메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 107, Issue 8, 2009, Pages 1431-1444

Fault in contract law

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 66749182684     PISSN: 00262234     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (13)

References (53)
  • 1
    • 21844526836 scopus 로고
    • The fault lines in contract damages
    • George Cohen's article is the most comprehensive discussion; however, he focuses on damages rules, which I will for the most part ignore. George M. Cohen, The Fault Lines in Contract Damages, 80 VA. L. REV. 1225, 1237-1239 (1994).
    • (1994) 80 Va. L. Rev. , vol.1225 , pp. 1237-1239
    • Cohen, G.M.1
  • 2
    • 21844526836 scopus 로고
    • The fault lines in contract damages
    • On this, see George M. Cohen, The Fault Lines in Contract Damages, 80 VA. L. REV. 1225, (1994), id. at 1245-1256
    • (1994) 80 Va. L. Rev. , vol.1225 , pp. 1245-1256
    • Cohen, G.M.1
  • 3
    • 0033192196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Damage measures for inadvertent breach of contract
    • I use a simplified version of the model that has been developed in the literature. See Lucian Arye Bebchuk & I.P.L. Png
    • I use a simplified version of the model that has been developed in the literature. See Lucian Arye Bebchuk & I.P.L. Png, Damage Measures for Inadvertent Breach of Contract, 19 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 319 (1999);
    • (1999) 19 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.319
  • 4
    • 67649349232 scopus 로고
    • Unity in tort, contract, and property: The model of precaution
    • Robert Cooter, Unity in Tort, Contract, and Property: The Model of Precaution, 73 CAL. L. REV. 1 (1985);
    • (1985) 73 Cal. L. Rev. , vol.1
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 5
    • 0009070748 scopus 로고
    • Performance, reliance, and one-sided information
    • Richard Craswell, Performance, Reliance, and One-sided Information, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 365 (1989);
    • (1989) 18 J. Legal Stud. , vol.365
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 6
    • 0008992534 scopus 로고
    • Precontractual investigation as an optimal precaution problem
    • Richard Craswell, Precontractual Investigation as an Optimal Precaution Problem, 17 J. LEGAL STUD. 401 (1988);
    • (1988) 17 J. Legal Stud. , vol.401
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 7
    • 66749089484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reliance, reputation and breach of contract
    • Lewis A. Kornhauser, Reliance, Reputation and Breach of Contract, 26 J.L. & ECON. 691 (1983). These articles focus on the extent to which different damage measures provide the promisor with proper incentives to take precautions. With a few exceptions to be noted, they do not discuss whether the law should use a fault-based liability rule.
    • 26 J.L. & Econ. , vol.691 , pp. 1983
    • Kornhauser, L.A.1
  • 8
    • 66749105961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • L), and d would need to be greater than this level of investment, instead of greater than V, as in the text.
  • 9
    • 66749118584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Cooter, supra note 3, at 31.
    • Supra Note , vol.3 , pp. 31
    • Cooter1
  • 10
    • 0013425724 scopus 로고
    • Penalties and the just compensation principle: Some notes on an enforcement model and a theory of efficient breach
    • See Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Liquidated Damages, Penalties and the Just Compensation Principle: Some Notes on an Enforcement Model and a Theory of Efficient Breach, 11 COLUM. L. REV. 554 (1977). This point has also been made about supracompensatory damage measures, such as punitive damages.
    • (1977) 11 Colum. L. Rev. , vol.554
    • Goetz, C.J.1    Scott, R.E.2    Damages, L.3
  • 11
    • 0009037768 scopus 로고
    • Contract remedies, renegotiation, and the theory of efficient breach
    • See, e.g., Richard Craswell, Contract Remedies, Renegotiation, and the Theory of Efficient Breach, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 629, 643-44 (1988);
    • (1988) 61 S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.629 , pp. 643-644
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 12
    • 0009905372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deterrence and damages: The multiplier principle and its alternatives
    • Richard Craswell, Deterrence and Damages: The Multiplier Principle and Its Alternatives, 97 MICH. L. REV. 2185, 2229 (1999).
    • (1999) 97 Mich. L. Rev. , vol.2185 , pp. 2229
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 13
    • 0002775690 scopus 로고
    • Strict liability versus negligence
    • Except in the context of products liability, where the normal justification for strict liability is that buyers are unlikely to discover information about the riskiness of the product except (implicitly) through the price system. See Steven. Shavell, Strict Liability versus Negligence, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 20-22 (1980).
    • (1980) 9 J. Legal Stud. , vol.1 , pp. 20-22
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 15
    • 66749191764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A further advantage of the negligence regime is that it would permit courts to award specific performance without deterring efficient breach. Under the negligence regime, specific performance would be awarded only if the breach was inefficient (or efficient but resulting from inefficient investment).
  • 16
    • 66749126162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS Ch. 11, Introductory N. (1981).
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS ch. 11, introductory n. (1981).
  • 18
    • 78649655692 scopus 로고
    • Fault in the common law of contract
    • Maarten Bos & Ian. Brownlie eds.
    • see also G.H. Treitel, Fault in the Common Law of Contract, in LIBER AMICORUM FOR THE RT. HON. LORD WILBERFORCE 185 (Maarten Bos & Ian. Brownlie eds., 1987).
    • (1987) Liber Amicorum for the Rt. Hon. Lord Wilberforce , vol.185
    • Treitel, G.H.1
  • 19
    • 0002870467 scopus 로고
    • Impossibility and related doctrines in contract law: An economic analysis
    • Posner and Rosenfield state as follows: The foregoing discussion indicates the factors that courts and legislatures might consider in devising efficient rules for the discharge of contracts. An easy case for discharge would be one where ( 1) the promisor asking to be discharged could not reasonably have prevented the event rendering his performance uneconomical, and (2) the promisee could have insured against the occurrence of the event at lower cost than the promisor because the promisee (a) was in a better position to estimate both (i) the probability of the event's occurrence and (ii) the magnitude of the loss if it did occur, and (b) could have self-insured, whereas the promisor would have had to buy more costly market insurance. Richard A. Posner & Andrew M. Rosenfield, Impossibility and Related Doctrines in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 83, 92 (1977). As will become clear, my argument is that (1) should be sufficient for discharge and (2) is irrelevant.
    • (1977) 6 J. Legal Stud. , vol.83 , pp. 92
    • Posner, R.A.1    Rosenfield, A.M.2
  • 21
    • 0012853585 scopus 로고
    • The doctrine of commercial impracticability in a second-best world
    • Alan O. Sykes, The Doctrine of Commercial Impracticability in a Second-best World, 19 J. LEGAL STUD. 43, 66-67 (1990).
    • (1990) 19 J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.43 , pp. 66-67
    • Sykes, A.O.1
  • 22
    • 66749161732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Am. Trading & Prod. Coip. v. Shell Int'l Marine Ltd., 453 F.2d 939 (2d Cir. 1972)
    • See, e.g., Am. Trading & Prod. Coip. v. Shell Int'l Marine Ltd., 453 F.2d 939 (2d Cir. 1972).
  • 23
    • 84868991852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 261 (emphasis added)
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 261 (emphasis added).
  • 24
    • 66749183794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Karno v. Bourbon Burlesque Club, Inc., 05-0241, p. 5 (La. App. 4 Cir. 5/10/06); 931 So. 2d 1111, 1115 (quoting Karno v. Joseph Fein Caterer, Inc., 02-1269, pp. 9-10 (La.App. 4 Cir. 4/16/03); 846 So. 2d 105, 110) (emphasis omitted)
    • Karno v. Bourbon Burlesque Club, Inc., 05-0241, p. 5 (La. App. 4 Cir. 5/10/06); 931 So. 2d 1111, 1115 (quoting Karno v. Joseph Fein Caterer, Inc., 02-1269, pp. 9-10 (La.App. 4 Cir. 4/16/03); 846 So. 2d 105, 110) (emphasis omitted).
  • 25
    • 84868970216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 241(e)
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 241(e).
  • 27
    • 66749153450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 931 So. 3d at 1117. 19. 335 N.E.2d 320 (N.Y. 1975)
    • 931 So. 3d at 1117. 19. 335 N.E.2d 320 (N.Y. 1975).
  • 28
    • 66749188001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 322-323
    • Id. at 322-323
  • 29
    • 66749108395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 32.
    • Id. at 321.
  • 30
    • 84868991847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, the court expressed doubt about whether such a test would be feasible. Id. at 323 ("In any event, 'economic feasibility', an expression subject to many interpretations, would not be a precise or reliable test.")
    • However, the court expressed doubt about whether such a test would be feasible. Id. at 323 ("In any event, 'economic feasibility', an expression subject to many interpretations, would not be a precise or reliable test.").
  • 31
    • 0000450443 scopus 로고
    • Principles of relational contracts
    • Cf. Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089 (1981). Goetz & Scott similarly argue that in such "relational contracts," courts cite the doctrines of good faith and best efforts when they are really just teying to determine whether continued performance would be value maximizing. For a recent case that can be given this interpretation,
    • (1981) 67 Va. L. Rev. , vol.1089
    • Goetz, C.J.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 32
    • 66749131591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Market Street Assoes, v. Frey, 941 F.2d 588 (7th Cir. 1991) (holding that failure to inform other party of its contractual rights violated duty of good faith)
    • see Market Street Assoes, v. Frey, 941 F.2d 588 (7th Cir. 1991) (holding that failure to inform other party of its contractual rights violated duty of good faith).
  • 33
    • 84868975226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 227 cmt. b, illus. 2 (1981)
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 227 cmt. b, illus. 2 (1981).
  • 34
    • 66749107825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 35
    • 66749153449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To be sure, if the contract explicitly provides for a negligence standard of liability-that is, it says that the promisor must take cost-justified actions-then "strict" enforcement of such a contract would produce the same outcome as fault-based enforcement.
  • 36
    • 66749103495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 129 N.E. 889 (N.Y. 1921)
    • 129 N.E. 889 (N.Y. 1921).
  • 37
    • 66749136655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 890
    • Id. at 890.
  • 38
    • 66749129912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 39
    • 66749169748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. The brand was printed on the outside of the pipe in intervals but the pipe was otherwise indistinguishable from other pipes
    • Id. The brand was printed on the outside of the pipe in intervals but the pipe was otherwise indistinguishable from other pipes.
  • 40
    • 66749182488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 41
    • 66749163812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 585 N.E.2d 315 (Mass. 1992)
    • 585 N.E.2d 315 (Mass. 1992).
  • 42
    • 66749146359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 316-318
    • Id. at 316-318
  • 44
    • 84868975228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39 (Tentative Draft No. 4, 2005). For similar principles, see RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 357 (1981)
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39 (Tentative Draft No. 4, 2005). For similar principles, see RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 357 (1981).
  • 45
    • 66749158819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Special cases include the use of damage multipliers when breach is difficult to detect. See Craswell, supra note 6, at 2230.
    • Supra Note , vol.6 , pp. 2230
    • Craswell1
  • 46
    • 0000626130 scopus 로고
    • The myth that promisees prefer supracompensatory remedies: An analysis of contracting for damage measures
    • See Alan Schwartz, The Myth that Promisees Prefer Supracompensatory Remedies: An Analysis of Contracting for Damage Measures, 100 YALE L.J. 369 (1990).
    • (1990) 100 Yale L.J. , vol.369
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 47
    • 66749084734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Again, a similar result can be found in the literature on tort law. See, e.g., Shavell, supra note 7.
    • Supra Note , vol.7
    • Shavell1
  • 48
    • 66749112066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In some cases, however, the burden is on the victim. For example, in interpretation cases, the burden is effectively on the victim to prove the relevant interpretation.
  • 50
    • 66749120393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shavell, supra note 7. The two rules do not always lead to identical results, of course; but even when they do not, each rule is superior under equally plausible (but different) conditions.
    • Supra Note , vol.7
    • Shavell1
  • 51
    • 66749131590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Damages for non-performance and the fault principle
    • German contract law is a fault-based system but fault is presumed, and in many settings there are strict-liability exceptions to the general rule of fault. For a very helpful discussion, see Karl Riesenhuber, Damages for Non-Performance and the Fault Principle, 4 EUR. REV. CONT. L. 119 (2008). So American and German law have different starting points but may well end up at the same midpoint. Riesenhuber identifies a similar mixing of fault and strict-liability principles in many other bodies of law, including French and Japanese.
    • (2008) 4 Eur. Rev. Cont. L. , vol.119
    • Riesenhuber, K.1
  • 52
    • 66749131590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Damages for non-performance and the fault principle
    • Karl Riesenhuber, Damages for Non-Performance and the Fault Principle, 4 EUR. REV. CONT. L. 119 (2008), Id.;
    • (2008) 4 Eur. Rev. Cont. L. , vol.119
    • Riesenhuber, K.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.