메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 96, Issue 6, 2008, Pages 1987-2027

The property puzzle

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 51249102396     PISSN: 00168092     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (17)

References (207)
  • 2
    • 51249106470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JESSE DUKEMINIER ET AL., PROPERTY 87-88 (6th ed. 2006); THOMAS W. MERRILL & HENRY E. SMITH, PROPERTY PRINCIPLES AND POLICIES 1-9 (2007) (starting off the casebook).
    • See, e.g., JESSE DUKEMINIER ET AL., PROPERTY 87-88 (6th ed. 2006); THOMAS W. MERRILL & HENRY E. SMITH, PROPERTY PRINCIPLES AND POLICIES 1-9 (2007) (starting off the casebook).
  • 3
    • 51249111102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jacque, 563 N.W.2d at 156-57.
    • Jacque, 563 N.W.2d at 156-57.
  • 4
    • 51249107344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jacque v. Steenberg Homes, Inc., 548 N.W.2d 80, 85 (Wis. Ct. App. 1996).
    • Jacque v. Steenberg Homes, Inc., 548 N.W.2d 80, 85 (Wis. Ct. App. 1996).
  • 5
    • 51249113449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jacque, 563 N.W.2d at 209.
    • Jacque, 563 N.W.2d at 209.
  • 7
    • 51249089942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 490; see U.S. CONST. amend. V, cl. 4 ([N]or shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation.).
    • Id. at 490; see U.S. CONST. amend. V, cl. 4 ("[N]or shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation.").
  • 8
    • 33751244230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a survey of the academic criticism, see Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, The Uselessness of Public Use, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1412, 1423-26 (2006). For an example of a lobbying group campaign against Kelo, see DANA BERLINER, OPENING THE FLOODGATES: EMINENT DOMAIN ABUSE IN THE POST-KELO WORLD (2006), available at http://www.castlecoalition.org/pdf/publications/floodgates-report.pdf (blaming the decision for spurring eminent-domain abuse in favor of politically powerful entrepreneurs at the expense of simple-rank landowners).
    • For a survey of the academic criticism, see Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, The Uselessness of Public Use, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1412, 1423-26 (2006). For an example of a lobbying group campaign against Kelo, see DANA BERLINER, OPENING THE FLOODGATES: EMINENT DOMAIN ABUSE IN THE POST-KELO WORLD (2006), available at http://www.castlecoalition.org/pdf/publications/floodgates-report.pdf (blaming the decision for spurring eminent-domain abuse in favor of politically powerful entrepreneurs at the expense of simple-rank landowners).
  • 9
    • 51249103630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Patricia Salkin, Eminent Domain Legislation Post Kelo: A State of the States, 36 ENVTL. L. REP. 10864 (2006); CASTLE COAL., 50 STATE REPORT CARD: TRACKING EMINENT DOMAIN REFORM LEGISLATION SINCE KELO, available at http://www.castlecoalition. org/pdf/publications/report_card/50_State_Report.pdf.
    • See Patricia Salkin, Eminent Domain Legislation Post Kelo: A State of the States, 36 ENVTL. L. REP. 10864 (2006); CASTLE COAL., 50 STATE REPORT CARD: TRACKING EMINENT DOMAIN REFORM LEGISLATION SINCE KELO, available at http://www.castlecoalition. org/pdf/publications/report_card/50_State_Report.pdf.
  • 10
    • 51249104912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., City of Norwood v. Homey, 853 N.E.2d 1115, 1123 (Ohio 2006); Bd. of County Comm'rs of Muskogee County v. Lowery, 136 P.3d 639, 647 (Okla. 2006).
    • See, e.g., City of Norwood v. Homey, 853 N.E.2d 1115, 1123 (Ohio 2006); Bd. of County Comm'rs of Muskogee County v. Lowery, 136 P.3d 639, 647 (Okla. 2006).
  • 11
    • 51249083256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lee Anne Fennell, Taking Eminent Domain Apart, 2004 MICH. ST. L. REV. 957, 962-67 (2004); Nicole Stelle Garnett, The Neglected Political Economy of Eminent Domain, 105 MICH. L. REV. 101, 106-10 (2006). To give a fair account in the Kelo matter, Susette Kelo and a few other landowners (who were the last to holdout following the Supreme Court's judgment) settled for amounts greatly exceeding the properties' formal assessed values. See Amnon Lehavi & Amir N. Licht, Eminent Domain, Inc., 107 COLUM. L. REV. 1704, 1708-09 (2007).
    • See Lee Anne Fennell, Taking Eminent Domain Apart, 2004 MICH. ST. L. REV. 957, 962-67 (2004); Nicole Stelle Garnett, The Neglected Political Economy of Eminent Domain, 105 MICH. L. REV. 101, 106-10 (2006). To give a fair account in the Kelo matter, Susette Kelo and a few other landowners (who were the last to holdout following the Supreme Court's judgment) settled for amounts greatly exceeding the properties' formal assessed values. See Amnon Lehavi & Amir N. Licht, Eminent Domain, Inc., 107 COLUM. L. REV. 1704, 1708-09 (2007).
  • 12
    • 51249099590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This basic taxonomy is derived from Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089, 1106-11 (1972, For a list of works supporting the superiority of liability rules, see Henry E. Smith, Property and Property Rules, 79 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1719, 1721 n.5 2004, criticizing this broad tendency
    • This basic taxonomy is derived from Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089, 1106-11 (1972). For a list of works supporting the superiority of liability rules, see Henry E. Smith, Property and Property Rules, 79 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1719, 1721 n.5 (2004) (criticizing this broad tendency).
  • 14
    • 0346581482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the information-harnessing effect of liability rules, see Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Property Rules Versus Liability Rules: An Economic Analysis, 109 HARV. L. REV. 713, 724-28 (1996); AYRES, supra note 13, at 103-04, 184-85.
    • For the information-harnessing effect of liability rules, see Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Property Rules Versus Liability Rules: An Economic Analysis, 109 HARV. L. REV. 713, 724-28 (1996); AYRES, supra note 13, at 103-04, 184-85.
  • 15
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost, 3
    • Ronald H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1, 1-2 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & ECON , vol.1 , pp. 1-2
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 16
    • 51249087345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 12, at 1115-24
    • Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 12, at 1115-24.
  • 17
    • 0347876092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theories of Regulation: Incorporating the Administrative Process, 98
    • For an efficient overview of this theory, see
    • For an efficient overview of this theory, see Steven P. Croley, Theories of Regulation: Incorporating the Administrative Process, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1, 34-41 (1998).
    • (1998) COLUM. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 34-41
    • Croley, S.P.1
  • 18
    • 51249095169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Daniel A. Farber, Public Choice and Just Compensation, 9 CONST. COMMENT. 279, 289-90 (1992); Daryl J. Levinson, Making Governments Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 345, 348-51 (2000).
    • See, e.g., Daniel A. Farber, Public Choice and Just Compensation, 9 CONST. COMMENT. 279, 289-90 (1992); Daryl J. Levinson, Making Governments Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 345, 348-51 (2000).
  • 19
    • 51249100022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This view has led authors to advocate for increasing judicial intervention in political and administrative decisionmaking. For a critical review of this literature, see Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review, 101 YALE L.J. 31, 44-48, 66-87 1991, arguing that adjudication is similarly prone to problems stated by public choice theory
    • This view has led authors to advocate for increasing judicial intervention in political and administrative decisionmaking. For a critical review of this literature, see Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101 YALE L.J. 31, 44-48, 66-87 (1991) (arguing that adjudication is similarly prone to problems stated by public choice theory).
  • 20
    • 37349074654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. 469
    • Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469, 472-75 (2005).
    • (2005) City of New London , vol.545 , pp. 472-475
    • Kelo, V.1
  • 21
    • 51249116071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a general characterization of private law as founded on the idea of corrective justice, see ERNEST J. WEINRIB, THE IDEA OF PRIVATE LAW 56-83, 204-31 (1995). For a discussion of the separation argument, see, for example, Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Why the Legal System is Less Efficient than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income, 23 J. LEGAL. STUD. 667, 667-698 (1994).
    • For a general characterization of private law as founded on the idea of corrective justice, see ERNEST J. WEINRIB, THE IDEA OF PRIVATE LAW 56-83, 204-31 (1995). For a discussion of the "separation" argument, see, for example, Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Why the Legal System is Less Efficient than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income, 23 J. LEGAL. STUD. 667, 667-698 (1994).
  • 22
    • 51249086689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See J.E. PENNER, THE IDEA OF PROPERTY IN LAW 202-203 (1997).
    • See J.E. PENNER, THE IDEA OF PROPERTY IN LAW 202-203 (1997).
  • 23
    • 51249097865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The term natural law is obviously an intricate one that has evolved in numerous forms but that, at its core, is based on the assertion that legal principles are founded on objective moral principles that are derived from the nature of the universe and can be discovered by reason. See M.D.A. FREEMAN, LLOYD'S INTRODUCTION TO J URISPRUDENCE 90-96 (7th ed. 2002).
    • The term "natural law" is obviously an intricate one that has evolved in numerous forms but that, at its core, is based on the assertion that legal principles are founded on objective moral principles that are derived from the nature of the universe and can be discovered by reason. See M.D.A. FREEMAN, LLOYD'S INTRODUCTION TO J URISPRUDENCE 90-96 (7th ed. 2002).
  • 24
    • 33745678499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a leading analysis of John Locke's theory of property, see JEREMY WALDRON, THE RIGHT TO PRIVATE PROPERTY 137-252 (1988). I deliberately use the term Lockean rather than simply referring to Locke because of the unique way in which Lockean viewpoints of counter-government, strong rights to private property have developed and intensified in legal and popular thought in the Anglo-American world, often bearing only scant resemblance to Locke's own ideas. See, e.g., Lior Zemer, The Making of a New Copyright Lockean, 29 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 891, 892-95 (2006) (alleging scholarly misinterpretation of Locke in the copyright arena).
    • For a leading analysis of John Locke's theory of property, see JEREMY WALDRON, THE RIGHT TO PRIVATE PROPERTY 137-252 (1988). I deliberately use the term "Lockean" rather than simply referring to Locke because of the unique way in which "Lockean" viewpoints of counter-government, strong rights to private property have developed and intensified in legal and popular thought in the Anglo-American world, often bearing only scant resemblance to Locke's own ideas. See, e.g., Lior Zemer, The Making of a New Copyright Lockean, 29 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 891, 892-95 (2006) (alleging scholarly misinterpretation of Locke in the copyright arena).
  • 25
    • 51249114121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recall Bentham's statement that property and law are born together, and die together. Before laws were made there was no property; take away laws, and property ceases. JEREMY BENTHAM, THEORY OF LEGISLATION 113 (C.K. Ogden ed., Routledge & Kegan Paul Ltd. 1931) (1802).
    • Recall Bentham's statement that "property and law are born together, and die together. Before laws were made there was no property; take away laws, and property ceases." JEREMY BENTHAM, THEORY OF LEGISLATION 113 (C.K. Ogden ed., Routledge & Kegan Paul Ltd. 1931) (1802).
  • 26
    • 33845453709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Order and Public Justice: Kant and Rawls, 92
    • See
    • See Arthur Ripstein, Private Order and Public Justice: Kant and Rawls, 92 VA. L. REV. 1391, 1411-15 (2006).
    • (2006) VA. L. REV , vol.1391 , pp. 1411-1415
    • Ripstein, A.1
  • 27
    • 51249095167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond classic social contract theories such as those of Thomas Hobbes, John Locke, and Jean-Jacques Rousseau, several contemporary theories of the State focus on its role as an efficient third party enforcer of private agreements. See, e.g., YORAM BARZEL, A THEORY OF THE STATE: ECONOMIC RIGHTS, LEGAL RIGHTS, AND THE SCOPE OF THE STATE 13-58 (2002). For another contemporary contractual theory of property, albeit one embedded in political analysis, see GARY D. LIBECAP, CONTRACTING FOR PROPERTY RIGHTS 4 (1989).
    • Beyond classic "social contract" theories such as those of Thomas Hobbes, John Locke, and Jean-Jacques Rousseau, several contemporary theories of the State focus on its role as an efficient third party enforcer of private agreements. See, e.g., YORAM BARZEL, A THEORY OF THE STATE: ECONOMIC RIGHTS, LEGAL RIGHTS, AND THE SCOPE OF THE STATE 13-58 (2002). For another contemporary contractual theory of property, albeit one embedded in political analysis, see GARY D. LIBECAP, CONTRACTING FOR PROPERTY RIGHTS 4 (1989).
  • 28
    • 51249108427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 347, 351-53 (1967). For later developments of Demsetz's principal insights, see, for example, Terry L. Anderson & Peter J. Hill, The Evolution of Property Rights, in PROPERTY RIGHTS: COOPERATION, CONFLICT, AND LAW 118, 118-19 (Terry L. Anderson & Fred S. McChesney eds., 2003).
    • Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 347, 351-53 (1967). For later developments of Demsetz's principal insights, see, for example, Terry L. Anderson & Peter J. Hill, The Evolution of Property Rights, in PROPERTY RIGHTS: COOPERATION, CONFLICT, AND LAW 118, 118-19 (Terry L. Anderson & Fred S. McChesney eds., 2003).
  • 29
    • 0345374665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property Enforcement as Organized Consent, 19
    • justifying governmental monopoly in land recording and registration activities as facilitating private contracts and protecting third parties, See
    • See Benito Arruñada, Property Enforcement as Organized Consent, 19 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 401 (2003) (justifying governmental monopoly in land recording and registration activities as facilitating private contracts and protecting third parties).
    • (2003) J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.401
    • Arruñada, B.1
  • 30
    • 18844435142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Katrina Miriam Wyman, From Fur to Fish: Reconsidering the Evolution of Private Property, 80 N.YU. L. REV. 117, 127-52 (2005) (analyzing the intricate ways in which political institutions operate and make decisions about the establishment or hindrance of new property regimes); see also ITAI SENED, THE POLITICAL INSTITUTION OF PRIVATE PROPERTY 1 (1997).
    • See Katrina Miriam Wyman, From Fur to Fish: Reconsidering the Evolution of Private Property, 80 N.YU. L. REV. 117, 127-52 (2005) (analyzing the intricate ways in which political institutions operate and make decisions about the establishment or hindrance of new property regimes); see also ITAI SENED, THE POLITICAL INSTITUTION OF PRIVATE PROPERTY 1 (1997).
  • 31
    • 51249107347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kant further argues that all citizens are entitled to demand that others treat them in accordance with the laws of natural freedom and equality, even if some are unable or ineligible to actively participate in public decisionmaking by voting, thus being passive members of society. See IMMANUEL KANT, THE METAPHYSICS OF MORALS 91-92 Mary Gergor ed. & trans, Cambridge Univ. Press 1996, 1797
    • Kant further argues that all citizens are entitled to demand that others treat them in accordance with the laws of natural freedom and equality, even if some are unable or ineligible to actively participate in public decisionmaking by voting, thus being "passive" members of society. See IMMANUEL KANT, THE METAPHYSICS OF MORALS 91-92 (Mary Gergor ed. & trans., Cambridge Univ. Press 1996) (1797).
  • 32
    • 51249094119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ripstein, supra note 26, at 1394, 1406-15
    • See Ripstein, supra note 26, at 1394, 1406-15.
  • 33
    • 51249101726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHN RAWLS, POLITICAL LIBERALISM 213-14 (rev. ed. 1996). For a concise analysis of Rawlsian public reason, see Lawrence B. Solum, Public Legal Reason, 92 VA. L. REV. 1449, 1467-79 (2006).
    • JOHN RAWLS, POLITICAL LIBERALISM 213-14 (rev. ed. 1996). For a concise analysis of Rawlsian public reason, see Lawrence B. Solum, Public Legal Reason, 92 VA. L. REV. 1449, 1467-79 (2006).
  • 34
    • 51249094738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POLITICAL LIBERALISM, supra note 33, at 223-27
    • POLITICAL LIBERALISM, supra note 33, at 223-27.
  • 35
    • 51249085428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 227-30
    • Id. at 227-30.
  • 36
    • 51249120732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 215-16. Rawls even depicts the court as the institutional exemplar of public reason in a constitutional regime with judicial review. Id. at 231-40.
    • Id. at 215-16. Rawls even depicts the court as the "institutional exemplar" of public reason in a constitutional regime with judicial review. Id. at 231-40.
  • 37
    • 51249106472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For these two principles, which would have been allegedly accepted by all society members in the original position, see JOHN RAWLS, A THEORY OF JUSTICE 10-15 (rev. ed. 1999).
    • For these two principles, which would have been allegedly accepted by all society members in the "original position," see JOHN RAWLS, A THEORY OF JUSTICE 10-15 (rev. ed. 1999).
  • 38
    • 51249090970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RAWLS, supra note 33, at 11-15. For a general discussion of this shift, see FREEMAN, supra note 23, at 523-27.
    • RAWLS, supra note 33, at 11-15. For a general discussion of this shift, see FREEMAN, supra note 23, at 523-27.
  • 39
    • 51249100019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RAWLS, supra note 33, at 36
    • RAWLS, supra note 33, at 36.
  • 40
    • 51249097276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 217
    • Id. at 217.
  • 41
    • 42149142169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at, text accompanying notes 55-59
    • Id. at 223-24. See also infra text accompanying notes 55-59.
    • See also infra , pp. 223-224
  • 42
    • 51249105786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ripstein, supra note 26, at 1428
    • Ripstein, supra note 26, at 1428.
  • 43
    • 51249119437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a critical discussion of the interplay between property and civic republicanism, see STEPHEN R. MUNZER, A THEORY OF PROPERTY 138-42 (1990).
    • For a critical discussion of the interplay between property and "civic republicanism," see STEPHEN R. MUNZER, A THEORY OF PROPERTY 138-42 (1990).
  • 45
    • 51249115858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JÜRGEN HABERMAS, THE STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION OF THE PUBLIC SPHERE: AN INQUIRY INTO A CATEGORY OF BOURGEOIS SOCIETY (Thomas Burger trans., MTT Press 1989) (1962).
    • JÜRGEN HABERMAS, THE STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION OF THE PUBLIC SPHERE: AN INQUIRY INTO A CATEGORY OF BOURGEOIS SOCIETY (Thomas Burger trans., MTT Press 1989) (1962).
  • 46
    • 33845386347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I thus dispute Lawrence Solum's contention that public legal reason should be shallow, that is, void of any deep premises about moral, religious, consequentalist, or deontological ideas. See Solum, supra note 33, at 1473-78. I subscribe to the more inclusionary view of public legal reason as expressed in George Rutherglen, Private Law and Public Reason, 92 VA. L. REV. 1503, 1513-15 (2006).
    • I thus dispute Lawrence Solum's contention that public legal reason should be "shallow," that is, void of any deep premises about moral, religious, consequentalist, or deontological ideas. See Solum, supra note 33, at 1473-78. I subscribe to the more inclusionary view of public legal reason as expressed in George Rutherglen, Private Law and Public Reason, 92 VA. L. REV. 1503, 1513-15 (2006).
  • 47
    • 51249118745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some admirable scholarly endeavors include J.W. HARRIS, PROPERTY AND JUSTICE (1996); MUNZER, supra note 43; PENNER, supra note 22; LAURA S. UNDERKUFFLER, THE IDEA OF PROPERTY: ITS MEANING AND POWER (2003); and WALDRON, supra note 24.
    • Some admirable scholarly endeavors include J.W. HARRIS, PROPERTY AND JUSTICE (1996); MUNZER, supra note 43; PENNER, supra note 22; LAURA S. UNDERKUFFLER, THE IDEA OF PROPERTY: ITS MEANING AND POWER (2003); and WALDRON, supra note 24.
  • 48
    • 51249121376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This suggested categorical division is my own. Other commentators have advocated for different groupings in mapping out property theories. See, e.g, WALDRON, supra note 24, at 106-36 differentiating between special- and general-rights-based arguments for private property, based on H.L.A. Hart's broad distinction between special rights and general rights in law
    • This suggested categorical division is my own. Other commentators have advocated for different groupings in mapping out property theories. See, e.g., WALDRON, supra note 24, at 106-36 (differentiating between special- and general-rights-based arguments for private property, based on H.L.A. Hart's broad distinction between special rights and general rights in law).
  • 49
    • 51249092840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The origins of this analysis go back to thinkers such as Adam Smith, William Blackstone, and Jeremy Bentham. See Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, What Happened to Property in Law and Economics?, 111 YALE L.J. 357, 360-64 (2001). For contemporary accounts, see STEVEN SHAVELL, THE FOUNDATIONS OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 11-23 (2004); Demsetz, supra note 28, at 347-50.
    • The origins of this analysis go back to thinkers such as Adam Smith, William Blackstone, and Jeremy Bentham. See Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, What Happened to Property in Law and Economics?, 111 YALE L.J. 357, 360-64 (2001). For contemporary accounts, see STEVEN SHAVELL, THE FOUNDATIONS OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 11-23 (2004); Demsetz, supra note 28, at 347-50.
  • 50
    • 51249090331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WALDRON, supra note 24; see also MUNZER, supra note 43, at 255-56, 285-87.
    • WALDRON, supra note 24; see also MUNZER, supra note 43, at 255-56, 285-87.
  • 51
    • 51249103421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RICHARD PIPES, PROPERTY AND FREEDOM 279-81 (1999); UNDERKUFFLER, supra note 47, at 40; James M. Buchanan, Property as a Guarantor of Liberty, in PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE LIMITS OF DEMOCRACY 1, 59 (Charles K. Rowley ed., 1993).
    • See, e.g., RICHARD PIPES, PROPERTY AND FREEDOM 279-81 (1999); UNDERKUFFLER, supra note 47, at 40; James M. Buchanan, Property as a Guarantor of Liberty, in PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE LIMITS OF DEMOCRACY 1, 59 (Charles K. Rowley ed., 1993).
  • 54
    • 51249124002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a critical analysis of such resource-specific arguments, see generally HARRIS, supra note 47, at 13-14
    • For a critical analysis of such "resource-specific" arguments, see generally HARRIS, supra note 47, at 13-14.
  • 55
    • 51249089937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ripstein, supra note 26, at 1433-35
    • Ripstein, supra note 26, at 1433-35.
  • 56
    • 51249103631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RAWLS, supra note 33, at 227
    • RAWLS, supra note 33, at 227.
  • 57
    • 51249083936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Both Kant and Rawls have been criticized, however, for allowing substantial economic disparities in society, thus undermining their own contentions about freedom and equality. See MUNZER, supra note 43, at 132; see also FREEMAN, supra note 23, at 527-28.
    • Both Kant and Rawls have been criticized, however, for allowing substantial economic disparities in society, thus undermining their own contentions about freedom and equality. See MUNZER, supra note 43, at 132; see also FREEMAN, supra note 23, at 527-28.
  • 59
    • 51249091688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronald Dworkin, What is Equality? Part 2: Equality of Resources, 10 PHIL. & PUB. AFF. 283, 283-90 (1981) (holding a thought experiment of survivors on a desert island that uses auctions following an initial equal allocation of tokens to construct a system of mutually acceptable resource allocation).
    • Ronald Dworkin, What is Equality? Part 2: Equality of Resources, 10 PHIL. & PUB. AFF. 283, 283-90 (1981) (holding a thought experiment of survivors on a desert island that uses auctions following an initial equal allocation of tokens to construct a system of mutually acceptable resource allocation).
  • 60
    • 51249117143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David Lametti, The (Virtue) Ethics of Private Property: A Framework and Implications, in NEW PERSPECTIVES ON PROPERTY LAW, OBLIGATIONS AND RESTITUTION 39, 39 (Alistair Hudson ed., 2004) [hereinafter NEW PERSPECTIVES]; JOSEPH WILLIAM SINGER, ENTITLEMENT: THE PARADOXES OF PROPERTY 209-13 (2000).
    • See David Lametti, The (Virtue) Ethics of Private Property: A Framework and Implications, in NEW PERSPECTIVES ON PROPERTY LAW, OBLIGATIONS AND RESTITUTION 39, 39 (Alistair Hudson ed., 2004) [hereinafter NEW PERSPECTIVES]; JOSEPH WILLIAM SINGER, ENTITLEMENT: THE PARADOXES OF PROPERTY 209-13 (2000).
  • 61
    • 51249114794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GREGORY S. ALEXANDER, THE GLOBAL DEBATE OVER CONSTITUTIONAL PROPERTY 59 (2006) (arguing that the content of property is very much determined by judicial interpretation which openly and systemically inquires what substantive value underlies the decision to make property a constitutionally protected right, and that the theory most compatible with liberalism is pluralist, recognizing multiple purposes inhering in the constitutional protection of property).
    • See GREGORY S. ALEXANDER, THE GLOBAL DEBATE OVER CONSTITUTIONAL PROPERTY 59 (2006) (arguing that the content of property is very much determined by judicial interpretation which "openly and systemically inquires what substantive value underlies the decision to make property a constitutionally protected right," and that the theory most compatible with liberalism is "pluralist, recognizing multiple purposes inhering in the constitutional protection of property").
  • 62
    • 0347416183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takings and Distributive Justice, 85
    • laying out a progressive takings law, See
    • See Hanoch Dagan, Takings and Distributive Justice, 85 VA. L. REV. 741, 767-91 (1999) (laying out a "progressive takings law").
    • (1999) VA. L. REV , vol.741 , pp. 767-791
    • Dagan, H.1
  • 63
    • 51249105122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This literature, which calls for placing positive duties on the government to endow its citizens with a certain level of governmental benefits, is most famously associated with Charles A. Reich, The New Property, 73 YALE L.J. 733 1964
    • This literature, which calls for placing positive duties on the government to endow its citizens with a certain level of governmental benefits, is most famously associated with Charles A. Reich, The New Property, 73 YALE L.J. 733 (1964).
  • 64
    • 33846316430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SINGER, supra note 60, at 95-139; Daphna Lewinsohn-Zamir, In Defense of Redistribution Through Private Law, 91 MINN. L. REV. 326, 340-46, 379-90 (2006) (calling to implement redistributive goals, aimed at enabling weaker members of society to enjoy an objective threshold of well-being, in certain social scenarios such as landlord-tenant law and family property).
    • SINGER, supra note 60, at 95-139; Daphna Lewinsohn-Zamir, In Defense of Redistribution Through Private Law, 91 MINN. L. REV. 326, 340-46, 379-90 (2006) (calling to implement redistributive goals, aimed at enabling weaker members of society to enjoy an objective threshold of well-being, in certain social scenarios such as landlord-tenant law and family property).
  • 65
    • 51249092626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is important to emphasize that not all these commentators agree on the same blueprint for the reconstruction of property law. For example, Lewinsohn-Zamir objects to the incorporation of explicit redistributive principles in takings law. Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 390-93 (arguing that compensation rules for regulatory takings are problematic because they do not directly provide for objective goods or advance the worse-off's well-being).
    • It is important to emphasize that not all these commentators agree on the same blueprint for the reconstruction of property law. For example, Lewinsohn-Zamir objects to the incorporation of explicit redistributive principles in takings law. Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 390-93 (arguing that compensation rules for regulatory takings are problematic because "they do not directly provide for objective goods or advance the worse-off's well-being").
  • 66
    • 51249084172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mixing Property, 38
    • Amnon Lehavi, Mixing Property, 38 SETON HALL L. REV. 137, 204-07 (2008).
    • (2008) SETON HALL L. REV , vol.137 , pp. 204-207
    • Lehavi, A.1
  • 67
    • 51249094120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Susan Rose-Ackerman, Against Ad Hocery: A Reply to Michelman, 88 COLUM. L. REV. 1697, 1700-02 (1988) (arguing against a strict case-by-case approach to judicial review of takings compensation).
    • Cf. Susan Rose-Ackerman, Against Ad Hocery: A Reply to Michelman, 88 COLUM. L. REV. 1697, 1700-02 (1988) (arguing against a strict case-by-case approach to judicial review of takings compensation).
  • 68
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 75-77 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 75-77 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 69
    • 51249106473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally note 66 identifying and analyzing different types of property regimes
    • See generally Lehavi, supra note 66 (identifying and analyzing different types of property regimes).
    • supra
    • Lehavi1
  • 70
    • 51249093467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An efficient review of this debate is found in MERRIL & SMITH, supra note 2, at 15-22
    • An efficient review of this debate is found in MERRIL & SMITH, supra note 2, at 15-22.
  • 71
    • 51249105585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Henry Merriman, Ownership and Estate, 48 TUL. L. REV. 916, 927 (1974) (explaining that under the Romanic theory of property, the box of ownership contains rights, including that of use and occupancy, that to the fruits or income, and the power of alienation).
    • John Henry Merriman, Ownership and Estate, 48 TUL. L. REV. 916, 927 (1974) (explaining that under the Romanic theory of property, the "box of ownership" contains rights, "including that of use and occupancy, that to the fruits or income, and the power of alienation").
  • 72
    • 51249116674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BARRY NICHOLAS, AN INTRODUCTION TO ROMAN LAW 99-101 (1962); Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, The Property/Contract Interface, 101 COLUM. L. REV. 773, 780 (2001).
    • See BARRY NICHOLAS, AN INTRODUCTION TO ROMAN LAW 99-101 (1962); Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, The Property/Contract Interface, 101 COLUM. L. REV. 773, 780 (2001).
  • 73
    • 51249091925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merriman, supra note 71, at 927-929
    • Merriman, supra note 71, at 927-929.
  • 74
    • 0000056271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WILLIAM BLACKSTONE, 2 COMMENTARIES ON THE LAWS OF ENGLAND 2 (Univ. of Chicago Press 1979) (1765) (defining the right of property as that sole and despotic dominion which one man claims and exercises over the external things of the world, in total exclusion of the right of any other individual in the universe). But see Carol M. Rose, Canons of Property Talk, or, Blackstone's Anxiety, 108 YALE L.J. 601, 603-06 (1998) (arguing that Blackstone's absolutistic concept was more wishful thinking than a depiction of the complex legal reality of his time).
    • See WILLIAM BLACKSTONE, 2 COMMENTARIES ON THE LAWS OF ENGLAND 2 (Univ. of Chicago Press 1979) (1765) (defining the right of property as "that sole and despotic dominion which one man claims and exercises over the external things of the world, in total exclusion of the right of any other individual in the universe"). But see Carol M. Rose, Canons of Property Talk, or, Blackstone's Anxiety, 108 YALE L.J. 601, 603-06 (1998) (arguing that Blackstone's absolutistic concept was more wishful thinking than a depiction of the complex legal reality of his time).
  • 75
    • 0001232077 scopus 로고
    • Fundamental Legal Conceptions as Applied in Judicial Reasoning, 26
    • Wesley Newcomb Hohfeld, Fundamental Legal Conceptions as Applied in Judicial Reasoning, 26 YALE L.J. 710, 718-19 (1917).
    • (1917) YALE L.J , vol.710 , pp. 718-719
    • Newcomb Hohfeld, W.1
  • 76
    • 51249085431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some scholars have remained rather faithful to the analytical contours separating in personam from in rem rights, portraying what they deem as quintessential or typical incidents of property and ownership. See, e.g, TONY HONORÉ, Ownership, in MAKING LAW BIND: ESSAYS LEGAL AND PHILOSOPHICAL 161, 161-84 1987
    • Some scholars have remained rather faithful to the analytical contours separating in personam from in rem rights, portraying what they deem as quintessential or typical incidents of property and ownership. See, e.g., TONY HONORÉ, Ownership, in MAKING LAW BIND: ESSAYS LEGAL AND PHILOSOPHICAL 161, 161-84 (1987).
  • 77
    • 51249095412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Thomas C. Grey, The Disintegration of Property, in NOMOS XXII: PROPERTY 69 (J. Roland Pennock & John W. Chapman eds., 1980).
    • See generally Thomas C. Grey, The Disintegration of Property, in NOMOS XXII: PROPERTY 69 (J. Roland Pennock & John W. Chapman eds., 1980).
  • 78
    • 51249094124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 72, at 787
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 72, at 787.
  • 79
    • 51249086460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal Standardization in the Law of Property: The Numerus Clausus Principle, 110
    • Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, Optimal Standardization in the Law of Property: The Numerus Clausus Principle, 110 YALE L.J. 1, 12-24 (2001).
    • (2001) YALE L.J , vol.1 , pp. 12-24
    • Merrill, T.W.1    Smith, H.E.2
  • 80
    • 51249085238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 49, at 395-96
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 49, at 395-96.
  • 81
    • 51249098085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Merrill & Smith, supra note 72, at 789-809. Other prominent scholarship that advances an essentialist approach to property, especially in regard to the general right of exclusion, includes PENNER, supra note 22, at 23-27, 68-76, and HARRIS, supra note 47, at 85-86.
    • See, e.g., Merrill & Smith, supra note 72, at 789-809. Other prominent scholarship that advances an essentialist approach to property, especially in regard to the general right of exclusion, includes PENNER, supra note 22, at 23-27, 68-76, and HARRIS, supra note 47, at 85-86.
  • 83
    • 51249118126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., SINGER, supra note 60, at 130-39 (locating property's center of gravity in social interdependence and arguing that rights, including property ones, should be perceived as socially situated, contingent on their effects on others, and therefore set within the context of relationships involving mutual obligations).
    • See, e.g., SINGER, supra note 60, at 130-39 (locating property's center of gravity in social interdependence and arguing that rights, including property ones, should be perceived as "socially situated, contingent on their effects on others, and therefore set within the context of relationships involving mutual obligations").
  • 84
    • 51249125095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hanoch Dagan, Legal Realism and the Taxonomy of Private Law, in STRUCTURE IN THE PRIVATE LAW: ESSAYS IN MEMORY OF PETER BIRKS 214, 224 (Charles Ricken & Ross Grantham eds., 2007).
    • Hanoch Dagan, Legal Realism and the Taxonomy of Private Law, in STRUCTURE IN THE PRIVATE LAW: ESSAYS IN MEMORY OF PETER BIRKS 214, 224 (Charles Ricken & Ross Grantham eds., 2007).
  • 85
    • 51249096087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The understanding that property rights are by nature incomplete, given also the inability to define and decide in advance the fate of all resource uses, known and unknown, new and foreseeable, is not only recognized in the legal literature, but is also increasingly gaining currency in the economic literature
    • The understanding that property rights are by nature incomplete, given also the inability to define and decide in advance the fate of all resource uses, "known and unknown, new and foreseeable," is not only recognized in the legal literature, but is also increasingly gaining currency in the economic literature.
  • 86
    • 51249107346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., CAROL M. ROSE, PROPERTY AND PERSUASION: ESSAYS ON THE HISTORY, THEORY, AND RHETORIC OF OWNERSHIP 11-20 (1994); Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, A Theory of Property, 90 CORNELL L. REV. 531, 554-63 (2005).
    • See, e.g., CAROL M. ROSE, PROPERTY AND PERSUASION: ESSAYS ON THE HISTORY, THEORY, AND RHETORIC OF OWNERSHIP 11-20 (1994); Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, A Theory of Property, 90 CORNELL L. REV. 531, 554-63 (2005).
  • 87
    • 77949833129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Morality of Property, 48
    • arguing that the American property system is largely based on a moral convention of exclusion
    • Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, The Morality of Property, 48 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1849 (2007) (arguing that the American property system is largely based on a moral convention of exclusion).
    • (2007) WM. & MARY L. REV. 1849
    • Merrill, T.W.1    Smith, H.E.2
  • 88
    • 51249107784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 49, at 395-96
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 49, at 395-96.
  • 89
    • 51249098086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of such tension, see Timothy J. Brennan, Copyright, Property, and the Right to Deny, 68 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 675 (1993). For an interesting recent exchange about similarities and differences in the protection of property in land vis-à-vis intellectual property, compare Peter S. Menell, Intellectual Property and the Property Rights Movement, REGULATION, Fall 2007, at 36, with Richard A. Epstein, A Response to Peter Menell: The Property Rights Movement and Intellectual Property, REGULATION, Winter 2008, at 58.
    • For a discussion of such tension, see Timothy J. Brennan, Copyright, Property, and the Right to Deny, 68 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 675 (1993). For an interesting recent exchange about similarities and differences in the protection of property in land vis-à-vis intellectual property, compare Peter S. Menell, Intellectual Property and the Property Rights Movement, REGULATION, Fall 2007, at 36, with Richard A. Epstein, A Response to Peter Menell: The Property Rights Movement and Intellectual Property, REGULATION, Winter 2008, at 58.
  • 90
    • 51249122646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, WALDRON, supra note 24, at 295
    • See, e.g., WALDRON, supra note 24, at 295.
  • 91
    • 34250678122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PENNER, supra note 22, at 71; see also Henry E. Smith, Intellectual Property as Property: Delineating Entitlements in Information, 116 YALE L.J. 1742, 1752 (2007).
    • PENNER, supra note 22, at 71; see also Henry E. Smith, Intellectual Property as Property: Delineating Entitlements in Information, 116 YALE L.J. 1742, 1752 (2007).
  • 92
    • 51249114528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Larissa M. Katz, Exclusion and Exclusivity in Property 16-23 (Legal Studies Research Paper Series No. 08-02, 2008), available at http://ssm.com/abstract=1126674.
    • Larissa M. Katz, Exclusion and Exclusivity in Property 16-23 (Legal Studies Research Paper Series No. 08-02, 2008), available at http://ssm.com/abstract=1126674.
  • 93
    • 51249109735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HONORÉ, supra note 76, at 168-79
    • HONORÉ, supra note 76, at 168-79.
  • 94
    • 51249085658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Lehavi, supra note 66
    • See generally Lehavi, supra note 66.
  • 95
    • 51249092629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 79, at 24-58 (arguing that the numerus clausus principle achieves optimal standardization that minimizes the sum of societal costs). Merrill and Smith's argument also has an institutional component, according to which new forms of property rights should be designed by the legislature and not by courts. Id. at 58-68. While I accept some of Merrill and Smith's general institutional arguments, I believe that their focus on generic kinds of property interests is too narrow and misses much of the real-life and theoretical complexity of property, in a manner that also distorts their otherwise insightful analysis.
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 79, at 24-58 (arguing that the numerus clausus principle achieves optimal standardization that minimizes the sum of societal costs). Merrill and Smith's argument also has an institutional component, according to which new forms of property rights should be designed by the legislature and not by courts. Id. at 58-68. While I accept some of Merrill and Smith's general institutional arguments, I believe that their focus on generic kinds of property interests is too narrow and misses much of the real-life and theoretical complexity of property, in a manner that also distorts their otherwise insightful analysis.
  • 96
    • 33846807441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Properties of Concentration, 73
    • For an analysis of neighborhood composition as a property issue, see
    • For an analysis of neighborhood composition as a property issue, see Lee Anne Fennell, Properties of Concentration, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 1227 (2006).
    • (2006) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1227
    • Anne Fennell, L.1
  • 97
    • 0001587675 scopus 로고
    • Alternatives to Toning: Covenants, Nuisance Rules, and Fines as Land Use Controls, 40
    • For a foundational analysis of the various forms of land-use controls and controllers, see
    • For a foundational analysis of the various forms of land-use controls and controllers, see Robert C. Ellickson, Alternatives to Toning: Covenants, Nuisance Rules, and Fines as Land Use Controls, 40 U. CHI. L. REV. 681 (1973).
    • (1973) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.681
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 98
    • 51249091450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra section II.B.1.
    • See discussion infra section II.B.1.
  • 99
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part III
    • See infra Part III.
    • See infra
  • 100
    • 51249109084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally BARZEL, supra note 27
    • See generally BARZEL, supra note 27.
  • 101
    • 51249089487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lehavi & Licht, supra note 11, at 1710-11
    • Lehavi & Licht, supra note 11, at 1710-11.
  • 102
    • 51249097519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra section III.C.
    • See infra section III.C.
  • 103
    • 51249103845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a survey of such prohibitions, see DUKEMINIER ET AL, supra note 2, at 376-84
    • For a survey of such prohibitions, see DUKEMINIER ET AL., supra note 2, at 376-84.
  • 104
    • 37849185466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unpacking the Household: Informal Property Rights Around the Hearth, 116
    • Robert C. Ellickson, Unpacking the Household: Informal Property Rights Around the Hearth, 116 YALE L.J. 226, 271-76 (2006).
    • (2006) YALE L.J , vol.226 , pp. 271-276
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 105
    • 51249094319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Amnon Lehavi, How Property Can Create, Maintain, or Destroy Community (Theorectical Inquiries in Law, 2009), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1087026.
    • See generally Amnon Lehavi, How Property Can Create, Maintain, or Destroy Community (Theorectical Inquiries in Law, 2009), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1087026.
  • 106
    • 51249105124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19-23
    • Id. at 19-23.
  • 107
    • 0742321665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One difficult problem in the context of my work concerns the proper institutional craning of intrafamily property law. See Carolyn J. Frantz & Hanoch Dagan, Properties of Marriage, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 75 (2004, advocating for a property system based on a normative conception of marriage as an egalitarian liberal community, Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 385-89 calling to incorporate egalitarian distributive concepts in this property system, I shall refrain from developing a full-scale argument about this setting and will only remark that the thrust of the dilemma lies in the fact that although a family is allegedly a quintessential close-knit community based on consent and fraternity, it is adversely affected by hierarchal social and cultural traditions that are increasingly conceived as requiring publicly reasoned, publicly made corrective measures
    • One difficult problem in the context of my work concerns the proper institutional craning of intrafamily property law. See Carolyn J. Frantz & Hanoch Dagan, Properties of Marriage, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 75 (2004) (advocating for a property system based on a normative conception of marriage as an "egalitarian liberal community"); Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 385-89 (calling to incorporate egalitarian distributive concepts in this property system). I shall refrain from developing a full-scale argument about this setting and will only remark that the thrust of the dilemma lies in the fact that although a family is allegedly a quintessential close-knit community based on consent and fraternity, it is adversely affected by hierarchal social and cultural traditions that are increasingly conceived as requiring publicly reasoned, publicly made corrective measures.
  • 108
    • 51249088615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The 286,000 CICs in the United States house about 57 million residents to date. See Community Associations Institution, Industry Data, http://www.caionline.org/about/facts.cfm (last visited Feb. 28, 2008).
    • The 286,000 CICs in the United States house about 57 million residents to date. See Community Associations Institution, Industry Data, http://www.caionline.org/about/facts.cfm (last visited Feb. 28, 2008).
  • 109
    • 51249110400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I expounded upon the basic structure of CICs in Lehavi, note 66, at
    • I expounded upon the basic structure of CICs in Lehavi, supra note 66, at 160-62.
    • supra , pp. 160-162
  • 110
    • 51249106902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a recent survey, 74% of CIC residents said that their CICs rules protect and enhance property values. Only 3% said these rules harm property values. Zogby International, Homeowners and Community Associations, 2005 National Research Findings, org/about/ survey.cfm last visited Aug. 1, 2007
    • In a recent survey, 74% of CIC residents said that their CICs rules "protect and enhance" property values. Only 3% said these rules "harm" property values. Zogby International, Homeowners and Community Associations, 2005 National Research Findings, http://www.caionline.org/about/ survey.cfm (last visited Aug. 1, 2007).
  • 111
    • 51249092627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In some states, the creation of CICs is governed by specific legislation on the matter. See RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF PROPERTY (SERVITUDES) § 6.3 (2000). Probably most familiar is California's Davis-Stirling Common Interest Development Act, codified at CAL. CIV. CODE § 350-78 (Deering 2005).
    • In some states, the creation of CICs is governed by specific legislation on the matter. See RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF PROPERTY (SERVITUDES) § 6.3 (2000). Probably most familiar is California's Davis-Stirling Common Interest Development Act, codified at CAL. CIV. CODE § 350-78 (Deering 2005).
  • 112
    • 51249105996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Villa De Las Palmas Homeowners Ass'n v. Terifaj, 90 P.3d 1223 (Cal. 2004).
    • Villa De Las Palmas Homeowners Ass'n v. Terifaj, 90 P.3d 1223 (Cal. 2004).
  • 113
    • 51249095626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1235
    • Id. at 1235.
  • 114
    • 51249094121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1228
    • Id. at 1228.
  • 115
    • 51249087752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1229
    • Id. at 1229.
  • 116
    • 51249084175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more detailed analysis, see Lehavi, supra note 66, at 160-66
    • For a more detailed analysis, see Lehavi, supra note 66, at 160-66.
  • 117
    • 51249106475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For differing views on the nature and scope of internal group power over members, compare Clayton P. Gillette, Courts, Covenants, and Communities, 61 U. CHI. L. REV. 1375, 1413-19 (1994) (generally advocating an approach to CIC powers based on a relational contract concept), with Gregory S. Alexander, Dilemmas of Group Autonomy: Residential Associations and Community, 75 CORNELL L. REV. 1, 55-58 (1989) (calling for the application of a more stringent standard of reasonableness for certain post-establishment nonconsensual decisions to avoid minority abuse).
    • For differing views on the nature and scope of internal group power over members, compare Clayton P. Gillette, Courts, Covenants, and Communities, 61 U. CHI. L. REV. 1375, 1413-19 (1994) (generally advocating an approach to CIC powers based on a "relational contract" concept), with Gregory S. Alexander, Dilemmas of Group Autonomy: Residential Associations and Community, 75 CORNELL L. REV. 1, 55-58 (1989) (calling for the application of a more stringent standard of "reasonableness" for certain post-establishment nonconsensual decisions to avoid minority abuse).
  • 118
    • 0009753182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Privatized Communities and the "Secession of the Successful": Democracy and Fairness Beyond the Gate, 28
    • See generally
    • See generally Sheryll D. Cashin, Privatized Communities and the "Secession of the Successful": Democracy and Fairness Beyond the Gate, 28 FORDHAM URB. L.J. 1675 (2001).
    • (2001) FORDHAM URB. L.J , vol.1675
    • Cashin, S.D.1
  • 119
    • 27744540829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Privatization and Its Discontents: Common Interest Communities and the Rise of the Government for "The Nice, " 37
    • See generally
    • See generally Paula A. Franzese, Privatization and Its Discontents: Common Interest Communities and the Rise of the Government for "The Nice, " 37 URB. LAW. 335 (2005).
    • (2005) URB. LAW , vol.335
    • Franzese, P.A.1
  • 120
    • 51249102988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Overt mechanisms may include gates and fences physically isolating the community. Formal sorting of community members is achieved by associational provisions setting up, for example, age restrictions or bans on convicted sex offenders. This is in addition to informal sorting mechanisms such as premeditated choice of the type of common amenities offered by the CIC. For references on these issues, see Lehavi, supra note 66, at 161 n.100.
    • Overt mechanisms may include gates and fences physically isolating the community. Formal sorting of community members is achieved by associational provisions setting up, for example, age restrictions or bans on convicted sex offenders. This is in addition to informal sorting mechanisms such as premeditated choice of the type of common amenities offered by the CIC. For references on these issues, see Lehavi, supra note 66, at 161 n.100.
  • 121
    • 51249088826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., David J. Kennedy, Note, Residential Associations as State Actors: Regulating the Impact of Gated Communities on Nonmembers, 105 YALE L.J. 761, 763, 778-79 (1995) (arguing that residential associations should be regarded as state actors and that their powers should not exceed those of government entities).
    • See, e.g., David J. Kennedy, Note, Residential Associations as State Actors: Regulating the Impact of Gated Communities on Nonmembers, 105 YALE L.J. 761, 763, 778-79 (1995) (arguing that residential associations should be regarded as state actors and that their powers should not exceed those of government entities).
  • 122
    • 3042734240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whereas such disputes are usually resolved in private-law jurisprudence through the law of nuisance, nuisance law's traditional location in tort does not undermine its proprietary nature. See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion and Property Rules in the Law of Nuisance, 90 VA. L. REV. 965, 990-96 2004
    • Whereas such disputes are usually resolved in private-law jurisprudence through the law of nuisance, nuisance law's traditional location in tort does not undermine its proprietary nature. See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion and Property Rules in the Law of Nuisance, 90 VA. L. REV. 965, 990-96 (2004).
  • 123
    • 51249105361 scopus 로고
    • See, 122 Eng. Rep. 27, 32-33
    • See Bamford v. Turnley, (1862) 122 Eng. Rep. 27, 32-33.
    • (1862)
    • Turnley, B.V.1
  • 124
    • 51249086898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ZYGMUNT J.B. PLATER ET AL., ENVIRONMENTAL LAW AND POLICY: NATURE, LAW, AND SOCIETY 114 (3d ed. 2004); Ellickson, supra note 97, at 731-33. As the United States Supreme Court famously stated in Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 388 (1926), A nuisance may be merely a right thing in the wrong place, like a pig in the parlor instead of the barnyard.
    • See ZYGMUNT J.B. PLATER ET AL., ENVIRONMENTAL LAW AND POLICY: NATURE, LAW, AND SOCIETY 114 (3d ed. 2004); Ellickson, supra note 97, at 731-33. As the United States Supreme Court famously stated in Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 388 (1926), "A nuisance may be merely a right thing in the wrong place, like a pig in the parlor instead of the barnyard."
  • 125
    • 51249098307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CLERK & LINDSELL ON TORTS § 19-15 (Anthony M. Dugdale et al. eds., 18th ed. 2000) and RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 822 (2007) for the English and American law, respectively, on that point.
    • See CLERK & LINDSELL ON TORTS § 19-15 (Anthony M. Dugdale et al. eds., 18th ed. 2000) and RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 822 (2007) for the English and American law, respectively, on that point.
  • 126
    • 51249096782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Smith, supra note 122, at 993-94
    • See Smith, supra note 122, at 993-94.
  • 127
    • 51249112790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ellickson, supra note 97, at 720-21
    • Ellickson, supra note 97, at 720-21.
  • 128
    • 51249091228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 941 (2007); see also John Copeland Nagle, Moral Nuisances, 50 EMORY L.J. 265, 274-75 (2001). The property rules versus liability rules taxonomy is based, of course, on the work of Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 12.
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 941 (2007); see also John Copeland Nagle, Moral Nuisances, 50 EMORY L.J. 265, 274-75 (2001). The property rules versus liability rules taxonomy is based, of course, on the work of Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 12.
  • 129
    • 51249100679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henry Smith argues that although the switch to such a governance regime is understandable from a case-specific efficiency viewpoint, too broad a reliance on such types of judicial resolutions may significantly increase the overall information costs, and this in turn justifies resolving such disputes through private parties or other institutions such as the legislature. Smith, supra note 122, at 1037-45. Whereas I definitely agree that for some types of disputes, other state institutions may be preferable to the judiciary, I think that Smith somewhat overstates the case against case-specificity. Obviously, environmental regulation is intended to resolve many potential land-use conflicts in advance, but arguing that every instance that is not covered by regulation requires site-specific legislation or administrative action may also prove prohibitively costly
    • Henry Smith argues that although the switch to such a "governance" regime is understandable from a case-specific efficiency viewpoint, too broad a reliance on such types of judicial resolutions may significantly increase the overall information costs, and this in turn justifies resolving such disputes through private parties or other institutions such as the legislature. Smith, supra note 122, at 1037-45. Whereas I definitely agree that for some types of disputes, other state institutions may be preferable to the judiciary, I think that Smith somewhat overstates the case against case-specificity. Obviously, environmental regulation is intended to resolve many potential land-use conflicts in advance, but arguing that every instance that is not covered by regulation requires site-specific legislation or administrative action may also prove prohibitively costly.
  • 130
    • 51249121377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally DUKEMINIER ET AL, supra note 2, at 361-449
    • See generally DUKEMINIER ET AL., supra note 2, at 361-449.
  • 131
    • 51249085432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1893-94
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1893-94.
  • 132
    • 51249095627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra section III.E. See generally Duncan Kennedy & Frank Michelman, Are Property and Contract Efficient?, 8 HOFSTRA L. REV. 711 (1980); David Pearce, Property and Contract: Where Are We?, in NEW PERSPECTIVES, supra note 60, at 87; Merrill & Smith, Interface, supra note 72.
    • See infra section III.E. See generally Duncan Kennedy & Frank Michelman, Are Property and Contract Efficient?, 8 HOFSTRA L. REV. 711 (1980); David Pearce, Property and Contract: Where Are We?, in NEW PERSPECTIVES, supra note 60, at 87; Merrill & Smith, Interface, supra note 72.
  • 133
    • 51249117356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • YORAM BARZEL, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS 90-96 (2d ed. 1997).
    • YORAM BARZEL, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS 90-96 (2d ed. 1997).
  • 134
    • 51249096583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 381-83
    • See Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 381-83.
  • 135
    • 51249106474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 383-85
    • Id. at 383-85.
  • 136
    • 51249125094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DUKEMINIER ET AL, supra note 2, at 431-39
    • DUKEMINIER ET AL., supra note 2, at 431-39.
  • 137
    • 51249094947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MUNZER, supra note 43, at 98-110; BARBARA H. FRIED, THE PROGRESSIVE ASSAULT ON LAISSEZ FAIRE: ROBERT HALE AND THE FIRST LAW AND ECONOMICS MOVEMENT 71-107 (1998).
    • See MUNZER, supra note 43, at 98-110; BARBARA H. FRIED, THE PROGRESSIVE ASSAULT ON LAISSEZ FAIRE: ROBERT HALE AND THE FIRST LAW AND ECONOMICS MOVEMENT 71-107 (1998).
  • 138
    • 51249096085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Morris R. Cohen, Property and Sovereignty, 13 CORNELL L.Q. 8 (1927).
    • See generally Morris R. Cohen, Property and Sovereignty, 13 CORNELL L.Q. 8 (1927).
  • 139
    • 51249102990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An interesting discussion of such theories is found in FRIED, supra note 137, at 108-59
    • An interesting discussion of such theories is found in FRIED, supra note 137, at 108-59.
  • 140
    • 51249110175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a critical analysis of various measures used by governments to attain the goal of providing an equitable distribution of resources in areas such as food stamps, low income housing, health care, education, and labor market training, see RONALD J. DANIELS & MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, RETHINKING THE WELFARE STATE: THE PROSPECTS FOR GOVERNMENT BY VOUCHER (2005).
    • For a critical analysis of various measures used by governments to attain the goal of "providing an equitable distribution of resources" in areas such as food stamps, low income housing, health care, education, and labor market training, see RONALD J. DANIELS & MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, RETHINKING THE WELFARE STATE: THE PROSPECTS FOR GOVERNMENT BY VOUCHER (2005).
  • 141
    • 51249113892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a critical discussion of direct public provision, see id. See also Lehavi, supra note 66, at 143-150, 177-78 (surveying the current debate over privatization of traditional public services and arguing in favor of direct public provision in the context of public spaces).
    • For a critical discussion of direct public provision, see id. See also Lehavi, supra note 66, at 143-150, 177-78 (surveying the current debate over privatization of traditional public services and arguing in favor of direct public provision in the context of public spaces).
  • 142
    • 51249091689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is probably most famously advocated in Reich, supra note 63. For a recent analysis of the British welfare state, see generally TONY BUTCHER, DELIVERING WELFARE 2d ed. 2002
    • This is probably most famously advocated in Reich, supra note 63. For a recent analysis of the British welfare state, see generally TONY BUTCHER, DELIVERING WELFARE (2d ed. 2002).
  • 143
    • 51249102172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of this debate, see Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 327-28, 333-39
    • For an overview of this debate, see Lewinsohn-Zamir, supra note 64, at 327-28, 333-39.
  • 144
    • 51249091448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469, 503 (2005) (O'Connor, J., dissenting).
    • Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469, 503 (2005) (O'Connor, J., dissenting).
  • 145
    • 51249086690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1853-57
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1853-57.
  • 146
    • 51249124003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1858-60, 1871-74 (describing the possessory rights afforded landowners under the first-in-time rule and the law of trespass). At the same time, private rights in land should be far from absolute. This should be so, for example, such that private rights would be subjected to principles such as de minimis or abuse of rights. For the prevalence of the abuse of rights concept in legal systems, see generally Joseph M. Perillo, Abuse of Rights: A Pervasive Legal Concept, 27 PAC. L.J. 37 (1995). Accordingly, I believe that the punitive damages award in the Jacque case was grossly exaggerated, even if it had set out to establish a property-rule protection and to deter future trespasses.
    • Id. at 1858-60, 1871-74 (describing the possessory rights afforded landowners under the first-in-time rule and the law of trespass). At the same time, private rights in land should be far from absolute. This should be so, for example, such that private rights would be subjected to principles such as "de minimis" or "abuse of rights." For the prevalence of the "abuse of rights" concept in legal systems, see generally Joseph M. Perillo, Abuse of Rights: A Pervasive Legal Concept, 27 PAC. L.J. 37 (1995). Accordingly, I believe that the punitive damages award in the Jacque case was grossly exaggerated, even if it had set out to establish a property-rule protection and to deter future trespasses.
  • 147
    • 47349096575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 2, at, describing how courts declined to allow trespass suits against owners of airplanes
    • See MERRILL & SMITH, supra note 2, at 9-15 (describing how courts declined to allow trespass suits against owners of airplanes).
    • supra , pp. 9-15
    • MERRILL1    SMITH2
  • 148
    • 51249123773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the American historical context, see generally William Michael Treanor, Note, The Origins and Original Significance of the Just Compensation Clause of the Fifth Amendment, 94 YALE L.J. 694 (1985).
    • For the American historical context, see generally William Michael Treanor, Note, The Origins and Original Significance of the Just Compensation Clause of the Fifth Amendment, 94 YALE L.J. 694 (1985).
  • 150
    • 51249120107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.Y. EXEC. LAW § 828 (McKinney Supp. 1981-1982). Prior to 1973, Teleprompter obtained installation permits from property owners along the cable route in return for a standard rate of 5% of the gross revenues that it realized from the particular property. Loretto, 458 U.S. at 422-24.
    • N.Y. EXEC. LAW § 828 (McKinney Supp. 1981-1982). Prior to 1973, Teleprompter obtained installation permits from property owners along the cable route in return for a standard rate of 5% of the gross revenues that it realized from the particular property. Loretto, 458 U.S. at 422-24.
  • 151
    • 51249098987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Loretto, 458 U.S. at 423-24.
    • Loretto, 458 U.S. at 423-24.
  • 152
    • 51249088828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 425-26
    • Id. at 425-26.
  • 153
    • 51249092843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 435-36
    • Id. at 435-36.
  • 154
    • 51249105362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 155
    • 51249107139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On remand, the New York Court of Appeals upheld the State Commission's determination regarding the $1 compensation, relying on the following reasons, among others: the small amount receivable by any single property owner, the relatively insignificant damage to an owner's property by attachment of cable faculties, and that Teleprompter had offered to post a bond in light of the Supreme Court's ruling. Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 446 N.E.2d 428,434-35 (N.Y. 1983).
    • On remand, the New York Court of Appeals upheld the State Commission's determination regarding the $1 compensation, relying on the following reasons, among others: the small amount receivable by any single property owner, the relatively insignificant damage to an owner's property by attachment of cable faculties, and that Teleprompter had offered to post a bond in light of the Supreme Court's ruling. Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 446 N.E.2d 428,434-35 (N.Y. 1983).
  • 156
    • 51249089940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984).
    • Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984).
  • 157
    • 51249094122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Land Reform Act of 1967, codified at HAW. REV. STAT. ANN. ch. 516 (LexisNexis 2007).
    • Land Reform Act of 1967, codified at HAW. REV. STAT. ANN. ch. 516 (LexisNexis 2007).
  • 158
    • 51249122872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Midkiff, 467 U.S. at 232.
    • Midkiff, 467 U.S. at 232.
  • 159
    • 51249112001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 160
    • 51249097746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 233
    • Id. at 233.
  • 161
    • 36249010744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, U.S. 469
    • See Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469, 473 (2005).
    • (2005) City of New London , vol.545 , pp. 473
    • Kelo, V.1
  • 162
    • 51249102989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I borrow Meir Dan-Cohen's term, depicting the potential divergence between conduct rules (that is, conduct guidelines addressed to the general public) and decision rules (that is, decision guidelines addressed to judges in solving disputes) - the selection of which depends on the specific policy that rulemakers deem desirable in a given context. Meir Dan-Cohen, Decision Rules and Conduct Rules: On Acoustic Separation in Criminal Law, 97 HARV. L. REV. 625, 627, 629 (1984).
    • I borrow Meir Dan-Cohen's term, depicting the potential divergence between "conduct rules" (that is, conduct guidelines addressed to the general public) and "decision rules" (that is, decision guidelines addressed to judges in solving disputes) - the selection of which depends on the specific policy that rulemakers deem desirable in a given context. Meir Dan-Cohen, Decision Rules and Conduct Rules: On Acoustic Separation in Criminal Law, 97 HARV. L. REV. 625, 627, 629 (1984).
  • 163
    • 51249085656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1879-84
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1879-84.
  • 164
    • 51249085237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Protocol to the Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms art. 1, March 20, 1952, 213 U.N.T.S. 262 [hereinafter European Convention].
    • Protocol to the Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms art. 1, March 20, 1952, 213 U.N.T.S. 262 [hereinafter European Convention].
  • 165
    • 51249087330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J.A. Pye (Oxford) Ltd. v. United Kingdom (J.A. Pye I), App. No. 44302/02 (Eur. Ct. H.R. Nov. 15, 2005), available at http://cmiskp.echr. coe.int/tkp197/view.asp?item=2&portal=hbkm&action= html&highlight=J. A.%20%7C%20Pye%20%7C%20United%20%7C%20Kingdom&sessionid=5803891 &skin=hudoc-en.
    • J.A. Pye (Oxford) Ltd. v. United Kingdom (J.A. Pye I), App. No. 44302/02 (Eur. Ct. H.R. Nov. 15, 2005), available at http://cmiskp.echr. coe.int/tkp197/view.asp?item=2&portal=hbkm&action= html&highlight=J. A.%20%7C%20Pye%20%7C%20United%20%7C%20Kingdom&sessionid=5803891 &skin=hudoc-en.
  • 166
    • 51249088183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally MARK P. THOMPSON, MODERN LAND LAW 201-39 (3d ed. 2006). For a survey of American adverse possession law, see MERRILL & SMITH, supra note 2, at 194-220.
    • See generally MARK P. THOMPSON, MODERN LAND LAW 201-39 (3d ed. 2006). For a survey of American adverse possession law, see MERRILL & SMITH, supra note 2, at 194-220.
  • 167
    • 51249113238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THOMPSON, supra note 166, at 226-30
    • See THOMPSON, supra note 166, at 226-30.
  • 168
    • 51249100021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, paras
    • See J.A. Pye I, App. No. 44302/02, paras. 63-65.
    • I, App , pp. 63-65
    • Pye, J.A.1
  • 169
    • 51249107986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • THOMPSON, supra note 166, at 94-95
    • THOMPSON, supra note 166, at 94-95.
  • 170
    • 51249095411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 230.
    • See id. at 230.
  • 171
    • 51249116073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 230-36
    • Id. at 230-36.
  • 172
    • 51249122049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J.A. Pye (Oxford) Ltd. v. United Kingdom (JA. Pye II), App. No. 44302/02 (Eur. Ct. H.R. Aug. 30, 2007) (Grand Chamber), available at http://cmiskp.echr.coe.int/tkp197/view.asp?item=1& portal=hbkm&action= html&highlight=J.A.%20%7C%20Pye%20%7C%20United%20%7C%20 Kingdon& sessionid=6054179&skin=hudoc-en.
    • J.A. Pye (Oxford) Ltd. v. United Kingdom (JA. Pye II), App. No. 44302/02 (Eur. Ct. H.R. Aug. 30, 2007) (Grand Chamber), available at http://cmiskp.echr.coe.int/tkp197/view.asp?item=1& portal=hbkm&action= html&highlight=J.A.%20%7C%20Pye%20%7C%20United%20%7C%20 Kingdon& sessionid=6054179&skin=hudoc-en.
  • 173
    • 51249103226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. paras. 9-12, 22-33.
    • Id. paras. 9-12, 22-33.
  • 174
    • 51249086251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. para. 3
    • Id. para. 3.
  • 175
    • 51249121378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • European Convention, supra note 164
    • European Convention, supra note 164.
  • 176
    • 51249092172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 177
    • 51249100021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • paras
    • J.A. Pye I, App. No. 44302/02, paras. 49-76.
    • I, App , pp. 49-76
    • Pye, J.A.1
  • 178
  • 179
    • 51249095410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 180
    • 51249120109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. para. 72
    • Id. para. 72.
  • 181
    • 51249107142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. para. 74
    • Id. para. 74.
  • 182
    • 51249089486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THOMPSON, supra note 166, at 231
    • See THOMPSON, supra note 166, at 231.
  • 183
    • 51249086899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking Coast Seriously: Neil Komesar on Law's Limits, 29
    • book review, arguing that, in practice, high numbers and complexity make decisions about the property system more suitable for political institutions than for legal ones
    • Cf. Daniel H. Cole, Taking Coast Seriously: Neil Komesar on Law's Limits, 29 LAW & SOC. INQUIRY 261, 282 (2004) (book review) (arguing that, in practice, high numbers and complexity make decisions about the property system more suitable for political institutions than for legal ones).
    • (2004) LAW & SOC. INQUIRY , vol.261 , pp. 282
    • Cf1    Daniel, H.2    Cole3
  • 185
    • 51249101324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Up to the summer of 2006, most of the $73 million expended over the Fort Trumbull project's course, including monies expended on taking the properties of Susette Kelo and her neighbors, came from the State of Connecticut's Department of Economic and Community Development. Ted Mann, Fort Trumbull Saga Ends on Costly Note, THE DAY (New London, Conn.), Aug. 23, 2006, at A1.
    • Up to the summer of 2006, most of the $73 million expended over the Fort Trumbull project's course, including monies expended on taking the properties of Susette Kelo and her neighbors, came from the State of Connecticut's Department of Economic and Community Development. Ted Mann, Fort Trumbull Saga Ends on Costly Note, THE DAY (New London, Conn.), Aug. 23, 2006, at A1.
  • 186
    • 0347301541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Alon Harel, Right-Based Judicial Review: A Democratic Justification, 22 LAW & PHIL. 247, 248-49 (2003).
    • See Alon Harel, Right-Based Judicial Review: A Democratic Justification, 22 LAW & PHIL. 247, 248-49 (2003).
  • 187
    • 51249106219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 248-49
    • Id. at 248-49.
  • 188
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 56-59 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 56-59 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 189
    • 51249124684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an analysis of this second group of arguments, see Harel, supra note 186, at 250-59
    • For an analysis of this second group of arguments, see Harel, supra note 186, at 250-59.
  • 191
    • 51249099592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. CONST. amend. V, cl. 4; id. amend. XIV, § 1, cl. 3. For an analysis of the procedural and substantive due-process rights to property, see, respectively, RONALD A. CASS ET AL., ADMINISTRATIVE LAW: CASES AND MATERIALS 598-615 (4th ed. 2002) and ROBERT C. ELLICKSON & VICKI L. BEEN, LAND USE CONTROLS: CASES AND MATERIALS 94-112 (3d ed. 2005).
    • See U.S. CONST. amend. V, cl. 4; id. amend. XIV, § 1, cl. 3. For an analysis of the procedural and substantive due-process rights to property, see, respectively, RONALD A. CASS ET AL., ADMINISTRATIVE LAW: CASES AND MATERIALS 598-615 (4th ed. 2002) and ROBERT C. ELLICKSON & VICKI L. BEEN, LAND USE CONTROLS: CASES AND MATERIALS 94-112 (3d ed. 2005).
  • 192
    • 51249096783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ELLICKSON & BEEN, supra note 191, at 836
    • ELLICKSON & BEEN, supra note 191, at 836.
  • 193
    • 51249122645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This latter type of acts or omissions is typically referred to as inverse condemnations or regulatory takings. See generally DUKEMINIER ET AL, supra note 2, at 941-1065
    • This latter type of acts or omissions is typically referred to as "inverse condemnations" or "regulatory takings." See generally DUKEMINIER ET AL., supra note 2, at 941-1065.
  • 195
    • 51249109295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 436 n.12 (citing Pruneyard Shopping Center v. Robbins, 447 U.S. 74 (1980)).
    • Id. at 436 n.12 (citing Pruneyard Shopping Center v. Robbins, 447 U.S. 74 (1980)).
  • 196
    • 51249111550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pruneyard Shopping Center v. Robbins, 447 U.S. 74, 82-86 (1980). It should be noted that the shopping mall raised the property issue as a takings argument in view of the California Supreme Court's interpretation of the state constitution as entitling citizens to exercise free expression and petition rights on shopping center property. The case was not, however, about a conventional governmental taking of property, but rather about a state-mandated reallocation of entitlements and obligations in shopping malls among private parties.
    • Pruneyard Shopping Center v. Robbins, 447 U.S. 74, 82-86 (1980). It should be noted that the shopping mall raised the property issue as a takings argument in view of the California Supreme Court's interpretation of the state constitution as entitling citizens to exercise free expression and petition rights on shopping center property. The case was not, however, about a conventional governmental taking of property, but rather about a state-mandated reallocation of entitlements and obligations in shopping malls among private parties.
  • 197
    • 47849111736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robbins, 127
    • discussing differences and similarities between the government and private citizens as landowners
    • Wilkie v. Robbins, 127 S. Ct. 2588, 2602 (2007) (discussing differences and similarities between the government and private citizens as landowners).
    • (2007) S. Ct , vol.2588 , pp. 2602
    • Wilkie, V.1
  • 198
    • 34547602865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, U.S. 469
    • See Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469, 480 (2003).
    • (2003) City of New London , vol.545 , pp. 480
    • Kelo, V.1
  • 199
    • 51249121829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 200
    • 26844438525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In this sense, the post-Kelo state reaction has resulted in property federalism, that is, a distinctive design of the property regime in land based on each state's unique perceptions. See Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, Of Property and Federalism, 115 YALE L.J. 72, 76-78 (2005). See generally Christopher Serkin, Local Property Law: Adjusting the Scale of Property Protection, 107 COLUM. L. REV. 883 (2007) (calling to allow local governments to select the property protection they want to offer, so that consumers select the kind of property protection they want by choosing where to live and invest).
    • In this sense, the post-Kelo state reaction has resulted in "property federalism," that is, a distinctive design of the property regime in land based on each state's unique perceptions. See Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, Of Property and Federalism, 115 YALE L.J. 72, 76-78 (2005). See generally Christopher Serkin, Local Property Law: Adjusting the Scale of Property Protection, 107 COLUM. L. REV. 883 (2007) (calling to allow local governments to select the property protection they want to offer, so that consumers select the kind of property protection they want by choosing where to live and invest).
  • 201
    • 51249101945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Merrill & Smith, supra note 72, at 809-49 (reviewing several legal institutions that exist along the property/contract interface, including bailments, landlord-tenant law, security interests, and trusts).
    • Cf. Merrill & Smith, supra note 72, at 809-49 (reviewing several legal institutions that exist along the property/contract interface, including bailments, landlord-tenant law, security interests, and trusts).
  • 202
    • 77954185262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an analysis of the debate over the integrity of such a distinction, see N.E. Simmonds, Justice, Causation and Private Law, in PUBLIC AND PRIVATE: LEGAL, POLITICAL AND PHILOSOPHICAL PERSPECTIVES 149 (Maurizio Passerin d'Entrèves & Ursula Vogel eds, 2000, Obviously, this quandary is also central to many other fields in the humanities and the social sciences. See Jeff Weintraub, The Theory and Politics of the Public/Private Distinction, in PUBLIC AND PRIVATE IN THOUGHT AND PRACTICE 1, 2-4 Jeff Weintraub & Krishan Kumar eds, 1997, Alan Wolfe, Public and Private in Theory and Practice: Some Implications of an Uncertain Boundary, in PUBLIC AND PRIVATE IN THOUGHT AND PRACTICE, supra, 182, 196-201
    • For an analysis of the debate over the integrity of such a distinction, see N.E. Simmonds, Justice, Causation and Private Law, in PUBLIC AND PRIVATE: LEGAL, POLITICAL AND PHILOSOPHICAL PERSPECTIVES 149 (Maurizio Passerin d'Entrèves & Ursula Vogel eds., 2000). Obviously, this quandary is also central to many other fields in the humanities and the social sciences. See Jeff Weintraub, The Theory and Politics of the Public/Private Distinction, in PUBLIC AND PRIVATE IN THOUGHT AND PRACTICE 1, 2-4 (Jeff Weintraub & Krishan Kumar eds., 1997); Alan Wolfe, Public and Private in Theory and Practice: Some Implications of an Uncertain Boundary, in PUBLIC AND PRIVATE IN THOUGHT AND PRACTICE, supra, 182, 196-201.
  • 203
    • 49249117909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Limited Autonomy of Private Law, 56 AM. J. COMP. L
    • For the debate on the autonomy of private law with respect to the type of rules and values on which it should be based in resolving specific disputes, see generally, forthcoming
    • For the debate on the autonomy of private law with respect to the type of rules and values on which it should be based in resolving specific disputes, see generally Hanoch Dagan, The Limited Autonomy of Private Law, 56 AM. J. COMP. L. (forthcoming 2008).
    • (2008)
    • Dagan, H.1
  • 204
    • 51249096086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lehavi, supra note 66, at 209-11
    • Lehavi, supra note 66, at 209-11.
  • 205
    • 51249098761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1850 (viewing the right to exclude as the basic moral tenet of property, and applying it throughout the spectrum of private and public jurisprudence).
    • Merrill & Smith, supra note 87, at 1850 (viewing the right to exclude as the basic moral tenet of property, and applying it throughout the spectrum of private and public jurisprudence).
  • 206
    • 33750519220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two Models of Tort (and Takings), 92
    • offering a consolidated theory for torts, especially proprietary nuisances, and takings, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Scott Hershovitz, Two Models of Tort (and Takings), 92 VA. L. REV. 1146, 1149 (2006) (offering a consolidated theory for torts - especially "proprietary" nuisances - and takings).
    • (2006) VA. L. REV , vol.1146 , pp. 1149
    • Hershovitz, S.1
  • 207
    • 51249090141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JEAN-JACQUES ROUSSEAU, ON THE SOCIAL CONTRACT, bk. IV, ch. 1 (G.D.H. Cole trans., Dover Publishing 2003) (1762).
    • See JEAN-JACQUES ROUSSEAU, ON THE SOCIAL CONTRACT, bk. IV, ch. 1 (G.D.H. Cole trans., Dover Publishing 2003) (1762).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.