메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 7, Issue 3, 2008, Pages 327-340

Can economics rank slavery against free labor in terms of efficiency?

Author keywords

Kaldor Hicks efficiency; Pareto efficiency; Property rights; Welfare economics

Indexed keywords


EID: 47249105674     PISSN: 1470594X     EISSN: 17413060     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1177/1470594X08092106     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (8)

References (31)
  • 1
    • 47249111293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the familiar two-person, two-good exchange economy illustrated by the Edgeworth-Bowley box, we can map the Pareto efficient range of allocations only once we have located the point representing the initial endowments of the two agents and we also need their indifference curves
    • In the familiar two-person, two-good exchange economy illustrated by the Edgeworth-Bowley box, we can map the Pareto efficient range of allocations only once we have located the point representing the initial endowments of the two agents (and we also need their indifference curves).
  • 2
    • 47249083022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I thank an anonymous referee for emphasizing this distinction
    • I thank an anonymous referee for emphasizing this distinction.
  • 3
  • 4
    • 47249164361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert William Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery, 2 Vols (Boston: Little Brown, 1974), 2, p. 139, Table B.24 reported indexes of total factor productivity for all slave farms of 120.8 in the Old South and 135.8 in the New South, where the index for free farms in each region is normalized to 100. Disaggregated by farm size, the range runs from 105.0 (for the smallest farms in the Old South) to 156.3 (for mid-sized farms in the New South).
    • Robert William Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery, 2 Vols (Boston: Little Brown, 1974), Vol. 2, p. 139, Table B.24 reported indexes of total factor productivity for all slave farms of 120.8 in the Old South and 135.8 in the New South, where the index for free farms in each region is normalized to 100. Disaggregated by farm size, the range runs from 105.0 (for the smallest farms in the Old South) to 156.3 (for mid-sized farms in the New South).
  • 5
    • 47249125775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The authors later reproduced the table and discussed the sensitivity of the estimates to various corrections and adjustments. See Robert William Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, Explaining the Relative Efficiency of Slave Agriculture in the Antebellum. South, American Economic Review 67 1977, 279
    • The authors later reproduced the table and discussed the sensitivity of the estimates to various corrections and adjustments. See Robert William Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, 'Explaining the Relative Efficiency of Slave Agriculture in the Antebellum. South', American Economic Review 67 (1977): 279.
  • 6
    • 47249115721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fogel and Engerman clearly specified the type of 'efficiency' they were talking about, namely 'relative total factor productivity' (see, for example, ibid., p. 275).
    • Fogel and Engerman clearly specified the type of 'efficiency' they were talking about, namely 'relative total factor productivity' (see, for example, ibid., p. 275).
  • 7
    • 47249117005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But in summary statements (for example, Fogel and Engerman, Time on the Cross, p. 5) they spoke of slave agriculture being simply 'more efficient' than free agriculture. It is unfortunate that they did not consistently refer to 'productivity' rather than 'efficiency'.
    • But in summary statements (for example, Fogel and Engerman, Time on the Cross, p. 5) they spoke of slave agriculture being simply 'more efficient' than free agriculture. It is unfortunate that they did not consistently refer to 'productivity' rather than 'efficiency'.
  • 8
    • 0002174865 scopus 로고
    • See, New York: Oxford University Press
    • See Paul A. David et al., Reckoning with Slavery (New York: Oxford University Press, 1976);
    • (1976) Reckoning with Slavery
    • David, P.A.1
  • 9
    • 0018676945 scopus 로고
    • Explaining the Relative Efficiency of Slave Agriculture in the Antebellum South: Comment
    • Paul A. David and Peter Temin, 'Explaining the Relative Efficiency of Slave Agriculture in the Antebellum South: Comment', American Economic Review 67 (1977): 213-18;
    • (1977) American Economic Review , vol.67 , pp. 213-218
    • David, P.A.1    Temin, P.2
  • 10
    • 47249087793 scopus 로고
    • The Efficiency of Slavery: Another Interpretation
    • and Gavin Wright, 'The Efficiency of Slavery: Another Interpretation', American Economic Review 67 (1977): 219-26.
    • (1977) American Economic Review , vol.67 , pp. 219-226
    • Wright, G.1
  • 12
    • 47249159433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Here they refer to Fogel and Engerman, Time on the Cross, 1 pp. 244-5, 2 pp. 160-2. Their Table 3 sets a dollar estimate of the 'non-pecuniary loss' to slaves due to the gang labor system (the estimate being based on the size of the compensating differential that had to be paid to hire gang laborers after the abolition of slavery) against the estimated 'pecuniary gains' to slaves and cotton consumers. Such estimates do not bear directly on the fate of slaves outside of labor gangs, for example household or urban slaves.
    • Here they refer to Fogel and Engerman, Time on the Cross, Vol. 1 pp. 244-5, Vol. 2 pp. 160-2. Their Table 3 sets a dollar estimate of the 'non-pecuniary loss' to slaves due to the gang labor system (the estimate being based on the size of the compensating differential that had to be paid to hire gang laborers after the abolition of slavery) against the estimated 'pecuniary gains' to slaves and cotton consumers. Such estimates do not bear directly on the fate of slaves outside of labor gangs, for example household or urban slaves.
  • 14
    • 47249133338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas So well, Applied Economics: Thinking Beyond Stage One (New York: Basic Books, 2004), p. 65.
    • Thomas So well, Applied Economics: Thinking Beyond Stage One (New York: Basic Books, 2004), p. 65.
  • 15
    • 0001364070 scopus 로고
    • The New Welfare Economics 1939-1974
    • For a technical exposition and critique of the Kaldor-Hicks-Scitovsky approach from, a Pareto-Robbins perspective, see
    • For a technical exposition and critique of the Kaldor-Hicks-Scitovsky approach from, a Pareto-Robbins perspective, see John S. Chipman and James C. Moore, 'The New Welfare Economics 1939-1974', International Economic Review 19 (1978): 547-84.
    • (1978) International Economic Review , vol.19 , pp. 547-584
    • Chipman, J.S.1    Moore, J.C.2
  • 16
    • 21144444713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaldor-Hicks Efficiency and the Problem of Central Planning
    • For the argument that judges cannot know willingness to pay under hypothetical circumstances, and thus cannot have all the information they would need to implement the Kaldor-Hicks criterion accurately, see
    • For the argument that judges cannot know willingness to pay under hypothetical circumstances, and thus cannot have all the information they would need to implement the Kaldor-Hicks criterion accurately, see Edward Stringham, 'Kaldor-Hicks Efficiency and the Problem of Central Planning', Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 4 (2001): 41-50.
    • (2001) Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics , vol.4 , pp. 41-50
    • Stringham, E.1
  • 17
  • 18
    • 0001956565 scopus 로고
    • When Does the Rule of Liability Matter?
    • Harod Demsetz, 'When Does the Rule of Liability Matter?' Journal of Legal Studies 1 (1972): 13-28.
    • (1972) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.1 , pp. 13-28
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 19
    • 0011005671 scopus 로고
    • First Come, First Served: An Economic Analysis of Coming to the Nuisance
    • Donald A. Wittman, 'First Come, First Served: An Economic Analysis of Coming to the Nuisance', Journal of Legal Studies 9 (1980): 557-68.
    • (1980) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.9 , pp. 557-568
    • Wittman, D.A.1
  • 20
    • 0141648019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • O.J. ' s Defense: A Reductio Ad Absurdum of the Economics of Ronald Coase and Richard Posner'
    • Walter Block criticizes the Coasean prescription on ethical grounds, contrasting it to the Lockean principles that men are naturally self-owners and that first use establishes rightful ownership. See
    • Walter Block criticizes the Coasean prescription on ethical grounds, contrasting it to the Lockean principles that men are naturally self-owners and that first use establishes rightful ownership. See Walter Block, 'O.J. ' s Defense: A Reductio Ad Absurdum of the Economics of Ronald Coase and Richard Posner', European Journal of Law and Economics 3 (1996): 265-86.
    • (1996) European Journal of Law and Economics , vol.3 , pp. 265-286
    • Block, W.1
  • 22
    • 47249142409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The view that no sane individual would ever sell himself into slavery, except under violent threat, raises the question of how we are to explain the historical cases, such as medieval Russia, where self-sales were apparently numerous. See Orlando Patterson, Slavery and Social Death (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982), pp. 130-1. Were self-sellers seeking the protection of stationary masters only because the alternative was continual subjection to roving predators?
    • The view that no sane individual would ever sell himself into slavery, except under violent threat, raises the question of how we are to explain the historical cases, such as medieval Russia, where self-sales were apparently numerous. See Orlando Patterson, Slavery and Social Death (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982), pp. 130-1. Were self-sellers seeking the protection of stationary masters only because the alternative was continual subjection to roving predators?
  • 23
    • 47249139542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Northern American states did abolish slavery peaceably through the political process even without compensation to slave-owners. Slave-owners did not lose much wealth because the abolition legislation allowed them time to sell their slaves into remaining slave states. Even so, we are entitled to doubt that slave-owners unanimously agreed to the abolition. Clearly the small loss to slave-owners would not apply to the last jurisdiction to abolish slavery without compensation
    • Northern American states did abolish slavery peaceably through the political process even without compensation to slave-owners. Slave-owners did not lose much wealth because the abolition legislation allowed them time to sell their slaves into remaining slave states. Even so, we are entitled to doubt that slave-owners unanimously agreed to the abolition. Clearly the small loss to slave-owners would not apply to the last jurisdiction to abolish slavery without compensation.
  • 24
    • 47249158982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, the Louisiana Code Noir of 1685 forbade slave-owners to set conditions for self-purchase 'without having obtained consent of our Superior Council', raising a barrier to mutually beneficial trade between slave-owner and slave. See Stanley Engerman, Seymour Drescher and Robert Paquette (editors), Slavery (New York: Oxford University Press, 2001), p. 118.
    • For example, the Louisiana Code Noir of 1685 forbade slave-owners to set conditions for self-purchase 'without having obtained consent of our Superior Council', raising a barrier to mutually beneficial trade between slave-owner and slave. See Stanley Engerman, Seymour Drescher and Robert Paquette (editors), Slavery (New York: Oxford University Press, 2001), p. 118.
  • 25
    • 47249158550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-purchase and other forms of manumission appear to have been far more common for urban than for agricultural Roman slaves
    • Self-purchase and other forms of manumission appear to have been far more common for urban than for agricultural Roman slaves.
  • 26
    • 0004554211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Slavery in the Roman. Empire: Numbers and Origins
    • URL
    • John Madden, 'Slavery in the Roman. Empire: Numbers and Origins', Classics Ireland 3 (1996): 109-28. URL: http://www.ucd.ie/classics/ classicsinfo/96/Madden96.html.
    • (1996) Classics Ireland , vol.3 , pp. 109-128
    • Madden, J.1
  • 28
    • 47249157243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recall that the Kaldor-Hicks criterion requires only hypothetical trade (or ability to pay fully utility-restoring compensation) and not actual trade (or actual compensation). Sowell's argument is in that sense a Kaldor-Hicks argument, not a Pareto argument. I place it within the discussion of Pareto arguments for the sake of continuity.
    • Recall that the Kaldor-Hicks criterion requires only hypothetical trade (or ability to pay fully utility-restoring compensation) and not actual trade (or actual compensation). Sowell's argument is in that sense a Kaldor-Hicks argument, not a Pareto argument. I place it within the discussion of Pareto arguments for the sake of continuity.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.