much harder to find than early social choice models had predicted)
    • Bernard Grofman, Public Choice, Civic Republicanism, and American Politics: Perspectives of a "Reasonable Choice" Modeler, 71 TEX. L. REV. 1541, 1553 (1993) (noting that cycles are much harder to find than early social choice models had predicted).
    • (1993) 71 TEX. L. REV. , vol.1541 , pp. 1553
    • Grofman, B.1
  • 103
    • 0014311250 scopus 로고
    • A mathematical solution for the probability of the paradox of voting
    • See Richard G. Niemi & Herbert F. Weisberg, A Mathematical Solution for the Probability of the Paradox of Voting, 13 BEHAV. SCI. 317, 321 (1968).
    • (1968) 13 BEHAV. SCI. , vol.317 , pp. 321
    • Niemi, R.G.1    Weisberg, H.F.2
  • 104
    • 70149099364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 322 & tbl.2
    • See id. at 322 & tbl.2.
  • 105
    • 70149119686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hayden, supra note 29, at 107-08
    • See Hayden, supra note 29, at 107-08;
  • 106
    • 84869601449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 306-07. Although the term "spectrum agreement" seems to imply some express understanding between voters, it is enough that voter preferences may be arrayed on a common continuum, regardless of whether the voters agreed ahead of time or, indeed, even knew about the agreement
    • Hayden, Note, supra note 31, at 306-07. Although the term "spectrum agreement" seems to imply some express understanding between voters, it is enough that voter preferences may be arrayed on a common continuum, regardless of whether the voters agreed ahead of time or, indeed, even knew about the agreement.
  • 107
    • 70149123445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hayden, supra note 29, at 107
    • Hayden, supra note 29, at 107.
  • 108
    • 70149099772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 109
    • 70149095715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RIKER, supra note 25, at 123-128
    • See RIKER, supra note 25, at 123-128
  • 110
    • 70149093439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 126
    • Id. at 126.
  • 111
    • 70149110023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BLACK, THEORY, supra note 19, at 19-25 (discussing proofs of theorems and examples involving single-peaked preference curves);
    • See BLACK, THEORY, supra note 19, at 19-25 (discussing proofs of theorems and examples involving single-peaked preference curves);
  • 112
    • 0010160731 scopus 로고
    • (discussing group voting on two separate issues and proving there can be at most one majority decision
    • DUNCAN BLACK & R.A. NEWING, Committee Decisions with Complementary Valuation 19-28 (1951) (discussing group voting on two separate issues and proving there can be at most one majority decision);
    • (1951) Committee Decisions with Complementary Valuation , pp. 19-28
    • Black, D.1    Newing, R.A.2
  • 113
    • 0001786352 scopus 로고
    • 56 J. Pol. Econ. (explaining and depicting a single-peaked preference profile for a voter with one most desired alternative
    • Duncan Black, On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making, 56 J. pol. econ. 23, 23-24 & fig.l (1948) (explaining and depicting a single-peaked preference profile for a voter with one most desired alternative).
    • (1948) On the Rationale of Group Decision-making , vol.23 , pp. 23-24
    • Black, D.1
  • 114
    • 70149120968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BLACK, THEORY, supra note 19, at 125-129
    • See BLACK, THEORY, supra note 19, at 125-129.
  • 115
    • 70149105700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 116
    • 0001653838 scopus 로고
    • A Possibility Theorem on Majority Decisions
    • See Amartya K. Sen, A Possibility Theorem on Majority Decisions, 34 ECONOMETRICA 491, 492-495 (1966).
    • (1966) 34 Econometrica , vol.491 , pp. 492-495
    • Sen, A.K.1
  • 117
    • 70149084785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 492
    • Id. at 492.
  • 118
    • 84869626448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Feld & Grofman, supra note 75, at 72-73 ("[1] f even one individual has non-single- peaked preferences then there can be a paradox of cyclical majorities.")
    • See Feld & Grofman, supra note 75, at 72-73 ("[1] f even one individual has non-single- peaked preferences then there can be a paradox of cyclical majorities.");
  • 119
    • 0012203902 scopus 로고
    • Majority decision-making with partial unidimensionality
    • (finding that for "majority voting [to] yield a transitive social ordering.... the preference ordering of every individual must be single-peaked"
    • Richard G. Niemi, Majority Decision-Making with Partial Unidimensionality, 63 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 488, 488 (1969) (finding that for "majority voting [to] yield a transitive social ordering.... the preference ordering of every individual must be single-peaked").
    • (1969) 63 AM. POL. SCI. REV. , vol.488 , pp. 488
    • Niemi, R.G.1
  • 120
    • 70149118985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hayden, supra note 29, at 125-126 (providing an example of a preference profile where sixteen of seventeen preference orders are single-peaked yet a majority vote produces an intransitive outcome).
    • See Hayden, supra note 29, at 125-126 (providing an example of a preference profile where sixteen of seventeen preference orders are single-peaked yet a majority vote produces an intransitive outcome).
  • 121
    • 0001210437 scopus 로고
    • On a class of equilibrium conditions for majority rule
    • Gerald H. Kramer, On a Class of Equilibrium Conditions for Majority Rule, 41 econometrica 285, 285 (1973).
    • (1973) 41 Econometrica , vol.285 , pp. 285
    • Kramer, G.H.1
  • 122
    • 70149092205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Niemi, supra note 88, at 488
    • See Niemi, supra note 88, at 488.
  • 123
    • 70149099155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 493-94
    • Id. at 493-94;
  • 124
    • 70149097787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Hayden, supra note 29, at 127-28 (discussing Niemi's findings). This is counterintuitive because the likelihood of transitive outcomes decreases as you increase the number of individuals in a profile assuming an impartial culture
    • see also Hayden, supra note 29, at 127-28 (discussing Niemi's findings). This is counterintuitive because the likelihood of transitive outcomes decreases as you increase the number of individuals in a profile assuming an impartial culture.
  • 125
    • 70149092332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Niemi, supra note 88, at 493-94
    • See Niemi, supra note 88, at 493-94.
  • 126
    • 0015811625 scopus 로고
    • Voter concordance, simple majorities, and group decision methods
    • See, e.g., Peter C. Fishburn, Voter Concordance, Simple Majorities, and Group Decision Methods, 18 BEHAV. SCI. 364, 371-372 (1973);
    • (1973) 18 Behav. Sci. , vol.364 , pp. 371-372
    • Fishburn, P.C.1
  • 128
    • 70149089712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Hayden, supra note 29, at 128-30 (discussing these two studies)
    • see also Hayden, supra note 29, at 128-30 (discussing these two studies).
  • 129
    • 70149100879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Feld & Grofman, supra note 75, at 73-79 (extending Niemi's result and finding that a social preference order will be transitive if there is more than a fifty percent probability that a randomly chosen individual would align the alternatives along one existing continuum)
    • See Feld & Grofman, supra note 75, at 73-79 (extending Niemi's result and finding that a social preference order will be transitive if there is more than a fifty percent probability that a randomly chosen individual would align the alternatives along one existing continuum)
  • 130
    • 70149102447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Niemi, supra note 88, at 494
    • Niemi, supra note 88, at 494.
  • 131
    • 70149091958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FROHLICH & OPPENHEIMER, supra note 8, at 19-20
    • See FROHLICH & OPPENHEIMER, supra note 8, at 19-20.
  • 132
    • 70149088400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405.
    • Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 9, at 405.
  • 133
    • 70149096208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id
  • 134
    • 70149083043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Grofman, supra note 75, at 1552
    • See Grofman, supra note 75, at 1552.
  • 135
    • 70149086909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The majority-voting movement: Curtailing shareholder disenfranchisement in corporate director elections
    • Some shareholders have pressed corporations to change their voting rules so that a director must win a majority of the votes cast in order to win the seat
    • Joshua R. Mourning, Note, The Majority-Voting Movement: Curtailing Shareholder Disenfranchisement in Corporate Director Elections, 85 WASH. U. L. REV. 1143, 1144 (2007). Some shareholders have pressed corporations to change their voting rules so that a director must win a majority of the votes cast in order to win the seat.
    • (2007) 85 WASH. U. L. REV. , vol.1143 , pp. 1144
    • Mourning, J.R.1
  • 136
    • 84869614467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally id. at 1143-46. However, even under such a "majority-vote" regime, a director who fails to get a majority will stay on until a replacement is chosen or until a majority of shareholders vote to remove the person
    • See generally id. at 1143-46. However, even under such a "majority-vote" regime, a director who fails to get a majority will stay on until a replacement is chosen or until a majority of shareholders vote to remove the person.
  • 137
    • 84859598055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (stating that "[e]ach director shall hold office until such director's successor is elected and qualified or until such director's earlier resignation or removal"). However, some companies have established resignation policies that require directors to resign if they are not elected by the shareholders. Mourning, supra, at 1182-1185. For criticism of majority voting as an ineffective reform
    • See DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 141(b) (2002) (stating that "[e]ach director shall hold office until such director's successor is elected and qualified or until such director's earlier resignation or removal"). However, some companies have established resignation policies that require directors to resign if they are not elected by the shareholders. Mourning, supra, at 1182-85. For criticism of majority voting as an ineffective reform
    • (2002) Del. Code. Ann. , vol.8 , pp. 141
  • 138
    • 70149124095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Majority voting in director elections: A simple, Direct, and Swift Solution?
    • For criticism of majority voting as an ineffective reform, see Vincent Falcone, Note, Majority Voting in Director Elections: A Simple, Direct, and Swift Solution?, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 844, 881-882
    • 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. , vol.844 , pp. 881-882
    • Falcone, V.1
  • 139
    • 70149111486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (allowing such a staggered election procedure)
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 141(d) (allowing such a staggered election procedure).
    • DEL. CODE. ANN. , vol.8 , pp. 141
  • 140
    • 70149097333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For some background on structure-induced equilibria, see, e.g., RIKER, supra note 25, at 188-192
    • For some background on structure-induced equilibria, see, e.g., RIKER, supra note 25, at 188-192
  • 141
    • 70149102679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grofman, supra note 75, at 1561-1562
    • Grofman, supra note 75, at 1561-1562.
  • 142
    • 70149091277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gordon, supra note 58, at 372-373
    • See Gordon, supra note 58, at 372-373.
  • 144
    • 58149131557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Management always wins the close ones
    • For an empirical examination of the power of incumbent boards to influence elections, see Yair Listokin
    • For an empirical examination of the power of incumbent boards to influence elections, see Yair Listokin, Management Always Wins the Close Ones, 10 Am. L. & ECON. REV. 159 (2008).
    • (2008) 10 Am L. & ECON. REV. , pp. 159


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.