메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 39, Issue 1, 2008, Pages 65-96

"Machinery has completely taken over": The diffusion of the mechanical cotton picker, I949-I964

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 50949126820     PISSN: 00221953     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1162/jinh.2008.39.1.65     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (11)

References (74)
  • 1
    • 0034955753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The quotation in the title was spoken by Hughley M. Jones of Panola County, Mississippi, in Goin' to Chicago, a California Newsteel, produced by George King and Associates in 1994. After World War II, the South played a key role in income convergence. See Francesco Caselli and Wilbur John Coleman II, The U.S. Structural Transformation and Regional Convergence: A Reinterpretation, Journal of Political Economy, CIX, (2001), 584-616;
    • The quotation in the title was spoken by Hughley M. Jones of Panola County, Mississippi, in Goin' to Chicago, a California Newsteel, produced by George King and Associates in 1994. After World War II, the South played a key role in income convergence. See Francesco Caselli and Wilbur John Coleman II, "The U.S. Structural Transformation and Regional Convergence: A Reinterpretation," Journal of Political Economy, CIX, (2001), 584-616;
  • 2
    • 0033493381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kris Mitchener and Ian McLean, U.S. Regional Growth and Convergence, 1880-1960, Journal of Economic History LIX, (1999), 1016-1042;
    • Kris Mitchener and Ian McLean, "U.S. Regional Growth and Convergence, 1880-1960, Journal of Economic History LIX, (1999), 1016-1042;
  • 3
    • 3142526383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Human Capital and Growth in the Postbellum South: A Separate but Unequal Story
    • Michelle Connolly, "Human Capital and Growth in the Postbellum South: A Separate but Unequal Story," ibid., LXIV (2004), 363-399;
    • (2004) , vol.64 , pp. 363-399
    • Connolly, M.1
  • 8
    • 50949098871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Wright's view, federal agricultural programs led to tenant displacement, and minimum wage laws reduced employment growth in labor-intensive industries (The Economic Revolution in the American South, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1 [1987], 161-178).
    • In Wright's view, federal agricultural programs led to tenant displacement, and minimum wage laws reduced employment growth in labor-intensive industries ("The Economic Revolution in the American South," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1 [1987], 161-178).
  • 9
    • 0020946092 scopus 로고
    • Labor for the Picking, the New Deal in the South
    • See also
    • See also Warren Whatley, "Labor for the Picking, the New Deal in the South," Journal of Economic History, XLIII (1983), 909-929.
    • (1983) Journal of Economic History , vol.43 , pp. 909-929
    • Whatley, W.1
  • 11
    • 0032723982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • on civil rights and economics, Wright, The Civil Rights Revolution as Economic History, Journal of Economic History, LIX (1999), 267-289.
    • on civil rights and economics, Wright, "The Civil Rights Revolution as Economic History," Journal of Economic History, LIX (1999), 267-289.
  • 12
    • 50949104785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Acemoglu and James Robinson, Persistence of Power, Elites and Institutions (Cambridge, Mass., 2006), 49, credit the collapse of southern equilibrium to changes in incentives favoring previous political strategies.
    • Acemoglu and James Robinson, Persistence of Power, Elites and Institutions (Cambridge, Mass., 2006), 49, credit the "collapse" of southern equilibrium to changes in incentives favoring previous political strategies.
  • 13
    • 0028595845 scopus 로고
    • Economic Performance Through Time
    • Douglass North, "Economic Performance Through Time," American Economic Review, LXXXIV (1994), 360.
    • (1994) American Economic Review , vol.84 , pp. 360
    • North, D.1
  • 14
    • 50949099917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • North's definition of institution distinguishes the concept from physical (and sometimes more transitory) manifestations, such as specific governments or their branches. Some economic historians prefer a more expansive definition - for example, Avner Grief, Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy (New York, 2006)), 15-24 - although usage in this literature tends to follow North more closely.
    • North's definition of institution distinguishes the concept from physical (and sometimes more transitory) manifestations, such as specific governments or their branches. Some economic historians prefer a more expansive definition - for example, Avner Grief, Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy (New York, 2006)), 15-24 - although usage in this literature tends to follow North more closely.
  • 16
    • 50949127142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The social consequences of cotton-picker diffusion include effects on wage convergence between the South and North, the civil rights movement, the migration of African Americans, and changes in racial economic inequality. See Wright, Old South;
    • The social consequences of cotton-picker diffusion include effects on wage convergence between the South and North, the civil rights movement, the migration of African Americans, and changes in racial economic inequality. See Wright, Old South;
  • 17
    • 50949105846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daniel M. Johnson and Rex R. Campbell, Black Migration in America (Durham, N.C., 1981);
    • Daniel M. Johnson and Rex R. Campbell, Black Migration in America (Durham, N.C., 1981);
  • 18
    • 43949157502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • African-American Migration and Mechanized Cotton Harvesting, 1950-60
    • XXXI (1994) 501-520;
    • Heinicke, "African-American Migration and Mechanized Cotton Harvesting, 1950-60," Explorations in Economic Histor)', XXXI (1994) 501-520;
    • Explorations in Economic Histor
    • Heinicke1
  • 19
    • 0242563106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One Step Forward: African-American Married Women in the South, 1950-1960
    • idem, "One Step Forward: African-American Married Women in the South, 1950-1960," Journal of Interdisciplinary History, XXXI (2000), 43-62;
    • (2000) Journal of Interdisciplinary History , vol.31 , pp. 43-62
    • Heinicke1
  • 20
    • 0039384726 scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Technological Change and the Demise of the Sharecropper
    • Richard Day, "The Economics of Technological Change and the Demise of the Sharecropper," American Economic Review, LVII (1967), 427-449;
    • (1967) American Economic Review , vol.57 , pp. 427-449
    • Day, R.1
  • 22
    • 84971946918 scopus 로고
    • The Cotton Harvester in Retrospect: Labor Displacement or Replacement?
    • Willis Peterson and Yoav Kislev, "The Cotton Harvester in Retrospect: Labor Displacement or Replacement?" Journal of Economic History, XLVI (1986), 199-216;
    • (1986) Journal of Economic History , vol.46 , pp. 199-216
    • Peterson, W.1    Kislev, Y.2
  • 23
    • 50949088168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alston and Ferrie, Southern Paternalism;
    • Alston and Ferrie, Southern Paternalism;
  • 24
    • 0001593395 scopus 로고
    • Paternalism in Agricultural Labor Contracts in the U.S. South: Implications for the Growth of the Welfare State
    • idem, "Paternalism in Agricultural Labor Contracts in the U.S. South: Implications for the Growth of the Welfare State," American Economic Review, LXXXIII (1993), 852-876.
    • (1993) American Economic Review , vol.83 , pp. 852-876
  • 25
    • 50949120933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Revolution,
    • Wright, "Economic Revolution, "164-171.
    • 164-171
    • Wright1
  • 26
    • 0006303769 scopus 로고
    • Chapel Hill, The focus of this article is on diffusion, but institutions may well have blunted the incentive to invent the machine
    • James Street, The New Revolution in the Cotton Economy (Chapel Hill, 1957), 34. The focus of this article is on diffusion, but institutions may well have blunted the incentive to invent the machine.
    • (1957) The New Revolution in the Cotton Economy , pp. 34
    • Street, J.1
  • 27
    • 50949125708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alston and Ferrie, Southern Paternalism.
    • Alston and Ferrie, Southern Paternalism.
  • 28
    • 50949104289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for the view of mechanization as ending small-scale farming in the South
    • See Holley, Second Great Emancipation, 77, for the view of mechanization as ending small-scale farming in the South.
    • Second Great Emancipation , vol.77
    • Holley1
  • 29
    • 50949112639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Connelly, Human Capital, argues that racial discrimination in schooling undermined human-capital formation of both African Americans and whites in the South. Street, New Revolution, 238, asserts that the South was more tradition bound than the West.
    • Connelly, "Human Capital," argues that racial discrimination in schooling undermined human-capital formation of both African Americans and whites in the South. Street, New Revolution, 238, asserts that the South was more "tradition bound" than the West.
  • 30
    • 0020415111 scopus 로고
    • The Rise of the Cotton Industry in California: A Comparative Perspective
    • Moses Musoke and Alan Olmstead, "The Rise of the Cotton Industry in California: A Comparative Perspective," Journal of Economic History, XLII (1982), 385-412,
    • (1982) Journal of Economic History , vol.42 , pp. 385-412
    • Musoke, M.1    Olmstead, A.2
  • 31
    • 0041519412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cite capital-market imperfections and numerous other factors. On institutions and cotton-seed quality, see Paul Rhode and Olmstead, Hog-Round Marketing, Seed Quality, and Government Policy: Institutional Change in U.S. Cotton Production, 1920-60, ibid., LXIII (2003), 447-488.
    • cite capital-market imperfections and numerous other factors. On institutions and cotton-seed quality, see Paul Rhode and Olmstead, "Hog-Round Marketing, Seed Quality, and Government Policy: Institutional Change in U.S. Cotton Production, 1920-60," ibid., LXIII (2003), 447-488.
  • 33
    • 50949108481 scopus 로고
    • The Wright Interpretation of Southern U.S. Economic Development: A Review Essay of Old South, New South by Gavin Wright
    • Alston, "The Wright Interpretation of Southern U.S. Economic Development: A Review Essay of Old South, New South by Gavin Wright," Agricultural History, LXI (1987), 65-67,
    • (1987) Agricultural History , vol.61 , pp. 65-67
    • Alston1
  • 34
    • 0022231119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • questions the relative strength of the New Deal vs. outmigration. Musoke and Olmstead, Rise of the Cotton Industry, argue for the importance of environmental conditions in determining cotton mechanization. Whatley, A History of Mechanization in the Cotton South: Institutional Hypothesis, Quarterly Journal of Economics (1985), 1191-1215, focuses on share tenancy, although his argument applies mainly to invention.
    • questions the relative strength of the New Deal vs. outmigration. Musoke and Olmstead, "Rise of the Cotton Industry," argue for the importance of environmental conditions in determining cotton mechanization. Whatley, "A History of Mechanization in the Cotton South: Institutional Hypothesis," Quarterly Journal of Economics (1985), 1191-1215, focuses on share tenancy, although his argument applies mainly to invention.
  • 36
    • 50949107250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For detail about invention, see Holley, Second Great Emancipation 93-158; Street, New Revolution, 104-127.
    • For detail about invention, see Holley, Second Great Emancipation 93-158; Street, New Revolution, 104-127.
  • 37
    • 0000153011 scopus 로고
    • Economic Analysis," uses the 10% figure to designate the initial adoption of the cotton harvester. Zvi Griliches, "Hybrid Corn: An Exploration in the Economics of Technological. Change
    • also uses 10% of the ceiling acreage on which hybrid corn was planted to denote when the experimental stage for this innovation was passed
    • Maier, "Economic Analysis," uses the 10% figure to designate the initial adoption of the cotton harvester. Zvi Griliches, "Hybrid Corn: An Exploration in the Economics of Technological. Change," Econometrica, XXV (1957), 501-522, also uses 10% of the "ceiling acreage" on which hybrid corn was planted to denote when the experimental stage for this innovation was passed.
    • (1957) Econometrica , vol.25 , pp. 501-522
    • Maier1
  • 38
    • 50949122917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that differential rates of adoption by state based on a 20% mechanization rate showed a longer delay of the Delta relative to the West and a smaller lag within the South than the 10% threshold implies. For the 20% threshold, the lag is about equal between the West and the Delta, as well as between the Delta and the Southeast (four years). The speed of diffusion, however, is best suited to addressing this question. At least one Delta state experienced initial adoption before a western state (Louisiana vs. New Mexico); the ordering is preserved at 20% mechanization.
    • Note that differential rates of adoption by state based on a 20% mechanization rate showed a longer delay of the Delta relative to the West and a smaller lag within the South than the 10% threshold implies. For the 20% threshold, the lag is about equal between the West and the Delta, as well as between the Delta and the Southeast (four years). The speed of diffusion, however, is best suited to addressing this question. At least one Delta state experienced initial adoption before a western state (Louisiana vs. New Mexico); the ordering is preserved at 20% mechanization.
  • 39
    • 0001469825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a study of 265 diffusion cases by Arnulf Grübler, Diffusion, Long-Term Patterns and Discontinuities, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, XXXIX 1991, 159-180, a 10-90 lag range of fifteen to thirty years bounds the modal cell for diffusion lags in cells of fifteen-year periods; the mean 10-90 lag is forty-one years. The automobile diffused faster, the tractor a good deal more slowly
    • In a study of 265 diffusion cases by Arnulf Grübler, "Diffusion, Long-Term Patterns and Discontinuities," Technological Forecasting and Social Change, XXXIX (1991), 159-180, a 10-90 lag range of fifteen to thirty years bounds the modal cell for diffusion lags in cells of fifteen-year periods; the mean 10-90 lag is forty-one years. The automobile diffused faster, the tractor a good deal more slowly
  • 40
    • 0034781281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Olmstead and Rhode, Reshaping the Landscape: The Impact and Diffusion of the Tractor in American Agriculture, 1910-60, Journal of Economic History, LXI [2001], 663-669). The cotton-harvester diffusion pattern lacked the often-observed S-shape. See Griliches, Hybrid Corn; Bronwyn Hall and Beethika Kahn, Adoption of New Technology, National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 9730 (Cambridge, Mass., 2003)).
    • (Olmstead and Rhode, "Reshaping the Landscape: The Impact and Diffusion of the Tractor in American Agriculture, 1910-60," Journal of Economic History, LXI [2001], 663-669). The cotton-harvester diffusion pattern lacked the often-observed S-shape. See Griliches, "Hybrid Corn"; Bronwyn Hall and Beethika Kahn, "Adoption of New Technology," National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 9730 (Cambridge, Mass., 2003)).
  • 41
    • 50849154469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the 1957 crop year, see Clay Lyle, Labor and Technology on Selected Cotton Plantations in the Delta Area of Mississippi, 1953-1957, Mississippi Agricultural Experiment Station. Bulletin 575 (April 1959, 6, 17. For government cotton programs and mechanization, see Maier, Economic Analysis. Note that in many USDA publications, Arkansas, Louisiana, and Mississippi were categorized as Delta states, although only parts of these states fell within the Mississippi Delta sub-region proper. About half of the cotton in Arkansas and Mississippi and about 80% in Louisiana were produced within the fertile Mississippi Delta. The state of Tennessee defies clear categorization. For the Bracero Program that temporarily slowed western mechanization, see Grove, The Mexican Farm Labor Program, 1942-1964, Agricultural History, XXV 1996, 302-320
    • For the 1957 crop year, see Clay Lyle, "Labor and Technology on Selected Cotton Plantations in the Delta Area of Mississippi, 1953-1957," Mississippi Agricultural Experiment Station. Bulletin 575 (April 1959), 6, 17. For government cotton programs and mechanization, see Maier, "Economic Analysis." Note that in many USDA publications, Arkansas, Louisiana, and Mississippi were categorized as "Delta states," although only parts of these states fell within the Mississippi Delta sub-region proper. About half of the cotton in Arkansas and Mississippi and about 80% in Louisiana were produced within the fertile Mississippi Delta. The state of Tennessee defies clear categorization. For the Bracero Program that temporarily slowed western mechanization, see Grove, "The Mexican Farm Labor Program, 1942-1964," Agricultural History, XXV (1996), 302-320.
  • 42
    • 50949122364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes that parental demand for schooling was instrumental in African-American, progress
    • Margo, Race and Schooling, notes that parental demand for schooling was instrumental in African-American, progress.
    • Race and Schooling
    • Margo1
  • 43
    • 0036487665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to John Donahue, James Heckman, and Petra Todd, The Schooling of Southern Blacks: The Roles of Legal Activism and Private Philanthropy, Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXVII (2002), 225-262, schooling had improved by 1960, but regional differences remained stark.
    • According to John Donahue, James Heckman, and Petra Todd, "The Schooling of Southern Blacks: The Roles of Legal Activism and Private Philanthropy," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXVII (2002), 225-262, schooling had improved by 1960, but regional differences remained stark.
  • 44
    • 50949087893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maier, Economic Analysis, 28-37; Musoke and Olmstead, Rise of the Cotton Industry, 387-391. After the turn of the century, the boll weevil spread throughout the high moisture areas of the Southeast, the Delta, and Texas but not to the semi-arid regions. Western growers also benefited from the federal government's Mexican Farm Labor, or Bracero, Program. See Heinicke and Grove, Labor Markets, Regional Diversity, and Cotton Harvest Mechanization in the Post-WWII United States, Social Science History, XXIX (2005), 269-297.
    • Maier, "Economic Analysis," 28-37; Musoke and Olmstead, "Rise of the Cotton Industry," 387-391. After the turn of the century, the boll weevil spread throughout the high moisture areas of the Southeast, the Delta, and Texas but not to the semi-arid regions. Western growers also benefited from the federal government's Mexican Farm Labor, or Bracero, Program. See Heinicke and Grove, "Labor Markets, Regional Diversity, and Cotton Harvest Mechanization in the Post-WWII United States," Social Science History, XXIX (2005), 269-297.
  • 45
    • 50949114744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An operator in the North Carolina Piedmont gave two reasons for returning a picker to the dealer, each, related to the steepness of slopes or narrowness of terraces on slopes. See J. Gwyn. Sutherland and.Brooks James, Mechanical Cotton Harvesting in North Carolina (Chapel Hill, 1947, 7. Early implementation of the one variety system helped to produce great cotton yields in the far West Olmstead and Rhode, Hog-Round, 457-459
    • An operator in the North Carolina Piedmont gave two reasons for returning a picker to the dealer, each, related to the steepness of slopes or narrowness of terraces on slopes. See J. Gwyn. Sutherland and.Brooks James, Mechanical Cotton Harvesting in North Carolina (Chapel Hill, 1947), 7. Early implementation of the "one variety" system helped to produce great cotton yields in the far West (Olmstead and Rhode, "Hog-Round," 457-459).
  • 46
    • 50949085394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is misleading to think in terms of an exogenous threshold size needed for adoption. International Harvester's assessment of threshold size was hardly stable. Operation size was also endogenous with respect to tractor adoption, which led to a change in the size of operations. See Gilbert Fite, Cotton Fields No More (Chapel Hill, 1984), 184-185. On that issue nationally, see Olmstead and Rhode, Reshaping.
    • It is misleading to think in terms of an exogenous "threshold" size needed for adoption. International Harvester's assessment of threshold size was hardly stable. Operation size was also endogenous with respect to tractor adoption, which led to a change in the size of operations. See Gilbert Fite, Cotton Fields No More (Chapel Hill, 1984), 184-185. On that issue nationally, see Olmstead and Rhode, "Reshaping."
  • 48
    • 50949089330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Street, New Revolution, 120-123. The machine-harvest cost estimates in Maier's Economic Analysis explicitly include yields, given that higher output per unit of land, with a given velocity of the machine through the field, resulted in lower average costs (113-114, 116, Appendix G). Owners may have used the picker in their own ways (sharing and renting), but because cotton could remain in the fields only for a certain amount of time before it deteriorated, the length of time for which fixed costs could be spread over output was limited.
    • Street, New Revolution, 120-123. The machine-harvest cost estimates in Maier's "Economic Analysis" explicitly include yields, given that higher output per unit of land, with a given velocity of the machine through the field, resulted in lower average costs (113-114, 116, Appendix G). Owners may have used the picker in their own ways (sharing and renting), but because cotton could remain in the fields only for a certain amount of time before it deteriorated, the length of time for which fixed costs could be spread over output was limited.
  • 49
    • 50949107533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the following three memos located in the International Harvester Company archives, State Historical Society of Wisconsin, Madison: J. A. Hamilton, Cotton Picker Potential Market, March 10, 1947, Market Analysis and Consumer Research Department, Farm Equipment Division, International Harvester Company; M. J. Steitz, The Market for Cotton Pickers, March 20, 1951, Market Research Section, Consumer Relations Department, Farm Equipment Division, International Harvester Company; idem, The Total Industry Potential Market for Cotton Pickers and Strippers, January 20, 1953, Market Research Section, Consumer Relations Department, Farm Equipment Division, International Harvester Company.
    • See the following three memos located in the International Harvester Company archives, State Historical Society of Wisconsin, Madison: J. A. Hamilton, "Cotton Picker Potential Market," March 10, 1947, Market Analysis and Consumer Research Department, Farm Equipment Division, International Harvester Company; M. J. Steitz, "The Market for Cotton Pickers," March 20, 1951, Market Research Section, Consumer Relations Department, Farm Equipment Division, International Harvester Company; idem, "The Total Industry Potential Market for Cotton Pickers and Strippers," January 20, 1953, Market Research Section, Consumer Relations Department, Farm Equipment Division, International Harvester Company.
  • 50
    • 50949095485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Historical Statistics of the U.S., Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, 1970), Part 1, Series K 458, 500. Olmstead and Rhode referred to this increase in yield as the other revolution (Hog-Round, 480). For contemporary under-predictions, see Appraisal of Agricultural Productive Capacity in Arkansas, 1955, Form 3 National Archives RG 164, Records of the Office of Experiment Stations, Arkansas Agricultural Experiment Station;
    • U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Historical Statistics of the U.S., Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, 1970), Part 1, Series K 458, 500. Olmstead and Rhode referred to this increase in yield as the "other revolution" ("Hog-Round," 480). For contemporary under-predictions, see "Appraisal of Agricultural Productive Capacity in Arkansas, 1955," Form 3 National Archives RG 164, Records of the Office of Experiment Stations, Arkansas Agricultural Experiment Station;
  • 52
    • 50949100983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Data on the relevant variables, except for the percentage of cotton harvested mechanically, are unavailable after 1964
    • Data on the relevant variables, except for the percentage of cotton harvested mechanically, are unavailable after 1964.
  • 53
    • 50949119220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. Department of Agriculture, Statistics on Cotton and Related Data 1920-1973 (Washington, D.C. 1974), Tables 48-61, 64-77.
    • See U.S. Department of Agriculture, Statistics on Cotton and Related Data 1920-1973 (Washington, D.C. 1974), Tables 48-61, 64-77.
  • 54
    • 50949122081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maier, Economic Analysis, 104-162, estimated machine harvest costs for the spindle picker from 1949 to 1964 based on (1) fixed and variable costs, such as purchase prices, depreciation schedules, interest rates, storage costs, insurance, taxes, tractor costs, repairs, lubricants, fuel, and labor; (2) estimates of the hours of potential use by state during a typical harvest season; (3) field waste relative to hand picking; and (4) grade loss relative to hand picking. Correction to these data came from Whatley, New Estimates of the Cost of Harvesting Cotton: 1949-1964, Research in Economic History, XIII 1991, 199-225, who added the cost of the machine operator's helper, and Grove, The Economics of Cotton Harvest Mechanization in the United States, 1920-1970, unpub. Ph.D. diss, University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign, 2000, 25-137, who added ginning costs associated with machine harvesting. Grove also provides a time series of ha
    • Maier, "Economic Analysis," 104-162, estimated machine harvest costs for the spindle picker from 1949 to 1964 based on (1) fixed and variable costs, such as purchase prices, depreciation schedules, interest rates, storage costs, insurance, taxes, tractor costs, repairs, lubricants, fuel, and labor; (2) estimates of the hours of potential use by state during a typical harvest season; (3) field waste relative to hand picking; and (4) grade loss relative to hand picking. Correction to these data came from Whatley, "New Estimates of the Cost of Harvesting Cotton: 1949-1964," Research in Economic History, XIII (1991), 199-225, who added the cost of the machine operator's "helper," and Grove, "The Economics of Cotton Harvest Mechanization in the United States, 1920-1970," unpub. Ph.D. diss. (University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign, 2000), 25-137, who added ginning costs associated with machine harvesting. Grove also provides a time series of hand-harvest costs to match the Maier machine-cost data that (1) converts piece-rate wages to cash wages per lb. of lint and (2) estimates non-wage costs for resident laborers, day-haul workers, domestic migrants, and foreign contract workers. Annual state hand-harvesting costs are obtained by combining state wage and non-wage labor expenses, weighted according to the type of labor as estimated by the state for each year. Cash wages (used in other studies), paid per 100 lb. of unprocessed "seed-cotton," do not reflect growers' total hand-harvest costs because they do not reflect the unit costs per pound of lint and because they ignore other employer expenses. No measure of operation size is available for the full panel. Farm size, which is recorded only for agricultural census years, is misleading, since sharecropper plots are entered as farms in the agricultural census. Hand costs are measured per lb. of lint - the same unit as machine-harvest costs.
  • 55
    • 0242498375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grove and Heinicke, Better Opportunities or Worse? The Demise of Cotton Harvest Labor in the US, 1949-1964, Journal of Economic History, LXIII (2003), 753; Wright, Economic Revolution, 171. Olmstead and Rhode, Reshaping, 682-691, find that substitute draft-animal prices are endogenous with respect to tractor diffusion. Despite the fact that the wage rates measured herein are lagged one year, a high degree of autocorrelation in this series suggests that testing for endogeneity is in order.
    • Grove and Heinicke, "Better Opportunities or Worse? The Demise of Cotton Harvest Labor in the US, 1949-1964," Journal of Economic History, LXIII (2003), 753; Wright, "Economic Revolution," 171. Olmstead and Rhode, "Reshaping," 682-691, find that substitute draft-animal prices are endogenous with respect to tractor diffusion. Despite the fact that the wage rates measured herein are lagged one year, a high degree of autocorrelation in this series suggests that testing for endogeneity is in order.
  • 56
    • 50949117151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • -4). The average annual increase in machine harvesting was 4.3 percentage points.
    • -4). The average annual increase in machine harvesting was 4.3 percentage points.
  • 57
    • 50949113185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The estimates hold up reasonably well with different specifications, including one with a time trend. One exception is that the version with the log of the odds ratio as the dependent variable results in a positive machine-cost coefficient in the full (year and state) fixed-effects model, although inclusion of a time trend restores the negative coefficient. There is no reason to suggest that the functional form is logistic, even with respect to time, however (see Figure 1).
    • The estimates hold up reasonably well with different specifications, including one with a time trend. One exception is that the version with the log of the odds ratio as the dependent variable results in a positive machine-cost coefficient in the full (year and state) fixed-effects model, although inclusion of a time trend restores the negative coefficient. There is no reason to suggest that the functional form is logistic, even with respect to time, however (see Figure 1).
  • 58
    • 50949131998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regressing each potentially endogenous variable on the exogenous variables, with the nonagricultural wage rate (lagged) added as a regressor for identification, finds the F-statistic for these tests to be 24.98 (df = 1, 184; p-value = 0.0018) for harvest wages, and 13.9 (1, 184; p-value = 0.0003) for overhead costs.
    • Regressing each potentially endogenous variable on the exogenous variables, with the nonagricultural wage rate (lagged) added as a regressor for identification, finds the F-statistic for these tests to be 24.98 (df = 1, 184; p-value = 0.0018) for harvest wages, and 13.9 (1, 184; p-value = 0.0003) for overhead costs.
  • 59
    • 50949132877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Day, Technological Change; Grove and Heinicke, Better Opportunities; Wright, Old South. The variable federal grants to states is problematical because it is a weak instrument for harvest wages; the correlation coefficient with cotton-picking wages is 0.2. Given that these data include a time-series element, there is the possibility that the variables are nonstatiouary. Insufficient time periods exit to perform formal tests for unit roots. Along the lines of recommendations by A. Levin and C. F. Lin, Unit Root Test in Panel Data: Asymptotic and Finite-Sample Properties, Economics Working Paper 93-56 (University of San Diego, 1993);
    • See Day, "Technological Change"; Grove and Heinicke, "Better Opportunities"; Wright, Old South. The variable federal grants to states is problematical because it is a weak instrument for harvest wages; the correlation coefficient with cotton-picking wages is 0.2. Given that these data include a time-series element, there is the possibility that the variables are nonstatiouary. Insufficient time periods exit to perform formal tests for unit roots. Along the lines of recommendations by A. Levin and C. F. Lin, "Unit Root Test in Panel Data: Asymptotic and Finite-Sample Properties," Economics Working Paper 93-56 (University of San Diego, 1993);
  • 60
    • 0000391884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unit Root Tests in Panel Data: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties
    • Levin, Lin, and C.J. Chu, "Unit Root Tests in Panel Data: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties," Journal of Econometrics, CVIII (2002), 1-24;
    • (2002) Journal of Econometrics , vol.108 , pp. 1-24
    • Lin, L.1    Chu, C.J.2
  • 61
    • 50949127684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Badi H. Baltagi, Econometric Analysis of Panel Data (New York, 1995), 235-238, the variable was regressed on its lag with fixed effects (including an intercept, and with or without a time trend). Whereas Levin and Lin suggest a formal-hypothesis test, we simply compared the standard errors to see whether the coefficient on the lagged value is close to 1, with inconclusive results. Despite the lack of evidence for a nonstationary harvesting variable, we ran a first-differenced equation one (available upon request). The machine-cost coefficient is negative but not statistically significant (10% or lower) with that specification.
    • Badi H. Baltagi, Econometric Analysis of Panel Data (New York, 1995), 235-238, the variable was regressed on its lag with fixed effects (including an intercept, and with or without a time trend). Whereas Levin and Lin suggest a formal-hypothesis test, we simply compared the standard errors to see whether the coefficient on the lagged value is "close" to 1, with inconclusive results. Despite the lack of evidence for a nonstationary harvesting variable, we ran a first-differenced equation one (available upon request). The machine-cost coefficient is negative but not statistically significant (10% or lower) with that specification.
  • 62
    • 50949112911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regressions of the log of cotton-harvest wages on a time trend show a negative and significant (10 percent or lower) coefficient for our period except for Alabama, Arizona, Georgia, and South Carolina.
    • Regressions of the log of cotton-harvest wages on a time trend show a negative and significant (10 percent or lower) coefficient for our period except for Alabama, Arizona, Georgia, and South Carolina.
  • 63
    • 50949090690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • -6.57), controlling productivity with the U.S. manufacturing productivity index.
    • -6.57), controlling productivity with the U.S. manufacturing productivity index.
  • 64
    • 50949090933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • -1.26. If this figure were statistically significant at usual levels, the southern yield growth would be almost three-quarters of a percentage point per year lower than that in the West.
    • -1.26. If this figure were statistically significant at usual levels, the southern yield growth would be almost three-quarters of a percentage point per year lower than that in the West.
  • 65
    • 50949127956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The measure for educational attainment in the West is likely to register values for large urban centers to a much greater extent than in the South, given the population distributions. In 1950, the West's urbanization rates were 70% for whites and 90% for blacks; the South's were 49% for whites and 48% for blacks Johnson and Campbell, Black Migration, 132, Hence, the differences between the West and the South may be overestimated. Working in the other direction, the quality of southern schools was poor, despite improvements by 1960
    • The measure for educational attainment in the West is likely to register values for large urban centers to a much greater extent than in the South, given the population distributions. In 1950, the West's urbanization rates were 70% for whites and 90% for blacks; the South's were 49% for whites and 48% for blacks (Johnson and Campbell, Black Migration, 132). Hence, the differences between the West and the South may be overestimated. Working in the other direction, the quality of southern schools was poor, despite improvements by 1960.
  • 66
    • 50949100710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The combination of machine costs and schooling attainment over-predicts the difference in machine harvesting between these two states in 1951. Since the schooling-attainment figures for many of the states in the South show little variation, the predicted differences across states due to that variable would be close to zero, and most of the difference in mechanization, would be due to other factors, such as machine-cost differences.
    • The combination of machine costs and schooling attainment "over-predicts" the difference in machine harvesting between these two states in 1951. Since the schooling-attainment figures for many of the states in the South show little variation, the predicted differences across states due to that variable would be close to zero, and most of the difference in mechanization, would be due to other factors, such as machine-cost differences.
  • 67
    • 50949083237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the 1950s, the federal government's Soil Bank displaced labor in the South but not in the West Heinicke and Grove, Labor Markets, 288-289
    • In the 1950s, the federal government's Soil Bank displaced labor in the South but not in the West (Heinicke and Grove, "Labor Markets," 288-289).
  • 68
    • 50949091185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peterson and Kislev, Cotton Harvester in Retrospect, 213-215, and Holley, Second Great Emancipation, 171-175, find that the decline in labor supply was greater than demand, and Heinicke, African-American Migration, 513-517, finds that harvest mechanization was not necessarily the cause of migration in the 1950s. Contrast Grove and Heinicke, Better Opportunities, 754-761, and Day, Technological Change, 441-443, for whom decreasing labor demand was predominant.
    • Peterson and Kislev, "Cotton Harvester in Retrospect," 213-215, and Holley, Second Great Emancipation, 171-175, find that the decline in labor supply was greater than demand, and Heinicke, "African-American Migration," 513-517, finds that harvest mechanization was not necessarily the cause of migration in the 1950s. Contrast Grove and Heinicke, "Better Opportunities," 754-761, and Day, "Technological Change," 441-443, for whom decreasing labor demand was predominant.
  • 71
    • 50949085393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peterson and Kislev, Cotton Harvester in Retrospect, 213-215; Holley, Second Great Emancipation, 171-174;
    • Peterson and Kislev, "Cotton Harvester in Retrospect," 213-215; Holley, Second Great Emancipation, 171-174;
  • 72
    • 50949117990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grove and Heinicke, Better Opportunities, 761; Alston and Ferrie, Southern Paternalism, 117-121.
    • Grove and Heinicke, "Better Opportunities," 761; Alston and Ferrie, Southern Paternalism, 117-121.
  • 74
    • 50949133664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Musoke and Olmstead, Rise of the Cotton Industry, 386-389.
    • Musoke and Olmstead, "Rise of the Cotton Industry," 386-389.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.