메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 75, Issue 2, 2008, Pages 623-635

Difference-in-differences analysis in antitrust: A cautionary note

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 57049104620     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (14)

References (23)
  • 1
    • 57049152112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical Methods in Antitrust Litigation: Review and Critique, 1 AM. L
    • For a discussion of this methodology, see
    • For a discussion of this methodology, see Jonathan B. Baker & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Empirical Methods in Antitrust Litigation: Review and Critique, 1 AM. L. ECON. REV. 386 (1999);
    • (1999) ECON. REV , vol.386
    • Baker, J.B.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 2
    • 0042231482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the Matter of Weyerhauser Company: The Use of a Hold-Separate Order in a Merger with Horizontal and Vertical Effects, 11
    • A variant on this methodology estimates the relationship between price and cost and demand factors and then forecasts price during the treatment period
    • Laurence Schumann, James D. Reitzes & Robert P. Rogers, In the Matter of Weyerhauser Company: The Use of a Hold-Separate Order in a Merger with Horizontal and Vertical Effects, 11 J. REG. ECON. 271 (1997). A variant on this methodology estimates the relationship between price and cost and demand factors and then forecasts price during the treatment period.
    • (1997) J. REG. ECON , vol.271
    • Schumann, L.1    Reitzes, J.D.2    Rogers, R.P.3
  • 3
    • 33747883236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Time-Series Estimation of the Effects of Natural Experiments, 135
    • See
    • See Halbert White, Time-Series Estimation of the Effects of Natural Experiments, 135 J. ECONOMETRICS 527 (2005).
    • (2005) J. ECONOMETRICS , vol.527
    • White, H.1
  • 4
    • 57049102635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For examples of studies using this approach, see David M. Barton & Roger Sherman, The Price and Profit Effects of Horizontal Merger: A Case Study, 33 J. INDUS. ECON. 165 (1984);
    • For examples of studies using this approach, see David M. Barton & Roger Sherman, The Price and Profit Effects of Horizontal Merger: A Case Study, 33 J. INDUS. ECON. 165 (1984);
  • 5
    • 0025629178 scopus 로고
    • Airline Mergers, Airport Dominance, and Market Power, 80
    • Severin Borenstein, Airline Mergers, Airport Dominance, and Market Power, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 400 (1990);
    • (1990) AM. ECON. REV , vol.400
    • Borenstein, S.1
  • 6
    • 2442675242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Relationships and Competition in Retail Gasoline Markets: Empirical Evidence from Contract Changes in Southern California, 94
    • hereinafter Vertical Relationships and Competition
    • Justine S. Hastings, Vertical Relationships and Competition in Retail Gasoline Markets: Empirical Evidence from Contract Changes in Southern California, 94 AM. ECON. REV. 317 (2004) [hereinafter Vertical Relationships and Competition];
    • (2004) AM. ECON. REV , vol.317
    • Hastings, J.S.1
  • 7
    • 29744470204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Power, Vertical Integration, and the Wholesale Price of Gasoline, 53
    • Justine S. Hastings & Richard J. Gilbert, Market Power, Vertical Integration, and the Wholesale Price of Gasoline, 53 J. INDUS. ECON. 469 (2005);
    • (2005) J. INDUS. ECON , vol.469
    • Hastings, J.S.1    Gilbert, R.J.2
  • 8
    • 0027767127 scopus 로고
    • Mergers and Market Power: Evidence from the Airline Industry, 83
    • E. Han Kim & Vijay Singal, Mergers and Market Power: Evidence from the Airline Industry, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 549 (1993);
    • (1993) AM. ECON. REV , vol.549
    • Han Kim, E.1    Singal, V.2
  • 9
    • 0032343126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Substantial Horizontal Mergers Generate Significant Price Effects? Evidence from the Banking Industry, 46
    • Robin A. Prager & Timothy H. Hannan, Do Substantial Horizontal Mergers Generate Significant Price Effects? Evidence from the Banking Industry, 46 J. INDUS. ECON. 433 (1998);
    • (1998) J. INDUS. ECON , vol.433
    • Prager, R.A.1    Hannan, T.H.2
  • 10
    • 57049138568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Gasoline Mergers Affect Consumer's Prices? The Marathon-Ashland and UDS Transaction, 51
    • forthcoming February
    • John Simpson & Christopher T. Taylor, Do Gasoline Mergers Affect Consumer's Prices? The Marathon-Ashland and UDS Transaction, 51 J.L. ECON. (forthcoming February 2008);
    • (2008) J.L. ECON
    • Simpson, J.1    Taylor, C.T.2
  • 11
    • 34548595675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economic Effects of the Marathon-Ashland Joint Venture: The Importance of Industry Supply Shocks and Vertical Market Structure, 55
    • Christopher T. Taylor & Daniel S. Hosken, The Economic Effects of the Marathon-Ashland Joint Venture: The Importance of Industry Supply Shocks and Vertical Market Structure, 55 J. INDUS. ECON. 419 (2007).
    • (2007) J. INDUS. ECON , vol.419
    • Taylor, C.T.1    Hosken, D.S.2
  • 12
    • 13244283045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making a similar point about DID estimators in a broader context, Abadie notes: [I]t is well known that the DID estimator is based on strong identifying assumptions. In particular, the conventional DID estimator requires that, in the absence of the treatment, the average outcomes for the treated and control groups would have followed parallel paths over time. Alberto Abadie, Semiparametric Difference-in-Differences Estimators, 72 REV. ECON. STUD. 1, 1 (2005).
    • Making a similar point about DID estimators in a broader context, Abadie notes: "[I]t is well known that the DID estimator is based on strong identifying assumptions. In particular, the conventional DID estimator requires that, in the absence of the treatment, the average outcomes for the treated and control groups would have followed parallel paths over time." Alberto Abadie, Semiparametric Difference-in-Differences Estimators, 72 REV. ECON. STUD. 1, 1 (2005).
  • 13
    • 57049083796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While a 20 percent cost shock may seem large, the control markets in at least one of the studies cited previously experienced price changes of this magnitude. See Hastings, Vertical Relationships and Competition, supra note 2, at 323 examining price changes in gasoline markets in Southern California
    • While a 20 percent cost shock may seem large, the control markets in at least one of the studies cited previously experienced price changes of this magnitude. See Hastings, Vertical Relationships and Competition, supra note 2, at 323 (examining price changes in gasoline markets in Southern California).
  • 14
    • 57049115207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We calculate the DID estimator as δ=(P1T, P0T, P1c, 0 o) where T and C respresent the treatment and control markets respectively, and 1 and 0 represent the post-treatment and pre-treatment periods respectively
    • o) where T and C respresent the treatment and control markets respectively, and 1 and 0 represent the post-treatment and pre-treatment periods respectively.
  • 15
    • 57049100077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This particular case is simplified to illustrate our main point
    • This particular case is simplified to illustrate our main point.
  • 16
    • 57049145110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While one might contend that the difference in the pre-treatment prices in the treatment and control markets might cause a judge or jury to question a comparison of price changes in the two types of markets, our main point would also hold in more complex examples where pre-treatment prices in the treatment and control markets were more similar. 0.5(0.75, 0.75, 0.50.8, 0.75, 0.025
    • While one might contend that the difference in the pre-treatment prices in the treatment and control markets might cause a judge or jury to question a comparison of price changes in the two types of markets, our main point would also hold in more complex examples where pre-treatment prices in the treatment and control markets were more similar. 0.5(0.75 - 0.75) + 0.5(0.8 - 0.75) = 0.025.
  • 17
    • 21844493421 scopus 로고
    • The Effects of Mergers in Differentiated Products Industries: Logit Demand and Merger Policy, 10
    • See
    • See Gregory J. Werden & Luke M. Froeb, The Effects of Mergers in Differentiated Products Industries: Logit Demand and Merger Policy, 10 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 407 (1994).
    • (1994) J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.407
    • Werden, G.J.1    Froeb, L.M.2
  • 18
    • 57049139174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Throughout this example, the market price is measured as the market-share weighted average price across all firms using premerger shares
    • Throughout this example, the market price is measured as the market-share weighted average price across all firms using premerger shares.
  • 19
    • 57049107907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The DID approach could also yield inaccurate results in this example if the treatment and control markets differed only in some other market characteristic. But the results would not be nearly as sensitive to differences in these other characteristics as they are to differences in the degree of substitutability
    • The DID approach could also yield inaccurate results in this example if the treatment and control markets differed only in some other market characteristic. But the results would not be nearly as sensitive to differences in these other characteristics as they are to differences in the degree of substitutability.
  • 20
    • 57049131300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The reason the merger effect is 9 percent, instead of the 7 percent reported by Werden and Froeb, is that in addition to the price change caused by the merger, this figure also accounts for the fact that the merged company in the treatment market passes through less of the cost decrease than its non-merged counterparts in the control market.
    • The reason the merger effect is 9 percent, instead of the 7 percent reported by Werden and Froeb, is that in addition to the price change caused by the merger, this figure also accounts for the fact that the merged company in the treatment market passes through less of the cost decrease than its non-merged counterparts in the control market.
  • 21
    • 57049160679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To put these differences in perspective, these parameters imply that the proportion of customers who would leave MCI due to a price increase that would switch to AT&T (the diversion ratio) is 60 percent in the treatment market and 42 percent in the control market.
    • To put these differences in perspective, these parameters imply that the proportion of customers who would leave MCI due to a price increase that would switch to AT&T (the "diversion ratio") is 60 percent in the treatment market and 42 percent in the control market.
  • 22
    • 57049120880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another way to interpret this graph is that a merger simulation model calibrated to reflect the control market would incorrectly predict the effect of a merger in the treatment market by exactly the amount shown in the graph
    • Another way to interpret this graph is that a merger simulation model calibrated to reflect the control market would incorrectly predict the effect of a merger in the treatment market by exactly the amount shown in the graph.
  • 23
    • 57049167332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In other cases, the same uncertainty about market conditions that complicates the application of the DID approach may also complicate the application of other measurement techniques. In these cases, a researcher might prefer the DID approach because of its simplicity
    • In other cases, the same uncertainty about market conditions that complicates the application of the DID approach may also complicate the application of other measurement techniques. In these cases, a researcher might prefer the DID approach because of its simplicity.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.