메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 107, Issue 8, 2009, Pages 1397-1412

A comparative fault defense in contract law

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 66749119890     PISSN: 00262234     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (15)

References (48)
  • 1
    • 84868978704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law of torts § 201 (2001). Dobbs also notes that several states had adopted it earlier
    • l DAN B. DOBBS, THE LAW OF TORTS § 201 (2001). Dobbs also notes that several states had adopted it earlier. Id.
    • Id.
    • Dobbs, L.D.B.1
  • 4
    • 66749126978 scopus 로고
    • For willingness to apply the defense to contracts, see
    • For refusal to apply the CFD to contracts, see Fortier v. Dona Anna Plaza Partners, 747 F.2d 1324 (10th Cir. 1984). For willingness to apply the defense to contracts, see
    • (1984) Fortier V. Dona Anna Plaza Partners, 747 F.2d , vol.10 , pp. 1324
  • 5
    • 66749131054 scopus 로고
    • Mo. Ct. App. There is an increasing willingness to apply the CFD to implied-warranty cases. See
    • American Mortgage Inv. Co. v. Hardin-Stockton Corp., 671 S.W.2d 283 (Mo. Ct. App. 1984). There is an increasing willingness to apply the CFD to implied-warranty cases. See
    • (1984) American Mortgage Inv. Co. V. Hardin-Stockton Corp., 671 S.W.2d , pp. 283
  • 7
    • 31444445485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and accompanying text.
    • infra notes 19-21 and accompanying text.
    • Infra Notes , pp. 19-21
  • 8
    • 0348163029 scopus 로고
    • For my earlier arguments calling for the adoption of the CFD by Commonwealth and European countries see Ariel Porat, (focusing primarily on contract law in England, Canada, Australia, France and Germany). The efficiency argument that is the subject of Part II of the current paper was not made in the earlier paper.
    • For my earlier arguments calling for the adoption of the CFD by Commonwealth and European countries see Ariel Porat, Contributory Negligence in Contract Law: Toward a Principled Approach, 28 U. BRIT. COLUM. L. REV. 141 (1994) (focusing primarily on contract law in England, Canada, Australia, France and Germany). The efficiency argument that is the subject of Part II of the current paper was not made in the earlier paper.
    • (1994) Contributory Negligence in Contract Law: Toward A Principled Approach, 28 U. BRIT. COLUM. L. REV. , pp. 141
  • 9
    • 66749132183 scopus 로고
    • This example is an adaptation of Lesmeister v
    • in which the court apportioned damages between the parties.
    • This example is an adaptation of Lesmeister v. Dilly, 330 N.W.2d 95 (Minn. 1983), in which the court apportioned damages between the parties.
    • (1983) Dilly, 330 N.W.2d 95 Minn.
  • 10
    • 84868994685 scopus 로고
    • (Posner, J.) ("The parties to a contract are embarked on a cooperative venture, and a minimum of cooperativeness in the event unforeseen problems arise at the performance stage is required even if not an explicit duty of the contract."); RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 205 cmt. d (1981) (asserting that noncooperation could be considered a breach of the duty of good faith).
    • E.g., AMPAT/Midwest, Inc. v. Ill. Tool Works Inc., 896 F.2d 1035, 1041 (7th Cir. 1990) (Posner, J.) ("The parties to a contract are embarked on a cooperative venture, and a minimum of cooperativeness in the event unforeseen problems arise at the performance stage is required even if not an explicit duty of the contract."); RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 205 cmt. d (1981) (asserting that noncooperation could be considered a breach of the duty of good faith).
    • (1990) AMPAT/Midwest, Inc. V. Ill. Tool Works Inc., 896 F.2d , vol.1041 , pp. 1035
  • 12
    • 66749139854 scopus 로고
    • Mkt. St. Assoes. Ltd. P'ship v. Frey, 941 F.2d 588
    • 7th Cir. In this case, one party refused to fulfill her duties and the other party could have easily corrected the mistake. Id. at 596-97. In reversing summary judgment, Judge Posner ruled that the contracting parties bore a duty not to take deliberate advantage of each others' oversights concerning their rights and duties under the contract.
    • Mkt. St. Assoes. Ltd. P'ship v. Frey, 941 F.2d 588, 594 (7th Cir. 1991). In this case, one party refused to fulfill her duties and the other party could have easily corrected the mistake. Id. at 596-97. In reversing summary judgment, Judge Posner ruled that the contracting parties bore a duty not to take deliberate advantage of each others' oversights concerning their rights and duties under the contract. Id. at 597-598
    • (1991) Id. at , vol.594 , pp. 597-598
  • 13
    • 0742323938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of the duty of disclosure generally, as well as a more specific discussion of the role of efficiency and morality in shaping this duty, see Melvin A. Eisenberg
    • For an overview of the duty of disclosure generally, as well as a more specific discussion of the role of efficiency and morality in shaping this duty, see Melvin A. Eisenberg, Disclosure in Contract Law, 91 CAL. L. REV. 1645 (2003).
    • (2003) Disclosure in Contract Law, 91 CAL. L. REV. , pp. 1645
  • 15
    • 66749085890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The following illustrates numerically the principles behind Example 4: assume at the time of contracting that the probability of losing $1000 was 0.1, yielding an expected loss of $100, but that a week after contracting, the probability of loss increased to 1, yielding an expected loss of $1000. Assume now that by investing $500 in precautions, A could prevent the breach. So long as A assumes the expected loss to be $100, he won't make this investment, whereas if he is aware that it has risen to $1000, he will. Since efficiency requires making the investment, efficiency also dictates that B should convey the information regarding his high potential loss to A.
  • 16
  • 18
    • 66749141686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Another situation in which the Hadley v. Baxendale principle would allow recovery, and where applying the CFD could be valuable, is one in which the high potential losses are foreseeable (objectively) but unforeseen (subjectively) by the promisor at both the time of contracting and later on. Here, too, if the promisee realizes during performance that the promisor is unaware of the high potential loss entailed by a breach, efficiency requires conveying the information to the promisor. The CFD would provide incentives to achieve this result.
  • 19
    • 66749129339 scopus 로고
    • This example is an adaptation of
    • Colo. Ct. App.
    • This example is an adaptation of Carfield & Sons, Inc. v. Cowling, 616 P.2d 1008 (Colo. Ct. App. 1980).
    • (1980) Carfield & Sons, Inc. V. Cowling, 616 P.2d , vol.1008
  • 20
    • 84868996400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [A] was obligated to request adequate assurance of performance. if [B] then refused to provide that assurance, [A] could treat the contract as terminated."
    • There, the court stated that in order to avoid liability
    • There, the court stated that in order to avoid liability, "[A] was obligated to request adequate assurance of performance. If [B] then refused to provide that assurance, [A] could treat the contract as terminated." Id at 1010.
    • Id at , pp. 1010
  • 22
    • 84868960254 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 350 cmt. f
    • Id. § 350 cmt. f.
  • 23
    • 84868979033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "[a] plaintiff may be guilty of contributory negligence... even if the 'very purpose' of the duty owed by the defendant is to protect the plaintiff's property."
    • The High Court of Australia considered a similar situation. While refusing to apply the CFD to contracts, it maintained that 197 C.L.R.
    • The High Court of Australia considered a similar situation. While refusing to apply the CFD to contracts, it maintained that "[a] plaintiff may be guilty of contributory negligence ... even if the 'very purpose' of the duty owed by the defendant is to protect the plaintiff's property." Astley v. Austrust Ltd. (1999) 197 C.L.R. 1, 14.
    • (1999) Astley V. Austrust Ltd. , vol.1 , pp. 14
  • 25
    • 66749108398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In that case, the plaintiff suffered losses due to a fire from a malfunctioning heater. Id. at 323. the defendants, who had manufactured, designed, and installed the heater, were found liable for breach of implied warranties of fitness and suitability
    • In that case, the plaintiff suffered losses due to a fire from a malfunctioning heater. Id. at 323. The defendants, who had manufactured, designed, and installed the heater, were found liable for breach of implied warranties of fitness and suitability. Id. at 329.
    • Id. at , pp. 329
  • 26
    • 66749098615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The court applied the CFD and reduced damages, finding that the plaintiff had been contributorily negligent in not shutting down, the heater despite warnings of the impending hazard
    • The court applied the CFD and reduced damages, finding that the plaintiff had been contributorily negligent in not shutting down, the heater despite warnings of the impending hazard. Id.
    • Id.
  • 28
    • 84868963687 scopus 로고
    • Karl v. Bryant Air Conditioning Co., 331 N.W.2d 456 Mich
    • (applying a comparative fault defense)
    • See, e.g., Karl v. Bryant Air Conditioning Co., 331 N.W.2d 456 (Mich. 1982) (applying a comparative fault defense); Signal Oil á Gas Co., 572 S.W.2d. 320 (same).
    • (1982) Signal Oil Á Gas Co., 572 S.W.2d. , vol.320
  • 30
    • 0043172221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When noncooperation or overreliance is not observable or verifiable, other mechanisms can be employed to provide both parties with efficient incentives. See, e.g
    • (proposing a mechanism for creating full liability for both, the promisor and promisee that would result in efficient incentives for both).
    • When noncooperation or overreliance is not observable or verifiable, other mechanisms can be employed to provide both parties with efficient incentives. See, e.g., Robert Cooter & Ariel Porat, Anti-insurance, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. 203 (2002) (proposing a mechanism for creating full liability for both, the promisor and promisee that would result in efficient incentives for both).
    • (2002) Anti-insurance, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.203
    • Cooter, R.1    Porat, A.2
  • 31
    • 66749125026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The parties will sometimes prefer to leave the question of cooperation open for future negotiation. However, that can only be done when, the costs of renegotiation are not prohibitively high.
  • 32
    • 66749185545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sometimes the parties may overcome this hurdle by imposing a duty (or burden) of cooperation on the promisee and a duty for the promisor to compensate the promisee for his costs. But since this solution could only work for some cases (for example, it would not work when, transaction costs involved in measuring the costs of cooperation and in transferring payments for cooperation are high), it cannot serve as a default rule.
  • 33
    • 66749134338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In different terminology, under certain circumstances the promisee can be the cheapest cost avoider of the breach, while the promisor is the cheapest cost avoider of the circumstances giving rise to the need to avoid the breach.
  • 35
    • 66749184392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But if most of the costs are fixed and their magnitudes are not dependent on the promisor's behavior, a different conclusion could be warranted
    • But if most of the costs are fixed and their magnitudes are not dependent on the promisor's behavior, a different conclusion could be warranted. See supra Section II.B.l.b.
    • See Supra Section II.B.l.b.
  • 36
    • 66749138444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But sometimes the promisee may refrain from cooperating to induce a breach and find a way out of the contract; placing an expected burden on him, equivalent to the costs of cooperation, would not be sufficient to deter him efficiently.
    • But sometimes the promisee may refrain from cooperating to induce a breach and find a way out of the contract; placing an expected burden on him, equivalent to the costs of cooperation, would not be sufficient to deter him efficiently.
  • 37
    • 66749174291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that instead of leaving some unrecoverable losses on the promisee's shoulders (as the CFD mandates), the law could also make him liable for some of the promisor's losses (as though the promisor and promisee were both responsible for the breach, and its consequences). However, the latter solution would add the administrative costs of measuring the promisor's losses.
  • 38
    • 66749104660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The distinction, between high-cost and low-cost overreliance is analogous to that applied to high-cost and low-cost cooperation
    • The distinction, between high-cost and low-cost overreliance is analogous to that applied to high-cost and low-cost cooperation. See supra Section II.B.1.
    • See Supra Section II.B.1.
  • 40
    • 66749156209 scopus 로고
    • which suggests a rule under which the promisor would state the probability of a breach, and on which the promisee would rely accordingly. For various doctrines in prevailing contract law that reduce overreliance
    • Richard Craswell, Performance, Reliance, and One-sided Information, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 365, 367-68 (1989), which suggests a rule under which the promisor would state the probability of a breach, and on which the promisee would rely accordingly. For various doctrines in prevailing contract law that reduce overreliance,
    • (1989) Performance, Reliance, and One-sided Information, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.365 , pp. 367-368
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 43
    • 0242511574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the argument that overreliance is not a severe or prevalent problem, in contract law, see
    • But note that Eisenberg and McDonnell consider the cases represented by Example 6 to be
    • For the argument that overreliance is not a severe or prevalent problem, in contract law, see Melvin A. Eisenberg & Brett H. McDonnell, Expectation Damages and the Theory of Overreliance, 54 HASTINGS L.J. 1335 (2003). But note that Eisenberg and McDonnell consider the cases represented by Example 6 to be
    • (2003) Expectation Damages and the Theory of Overreliance, 54 HASTINGS L.J. , vol.1335
    • Eisenberg, M.A.1    McDonnell, B.H.2
  • 44
    • 66749107091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Out of the realm of overreliance
    • "out of the realm of overreliance." Id. at 1346.
    • Id. at 1346.
  • 46
    • 66749162841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Knowing the chance of performance increases if he overrelies, the promisee may increase his reliance even more when the promisor is aware of his overreliance. This possibility notwithstanding, when avoidance of overreliance is low cost and the risk of breach is significant in spite of his overreliance, the promisee will prefer to restrain his reliance.
  • 47
    • 66749160564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This argument seems to be more persuasive in the context of Example 6 than in Examples 7 and 8, since asymmetric information and control are more prevalent in the former.
  • 48
    • 66749085888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the outcome when cooperation or avoiding overreliance is low cost and the probability of a breach, without cooperation, or avoidance of overreliance is high
    • This is the outcome when cooperation or avoiding overreliance is low cost and the probability of a breach, without cooperation, or avoidance of overreliance is high. See supra Section II.B.2 (providing a numerical example).
    • See Supra Section II.B.2 (Providing A Numerical Example).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.