메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 2008, Issue 3, 2008, Pages 611-654

An analysis of recent tax reforms from a marital-bias perspective: It is time to oust marriage from the tax code

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 46049115486     PISSN: 0043650X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Note
Times cited : (6)

References (310)
  • 1
    • 46049106802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taxing an activity - or not taxing it - demonstrates how accepted and encouraged that particular activity is in society. Through taxes, the government imposes a burden on certain activities, while tax credits can serve as an incentive for other behaviors
    • Society expresses its values through the tax code, note 172
    • Society expresses its values through the tax code. Taxing an activity - or not taxing it - demonstrates how accepted and encouraged that particular activity is in society. Through taxes, the government imposes a burden on certain activities, while tax credits can serve as an incentive for other behaviors. See, e.g., infra note 172.
    • See, e.g., infra
  • 3
    • 33750561286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shari Motro, A New I Do: Towards a Marriage-Neutral Income Tax, 91 IOWA L. REV. 1509, 1518 (2006) (suggesting an approach that focuses on legal entitlement to income).
    • Shari Motro, A New "I Do": Towards a Marriage-Neutral Income Tax, 91 IOWA L. REV. 1509, 1518 (2006) (suggesting an approach that focuses on legal entitlement to income).
  • 4
    • 46049118263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 5
    • 46049113136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The tax code featured a joint-filing system beginning in 1948. See infra notes 6-7 and accompanying text.
    • The tax code featured a joint-filing system beginning in 1948. See infra notes 6-7 and accompanying text.
  • 6
    • 46049116327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 54. Choosing to file separately does not allow married taxpayers to escape the marital tax brackets. See infra Part I.B. Filing separately would just split the couple's bracket in half. No matter how they file, the couple's tax bracket is assigned on the basis of the fact that they are married. Married taxpayers do not qualify for the same tax brackets as single taxpayers. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007); Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 54. Choosing to file separately does not allow married taxpayers to escape the marital tax brackets. See infra Part I.B. Filing separately would just split the couple's bracket in half. No matter how they file, the couple's tax bracket is assigned on the basis of the fact that they are married. Married taxpayers do not qualify for the same tax brackets as single taxpayers. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007); Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
  • 7
    • 84976115176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In an early case, the United States Supreme Court held that couples in community-property states could split their income for tax purposes, regardless of who earned it. Poe v. Seaborn, 282 U.S. 101, 113, 118 (1930, Yet couples in non-community-property states could not accomplish this result through private contracts. See Lucas v. Earl, 281 U.S. 111, 114-15 1930, holding that a California couple could not contractually arrange to split their income for tax purposes, States quickly enacted pseudo-community-property laws to give their residents tax benefits. MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 45-55. To keep couples in community-property states from having a tax advantage over couples in other states, Congress instituted the joint return. Id. After this change in the code, states that had recently passed community-property statutes promptly abandoned that status. Id. Several critics argue that states wanted to confer tax benefits to proper
    • In an early case, the United States Supreme Court held that couples in community-property states could split their income for tax purposes, regardless of who earned it. Poe v. Seaborn, 282 U.S. 101, 113, 118 (1930). Yet couples in non-community-property states could not accomplish this result through private contracts. See Lucas v. Earl, 281 U.S. 111, 114-15 (1930) (holding that a California couple could not contractually arrange to split their income for tax purposes). States quickly enacted pseudo-community-property laws to give their residents tax benefits. MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 45-55. To keep couples in community-property states from having a tax advantage over couples in other states, Congress instituted the joint return. Id. After this change in the code, states that had recently passed community-property statutes promptly abandoned that status. Id. Several critics argue that states wanted to confer tax benefits to property owners (mostly men) without having to force them to share their property with their spouses. See, e.g., Carolyn C. Jones, Split Income and Separate Spheres: Tax Law and Gender Roles in the 1940s, 6 LAW & HIST. REV. 259, 295-96 (1988);
  • 8
    • 21144476856 scopus 로고
    • Taxation and the Family: A Fresh Look at Behavioral Gender Biases in the Code, 40
    • explaining the remarkable bit of social history accompanying the joint return
    • Edward J. McCaffery, Taxation and the Family: A Fresh Look at Behavioral Gender Biases in the Code, 40 UCLA L. REV. 983, 989-91 (1993) (explaining the "remarkable bit of social history" accompanying the joint return).
    • (1993) UCLA L. REV , vol.983 , pp. 989-991
    • McCaffery, E.J.1
  • 9
    • 46049119073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 54-55. The income shift mostly benefited men, as most women did not participate in the labor force at the time. Id. at 51. For a tool to track women's participation in the workforce over time, see Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment Status of the Civilian Population by Sex and Age, http://stats.bls.gov/webapps/legacy/ cpsatab1.htm (last visited Mar. 5, 2008). Joint filing now accomplishes what private contract could not. Cf. supra note 7.
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 54-55. The income shift mostly benefited men, as most women did not participate in the labor force at the time. Id. at 51. For a tool to track women's participation in the workforce over time, see Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment Status of the Civilian Population by Sex and Age, http://stats.bls.gov/webapps/legacy/ cpsatab1.htm (last visited Mar. 5, 2008). Joint filing now accomplishes what private contract could not. Cf. supra note 7.
  • 10
    • 46049097015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Motro, supra note 3, at 1543-49
    • See Motro, supra note 3, at 1543-49.
  • 11
    • 46049088752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 141-42
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 141-42.
  • 12
    • 46049111479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Most couples earn dual, as opposed to single, incomes. See U.S. Census Bureau, America's Family and Living Arrangements: 2006 tbl.FG2, http://www.census.gov/population/www/socdemo/hh-fam/cps2006.html (last visited Mar. 5, 2008).
    • Most couples earn dual, as opposed to single, incomes. See U.S. Census Bureau, America's Family and Living Arrangements: 2006 tbl.FG2, http://www.census.gov/population/www/socdemo/hh-fam/cps2006.html (last visited Mar. 5, 2008).
  • 13
    • 46049089477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally ELIZABETH WARREN & AMELIA WARREN TYAGI, THE TWO-INCOME TRAP (2003) (explaining that most families today need two incomes for necessary fixed costs).
    • See generally ELIZABETH WARREN & AMELIA WARREN TYAGI, THE TWO-INCOME TRAP (2003) (explaining that most families today need two incomes for necessary fixed costs).
  • 14
    • 46049103622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 16-20 (defining secondary earner and stacking effect).
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 16-20 (defining secondary earner and stacking effect).
  • 15
    • 46049086430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The ability of married couples to file separately does not impact this issue as there is no tax benefit. Married persons filing separately almost always pay more taxes. Id. at 16; see also infra Part I.B.2 (discussing how filing separately is not the same as filing as a single person).
    • The ability of married couples to file separately does not impact this issue as there is no tax benefit. Married persons filing separately almost always pay more taxes. Id. at 16; see also infra Part I.B.2 (discussing how filing separately is not the same as filing as a single person).
  • 16
    • 46049120859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, if a couple has two earners, each making the same amount, one will pay more tax on their income. Consider a couple with $50,000 taxable earnings each, for a total taxable income of $100,000. The total tax under the 2008 rate schedule is $17,688. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 2008 Rate Tables, However, broken down by income, one spouse is contributing $6,698 to the tax bill, while the other contributes a larger share, $10,990, This calculation is achieved by using the joint tax rates on $50,000 and then taking the difference from the total tax bill, The couple's first $50,000 is taxed at a lower rate than the couple's second $50,000, creating a secondary earner. Notice that the tax on a couple with only one spouse working and earning $100,000 as an individual would be the same, but there is no secondary-earner bias since the income is generated by only one person and the tax is pa
    • For example, if a couple has two earners, each making the same amount, one will pay more tax on their income. Consider a couple with $50,000 taxable earnings each, for a total taxable income of $100,000. The total tax under the 2008 rate schedule is $17,688. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables). However, broken down by income, one spouse is contributing $6,698 to the tax bill, while the other contributes a larger share, $10,990. (This calculation is achieved by using the joint tax rates on $50,000 and then taking the difference from the total tax bill.) The couple's first $50,000 is taxed at a lower rate than the couple's second $50,000, creating a secondary earner. Notice that the tax on a couple with only one spouse working and earning $100,000 as an individual would be the same, but there is no secondary-earner bias since the income is generated by only one person and the tax is paid by only one person. See id. This bias is often mistaken as the marriage penalty. See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 19.
  • 17
    • 46049111277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 19. It does not matter whether couples understand the stacking effect. The point is that couples respond to the stacking effect when making decisions. See id. at 11-12 ([W]omen [secondary earners] are not always . . . conscious of the effects [of taxes]. But tax exerts major pressures on all women.).
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 19. It does not matter whether couples understand the stacking effect. The point is that couples respond to the stacking effect when making decisions. See id. at 11-12 ("[W]omen [secondary earners] are not always . . . conscious of the effects [of taxes]. But tax exerts major pressures on all women.").
  • 18
    • 46049106991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19. Other commentators disagree and argue that the proper way to view the joint schedules is to evenly split the tax bill. They argue that since both incomes contribute to the taxes, the tax bill should be seen as equally divided among the incomes. See, e.g., id. (citing HAROLD M. GROVES, FEDERAL TAX TREATMENT OF THE FAMILY 106-07 (1963)). However, since the marital brackets are not double the single brackets, it seems more logical to view the higher income as the one that uses up the lower tax rates, causing the secondary income to be taxed at a higher rate. See id.
    • Id. at 19. Other commentators disagree and argue that the proper way to view the joint schedules is to evenly split the tax bill. They argue that since both incomes contribute to the taxes, the tax bill should be seen as equally divided among the incomes. See, e.g., id. (citing HAROLD M. GROVES, FEDERAL TAX TREATMENT OF THE FAMILY 106-07 (1963)). However, since the marital brackets are not double the single brackets, it seems more logical to view the higher income as the one that uses up the lower tax rates, causing the secondary income to be taxed at a higher rate. See id.
  • 19
    • 46049099018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 21, 23 (noting that most women earn less and that women are usually the secondary earner); U.S. DEP'T OF LABOR, WOMEN IN THE LABOR FORCE: A DATABOOK 66 tbl.25 (2005), available at http://www.bls.gov/cps/wlf-databook-2005.pdf (showing that an increasing number of women are making more money than their husbands);
    • Id. at 21, 23 (noting that most women earn less and that women are usually the secondary earner); U.S. DEP'T OF LABOR, WOMEN IN THE LABOR FORCE: A DATABOOK 66 tbl.25 (2005), available at http://www.bls.gov/cps/wlf-databook-2005.pdf (showing that an increasing number of women are making more money than their husbands);
  • 20
    • 46049092829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Census Bureau, Married Couple Family Groups: 2006 tbl.FG3, http://www.census.gov/population/socdemo/hh-fam/cps2006/tabFG3-all.xls (last visited Mar. 23, 2008) (showing that only 18 percent of wives earn more than their husbands but that 25 percent of couples have roughly equal earnings).
    • U.S. Census Bureau, Married Couple Family Groups: 2006 tbl.FG3, http://www.census.gov/population/socdemo/hh-fam/cps2006/tabFG3-all.xls (last visited Mar. 23, 2008) (showing that only 18 percent of wives earn more than their husbands but that 25 percent of couples have roughly equal earnings).
  • 21
    • 46049104963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kyra Kyles, Making Strides: Women Are Closing the Gap at Work, but It's Not All Equal Yet, CHI. TRIB., Mar. 14, 2006 (discussing the pay gap between women and men).
    • See Kyra Kyles, Making Strides: Women Are Closing the Gap at Work, but It's Not All Equal Yet, CHI. TRIB., Mar. 14, 2006 (discussing the pay gap between women and men).
  • 22
    • 46049108970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS, U.S. DEP'T OF LABOR, CHARTING THE U.S. LABOR MARKET IN 2005 chts.5-8, 5-10 & 6-3 (2006), available at http://www.bls.gov/cps/labor2005/chartbook.pdf (showing an increasing presence of mothers in the workforce and increased incomes for women with respect to men);
    • See BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS, U.S. DEP'T OF LABOR, CHARTING THE U.S. LABOR MARKET IN 2005 chts.5-8, 5-10 & 6-3 (2006), available at http://www.bls.gov/cps/labor2005/chartbook.pdf (showing an increasing presence of mothers in the workforce and increased incomes for women with respect to men);
  • 23
    • 46049101652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, AMERICA'S FAMILY AND LIVING ARRANGEMENTS: 2003, at 10 (2004) (showing significantly more stay-at-home mothers than fathers);
    • U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, AMERICA'S FAMILY AND LIVING ARRANGEMENTS: 2003, at 10 (2004) (showing significantly more stay-at-home mothers than fathers);
  • 24
    • 46049095518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Census Bureau, Married Couple Family Groups: 2006 tbl.FG1, http://www.census.gov/population/socdemo/hh-fam/cps2006/tabFG1-all.xls (last visited Mar. 13, 2008) (2007 data still show more stay-at-home mothers).
    • U.S. Census Bureau, Married Couple Family Groups: 2006 tbl.FG1, http://www.census.gov/population/socdemo/hh-fam/cps2006/tabFG1-all.xls (last visited Mar. 13, 2008) (2007 data still show more stay-at-home mothers).
  • 25
    • 46049093646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
    • Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
  • 26
    • 0345880359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Work done in the home without compensation is called imputed income and is not taxed. See Nancy C. Staudt, Taxing Housework, 84 GEO. L.J. 1571, 1576 & n.18 (1996) ([E]conomic benefits received from self-supplied services or services from a family member are exempt from taxation.). For why homemakers are more likely to be women, see infra Part I.C.4 and sources cited supra note 17.
    • Work done in the home without compensation is called imputed income and is not taxed. See Nancy C. Staudt, Taxing Housework, 84 GEO. L.J. 1571, 1576 & n.18 (1996) ("[E]conomic benefits received from self-supplied services or services from a family member are exempt from taxation."). For why homemakers are more likely to be women, see infra Part I.C.4 and sources cited supra note 17.
  • 27
    • 46049109955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C.
    • See infra Part I.C.
  • 28
    • 46049091606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part.I.C. Of course, this argument applies with equal force if the father is the secondary earner and is facing the decision of staying at home with the children or working outside the home. More fathers are becoming secondary earners. See U.S. Census Bureau, supra note 17.
    • See infra Part.I.C. Of course, this argument applies with equal force if the father is the secondary earner and is facing the decision of staying at home with the children or working outside the home. More fathers are becoming secondary earners. See U.S. Census Bureau, supra note 17.
  • 29
    • 46049119265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 59, 163 ([N]o one at all seemed to be thinking of the biases against working wives . . . .).
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 59, 163 ("[N]o one at all seemed to be thinking of the biases against working wives . . . .").
  • 30
    • 46049117098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 51; see also Marjorie E. Kornhauser, A Legislator Named Sue: Re-imagining the Income Tax, 5 J. GENDER RACE & JUST. 289, 290 (2002) (noting that female policy makers make different choices, including on tax policy; women legislators, regardless of whether they are feminists, act differently from male ones[;] and . . . the presence of female legislators makes a difference).
    • Id. at 51; see also Marjorie E. Kornhauser, A Legislator Named Sue: Re-imagining the Income Tax, 5 J. GENDER RACE & JUST. 289, 290 (2002) (noting that female policy makers make different choices, including on tax policy; "women legislators, regardless of whether they are feminists, act differently from male ones[;] and . . . the presence of female legislators makes a difference").
  • 31
    • 46049089464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 57 (noting that women had little representation in Congress in 1948). In 2006, voters elected the largest percentage of women to both houses of Congress, but women still remained a small minority. See Katharine Mieszkowski, Most. Women. Leaders. Ever!, SALON, Nov. 8, 2006, http://www.salon.com/mwt/ broadsheet/2006/11/08/women/print.html (noting that more women were elected in 2006 than ever before);
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 57 (noting that women had little representation in Congress in 1948). In 2006, voters elected the largest percentage of women to both houses of Congress, but women still remained a small minority. See Katharine Mieszkowski, Most. Women. Leaders. Ever!, SALON, Nov. 8, 2006, http://www.salon.com/mwt/ broadsheet/2006/11/08/women/print.html (noting that more women were elected in 2006 than ever before);
  • 32
    • 46049093426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Breaking Through; Pelosi's Ascent to House Speaker a Boost for Women in U.S. Politics, CHI. TRIB., Jan. 4, 2007 (noting that women now occupy 16 percent of the House of Representatives).
    • Breaking Through; Pelosi's Ascent to House Speaker a Boost for Women in U.S. Politics, CHI. TRIB., Jan. 4, 2007 (noting that women now occupy 16 percent of the House of Representatives).
  • 33
    • 46049092413 scopus 로고
    • See note 2, at, 57, 244 explaining that in the, marriage worked against women joining the workplace
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 33, 57, 244 (explaining that in the 1950s, marriage worked against women joining the workplace).
    • (1950) supra , pp. 33
    • MCCAFFERY1
  • 34
    • 46049090236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, note 19, at tbl.1 family statistics
    • See U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, supra note 19, at 3 tbl.1 (family statistics).
    • supra , pp. 3
  • 35
    • 46049101040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This concern applies to most families. See id. See generally R. Michael Alvarez & Edward J. McCaffery, Gender and Tax, in GENDER AND AMERICAN POLITICS 91, 91-113 Sue Tolleson-Rinehart & Jyl J. Josephson eds, 2000, gender and tax law
    • This concern applies to most families. See id. See generally R. Michael Alvarez & Edward J. McCaffery, Gender and Tax, in GENDER AND AMERICAN POLITICS 91, 91-113 (Sue Tolleson-Rinehart & Jyl J. Josephson eds., 2000) (gender and tax law).
  • 36
    • 46049096798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See The Changing American Family, N.Y. TIMES, May 18, 2001, at A18 (reporting census data); U.S. Census Bureau, supra note 19, at 3 (family statistics); U.S. Census Bureau, supra note 19 (family statistics).
    • See The Changing American Family, N.Y. TIMES, May 18, 2001, at A18 (reporting census data); U.S. Census Bureau, supra note 19, at 3 (family statistics); U.S. Census Bureau, supra note 19 (family statistics).
  • 37
    • 0347936410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For general criticisms of the joint return and a discussion of how the tax code affects women, see MCCAFFERY, supra note 2; Anne L. Alstott, Tax Policy and Feminism: Competing Goals and Institutional Choices, 96 COLUM. L. REV. 2001 (1996);
    • For general criticisms of the joint return and a discussion of how the tax code affects women, see MCCAFFERY, supra note 2; Anne L. Alstott, Tax Policy and Feminism: Competing Goals and Institutional Choices, 96 COLUM. L. REV. 2001 (1996);
  • 38
    • 85055760449 scopus 로고
    • Sexism in the Code: A Comparative Study of Income Taxation of Working Wives and Mothers, 21
    • Grace Blumberg, Sexism in the Code: A Comparative Study of Income Taxation of Working Wives and Mothers, 21 BUFF. L. REV. 49 (1971);
    • (1971) BUFF. L. REV , vol.49
    • Blumberg, G.1
  • 39
    • 46049094894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lora Cicconi, Competing Goals amidst the Opt-Out Revolution: An Examination of Gender-Based Tax Reform in Light of New Data on Female Labor Supply, 42 GONZ. L. REV. 257 (2006-07);
    • Lora Cicconi, Competing Goals amidst the "Opt-Out" Revolution: An Examination of Gender-Based Tax Reform in Light of New Data on Female Labor Supply, 42 GONZ. L. REV. 257 (2006-07);
  • 40
    • 21344496167 scopus 로고
    • Love, Money, and the IRS: Family, Income-Sharing, and the Joint Income Tax Return, 45
    • Staudt, supra note 21;
    • Marjorie E. Kornhauser, Love, Money, and the IRS: Family, Income-Sharing, and the Joint Income Tax Return, 45 HASTINGS L.J. 63 (1993); Staudt, supra note 21;
    • (1993) HASTINGS L.J , vol.63
    • Kornhauser, M.E.1
  • 41
    • 46049095524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Lawrence Zelenak, Marriage and the Income Tax, 67 S. CAL. L. REV. 339 (1994) [hereinafter Zelenak, Marriage and the Income Tax].
    • and Lawrence Zelenak, Marriage and the Income Tax, 67 S. CAL. L. REV. 339 (1994) [hereinafter Zelenak, Marriage and the Income Tax].
  • 42
    • 77954718963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking Critical Tax Theory Seriously, 76
    • hereinafter Zelenak, Critical Tax Theory, For an analysis of this growing body of literature, see
    • For an analysis of this growing body of literature, see Lawrence Zelenak, Taking Critical Tax Theory Seriously, 76 N.C. L. REV. 1521 (1998) [hereinafter Zelenak, Critical Tax Theory].
    • (1998) N.C. L. REV , vol.1521
    • Zelenak, L.1
  • 43
    • 46049111276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Tax Code May Be Facing a Full Rewrite
    • comparing historical tax reforms to more recent proposals, See, Nov. 7, at
    • See Warren Vieth, U.S. Tax Code May Be Facing a Full Rewrite, L.A. TIMES, Nov. 7, 2004, at 27 (comparing historical tax reforms to more recent proposals).
    • (2004) L.A. TIMES , pp. 27
    • Vieth, W.1
  • 44
    • 46049101039 scopus 로고
    • See McCaffery, note 7, at, describing the institution of the joint return in
    • See McCaffery, supra note 7, at 988-94 (describing the institution of the joint return in 1948).
    • (1948) supra , pp. 988-994
  • 45
    • 46049092243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modern families no longer resemble the traditional family. See supra note 30 and accompanying text. The tax code should put one and two-earner families on nominally equal footing. McCaffery, supra note 7, at 1059. Zelenak suggests that the tax code should not take sides in the marriage debate. Lawrence Zelenak, Tax and the Married Woman, 70 S. CAL. L. REV. 1021, 1033-34 (1997) (book review).
    • Modern families no longer resemble the traditional family. See supra note 30 and accompanying text. The tax code should "put one and two-earner families on nominally equal footing." McCaffery, supra note 7, at 1059. Zelenak suggests that the tax code should not take sides in the marriage debate. Lawrence Zelenak, Tax and the Married Woman, 70 S. CAL. L. REV. 1021, 1033-34 (1997) (book review).
  • 46
    • 46049102830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under President Bush, Congress has passed numerous reforms in recent years. See, e.g, Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006, Pub. L. 109-432, 120 Stat. 2922; Tax Increase Prevention and Reconciliation Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 109-222, 120 Stat. 345; American Jobs Creation Act of 2004, Pub. L. No. 108-357, 118 Stat. 1418; Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004, Pub. L. No. 108-311, 118 Stat. 1166; Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003, Pub. L. No. 108-27, 117 Stat. 752; Job Creation and Worker Assistance Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-147, 116 Stat. 21; Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, 115 Stat. 38; see also Grover G. Norquist, Editorial, Outside View: A Tax Cut Every Year, UNITED PRESS INT'L, Sept. 2, 2004 describing the prolific tax cuts
    • Under President Bush, Congress has passed numerous reforms in recent years. See, e.g., Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006, Pub. L. 109-432, 120 Stat. 2922; Tax Increase Prevention and Reconciliation Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 109-222, 120 Stat. 345; American Jobs Creation Act of 2004, Pub. L. No. 108-357, 118 Stat. 1418; Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004, Pub. L. No. 108-311, 118 Stat. 1166; Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003, Pub. L. No. 108-27, 117 Stat. 752; Job Creation and Worker Assistance Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-147, 116 Stat. 21; Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, 115 Stat. 38; see also Grover G. Norquist, Editorial, Outside View: A Tax Cut Every Year, UNITED PRESS INT'L, Sept. 2, 2004 (describing the prolific tax cuts).
  • 47
    • 46049098836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 35
    • See supra note 35.
  • 48
    • 46049093645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The literature began with Professor Blumberg's article in 1971. See Blumberg, supra note 31. However, many scholars began an intensive review of her ideas in the 1990s. See, e.g, Alstott, supra note 31; Kornhauser, supra note 31; Staudt, supra note 21. These critiques culminated in Professor McCaffery's book. See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2. Representative Barbara Kennelly, a former member of the House Committee on Ways and Means, seemed to respond to this growing body of literature by requesting a study on how the federal tax laws impact the taxes of married couples. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, FOR BETTER OR FOR WORSE: MARRIAGE AND THE FEDERAL INCOME TAX 1997, comprehensive study on marriage and the income tax, For more examples of this growing body of literature, see sources cited supra note 31
    • The literature began with Professor Blumberg's article in 1971. See Blumberg, supra note 31. However, many scholars began an intensive review of her ideas in the 1990s. See, e.g., Alstott, supra note 31; Kornhauser, supra note 31; Staudt, supra note 21. These critiques culminated in Professor McCaffery's book. See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2. Representative Barbara Kennelly, a former member of the House Committee on Ways and Means, seemed to respond to this growing body of literature by requesting a study on how the federal tax laws impact the taxes of married couples. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, FOR BETTER OR FOR WORSE: MARRIAGE AND THE FEDERAL INCOME TAX (1997) (comprehensive study on marriage and the income tax). For more examples of this growing body of literature, see sources cited supra note 31.
  • 49
    • 46049107394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The debate that did happen mostly focused on secondary-earner issues rather than the underlying marital bias. See CBO Testimony on Marriage and the Federal Income Tax before the H. Comm. on Ways & Means, 105th Cong. (1998) (statement of June E. O'Neill, Director, Cong. Budget Office), available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/3xx/doc322/020498.pdf. The Ways and Means Committee report on this issue has been virtually ignored by Congress since its completion in 1997. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37 (suggesting reforms, none of which have been enacted).
    • The debate that did happen mostly focused on secondary-earner issues rather than the underlying marital bias. See CBO Testimony on Marriage and the Federal Income Tax before the H. Comm. on Ways & Means, 105th Cong. (1998) (statement of June E. O'Neill, Director, Cong. Budget Office), available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/3xx/doc322/020498.pdf. The Ways and Means Committee report on this issue has been virtually ignored by Congress since its completion in 1997. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37 (suggesting reforms, none of which have been enacted).
  • 50
    • 46049112504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part IV for a discussion of how the decrease in marginal rates, the reduction of the marriage penalty, and the increases in the child-care credit have helped ease the burden on the secondary earner
    • See infra Part IV for a discussion of how the decrease in marginal rates, the reduction of the marriage penalty, and the increases in the child-care credit have helped ease the burden on the secondary earner.
    • infra
  • 51
    • 46049113932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., sources cited supra note 19 (regarding the presence of women in the workforce).
    • See, e.g., sources cited supra note 19 (regarding the presence of women in the workforce).
  • 52
    • 46049087789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Married persons can file either joint or separate returns. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007). Single persons enjoy a larger tax bracket and single taxpayers that qualify to file as Heads of households have the largest tax brackets that an individual may claim. Id. A married person may not file as a head of household or as a single person. Id.; see also Part I.B.2 (explaining that separate returns for married couples are still based on marital tax brackets).
    • Married persons can file either joint or separate returns. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007). Single persons enjoy a larger tax bracket and single taxpayers that qualify to file as "Heads of households" have the largest tax brackets that an individual may claim. Id. A married person may not file as a head of household or as a single person. Id.; see also Part I.B.2 (explaining that separate returns for married couples are still based on marital tax brackets).
  • 53
    • 46049121051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, note 19, at, statistics
    • See U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, supra note 19, at 3 (statistics).
    • supra , pp. 3
  • 54
    • 46049095097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 277-78 (suggesting that Congress tax married men more); Motro, supra note 3, at 1518 (suggesting an approach that focuses on legal entitlement to income); Zelenak, Marriage and the Income Tax, supra note 31, at 405 (arguing that the current tax treatment of marriage gets it wrong).
    • See, e.g., MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 277-78 (suggesting that Congress tax married men more); Motro, supra note 3, at 1518 (suggesting an approach that focuses on legal entitlement to income); Zelenak, Marriage and the Income Tax, supra note 31, at 405 (arguing that the current tax treatment of marriage gets it wrong).
  • 55
    • 46049105376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is what Professor Zelenak and others propose. See, e.g, Amy C. Christian, The Joint Return Rate Structure: Identifying and Addressing the Gendered Nature of the Tax Law, 13 J.L. & POL. 241, 246 (1997, criticizing the joint return, supra note 31 collecting sources, see also infra Part IV.A.1
    • This is what Professor Zelenak and others propose. See, e.g., Amy C. Christian, The Joint Return Rate Structure: Identifying and Addressing the Gendered Nature of the Tax Law, 13 J.L. & POL. 241, 246 (1997) (criticizing the joint return); supra note 31 (collecting sources); see also infra Part IV.A.1.
  • 56
    • 46049099636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is what Professor Motro proposes. Motro, supra note 3, at 1543-44 suggesting an approach that focuses on legal entitlement to income
    • This is what Professor Motro proposes. Motro, supra note 3, at 1543-44 (suggesting an approach that focuses on legal entitlement to income).
  • 57
    • 46049089659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.C.
    • See infra Part IV.C.
  • 58
    • 46049110153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally sources cited supra note 31
    • See generally sources cited supra note 31.
  • 59
    • 46049107870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McCaffery, supra note 7, at 993
    • McCaffery, supra note 7, at 993.
  • 60
    • 46049092014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 991
    • Id. at 991.
  • 61
    • 46049115511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 996. The effects are most dramatic when both spouses have roughly equivalent incomes. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 19.
    • See id. at 996. The effects are most dramatic when both spouses have roughly equivalent incomes. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 19.
  • 62
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 7 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 7 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 64
    • 46049088751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McCaffery, supra note 7, at 989-94
    • McCaffery, supra note 7, at 989-94.
  • 65
    • 46049103623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The tax code basically pretends that both spouses contribute toward the income
    • at
    • Id. The tax code basically pretends that both spouses contribute toward the income. See id. at 991.
    • See id , pp. 991
  • 66
    • 46049089134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 993; CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1 (finding that current marriage bonuses cost billions of dollars each year).
    • See id. at 993; CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1 (finding that current marriage bonuses cost billions of dollars each year).
  • 67
    • 46049091031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McCaffery, supra note 7, at 991
    • See McCaffery, supra note 7, at 991.
  • 68
    • 46049113549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Motro, supra note 3, at 1518
    • See Motro, supra note 3, at 1518.
  • 69
    • 46049100636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kornhauser, supra note 31, at 105-06 (questioning the assumption that married couples actually share money equally).
    • See Kornhauser, supra note 31, at 105-06 (questioning the assumption that married couples actually share money equally).
  • 70
    • 46049115120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lucas v. Earl, 281 U.S. 111, 114-15 (1930), held that money has to be attributed to the one who earns it. On the joint, return both spouses are jointly and severally liable for reporting the tax correctly, leading to the innocent-spouse problem when the income earner evades taxes and leaves the homemaker liable for paying them. See, e.g., Amy C. Christian, Joint and Several Liability and the Joint Return: Its Implications for Women, 66 U. CIN. L. REV. 535, 536-37 (1998); Motro, supra note 3, at 1532;
    • Lucas v. Earl, 281 U.S. 111, 114-15 (1930), held that money has to be attributed to the one who earns it. On the joint, return both spouses are jointly and severally liable for reporting the tax correctly, leading to the "innocent-spouse" problem when the income earner evades taxes and leaves the homemaker liable for paying them. See, e.g., Amy C. Christian, Joint and Several Liability and the Joint Return: Its Implications for Women, 66 U. CIN. L. REV. 535, 536-37 (1998); Motro, supra note 3, at 1532;
  • 71
    • 46049087981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Christopher B. Wyrick, Comment, Till Death Do Us Part - Including Our Taxes: Inequity Abounds in Spousal Joint and Several Tax Liability and the Innocent Spouse Rule, 6 KAN. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 163, 163-64 (1997).
    • Christopher B. Wyrick, Comment, Till Death Do Us Part - Including Our Taxes: Inequity Abounds in Spousal Joint and Several Tax Liability and the "Innocent Spouse" Rule, 6 KAN. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 163, 163-64 (1997).
  • 72
    • 46049116326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While the couple could file separate returns, tax rates always depend on marital status. Thus, even on separate returns, the tax code indirectly taxes them as one unit. See infra Part I.B.2
    • While the couple could file separate returns, tax rates always depend on marital status. Thus, even on separate returns, the tax code indirectly taxes them as one unit. See infra Part I.B.2.
  • 73
    • 46049119676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Motro, supra note 3, at 1513-14 & n.8 (citing examples of same-sex couples, relatives, friends, and others who live together, share finances, and function as a family but are denied the marriage bonuses sometimes enjoyed by traditional couples).
    • Motro, supra note 3, at 1513-14 & n.8 (citing examples of same-sex couples, relatives, friends, and others who live together, share finances, and function as a family but are denied the marriage bonuses sometimes enjoyed by traditional couples).
  • 74
    • 46049111668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress instituted the joint return in 1948, making the married tax brackets double the size of the single brackets. Revenue Act of 1948, Pub. L. No. 471-168, tit. III, pt. I, 62 Stat. 110, 114-16.
    • Congress instituted the joint return in 1948, making the married tax brackets double the size of the single brackets. Revenue Act of 1948, Pub. L. No. 471-168, tit. III, pt. I, 62 Stat. 110, 114-16.
  • 75
    • 46049121053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 76
    • 46049109163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a married person earning $10,000 enjoyed the same tax rate as a single taxpayer earning only $5,000. See id. The higher the taxpayer's earnings, the greater the tax benefit of shifting some of this income into lower tax brackets via joint filing. See id.
    • For example, a married person earning $10,000 enjoyed the same tax rate as a single taxpayer earning only $5,000. See id. The higher the taxpayer's earnings, the greater the tax benefit of shifting some of this income into lower tax brackets via joint filing. See id.
  • 77
    • 46049105787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a married person with a stay-at-home spouse could now earn twice as much as a single person and stay in a lower rate bracket. See id.
    • For example, a married person with a stay-at-home spouse could now earn twice as much as a single person and stay in a lower rate bracket. See id.
  • 78
    • 46049089465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Tax Reform Act of 1969, Pub. L. No. 91-172, § 803, 83 Stat. 487, 678-81. This act reduced the tax brackets for joint filers so that they were no longer double the brackets for single filers, thus introducing marriage penalties. Id. The brackets were still larger than the brackets for single filers, so many couples still enjoyed a marriage bonus. But it was less than it was before. Id.
    • See Tax Reform Act of 1969, Pub. L. No. 91-172, § 803, 83 Stat. 487, 678-81. This act reduced the tax brackets for joint filers so that they were no longer double the brackets for single filers, thus introducing marriage penalties. Id. The brackets were still larger than the brackets for single filers, so many couples still enjoyed a marriage bonus. But it was less than it was before. Id.
  • 79
    • 46049119480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables). Tax rate tables are found in section 1 of the Internal Revenue Code, but the amounts are updated each year to account for inflation, usually through a revenue ruling. I.R.C. § 1(f) (West 2007).
    • Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables). Tax rate tables are found in section 1 of the Internal Revenue Code, but the amounts are updated each year to account for inflation, usually through a revenue ruling. I.R.C. § 1(f) (West 2007).
  • 80
    • 46049118253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 19-20
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 19-20.
  • 81
    • 46049099649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C.
    • See infra Part I.C.
  • 82
    • 46049091411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59-60.
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59-60.
  • 83
    • 46049115718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the purposes of this refers to countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD
    • For the purposes of this Comment, developed countries refers to countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).
    • developed countries
    • Comment1
  • 84
    • 46049111673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59. (In 1993, of the 27 countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 19 imposed income taxes separately on husbands and wives . . . .). Professor Zelenak has argued that separate taxation is feasible in the United States. See Lawrence Zelenak, Doing Something About Marriage Penalties: A Guide for the Perplexed, 54 TAX L. REV. 1, 46-47 (2000).
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59. ("In 1993, of the 27 countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 19 imposed income taxes separately on husbands and wives . . . ."). Professor Zelenak has argued that separate taxation is feasible in the United States. See Lawrence Zelenak, Doing Something About Marriage Penalties: A Guide for the Perplexed, 54 TAX L. REV. 1, 46-47 (2000).
  • 85
    • 46049116317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Each taxpayer stands alone, so there is no secondary earner, although the concept could be reintroduced through tax credits or other mechanisms
    • Each taxpayer stands alone, so there is no secondary earner, although the concept could be reintroduced through tax credits or other mechanisms.
  • 86
    • 46049097407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59-60.
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59-60.
  • 87
    • 46049109568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 88
    • 46049095960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.A.1-2.
    • See supra Part I.A.1-2.
  • 89
    • 46049096604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59; Ayla A. Lari, Sharing Alike: French Family Taxation as a Model for Reform, 37 DUQ. L. REV. 207, 231-42 (1999) (describing the French system as it existed in 1995 under L'impôt sur le revenu as codified in the Code Général des Impôts).
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59; Ayla A. Lari, Sharing Alike: French Family Taxation as a Model for Reform, 37 DUQ. L. REV. 207, 231-42 (1999) (describing the French system as it existed in 1995 under L'impôt sur le revenu as codified in the Code Général des Impôts).
  • 90
    • 46049119675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Splitting income allows the shift that is inherent in the stacking effect. See supra Part I.A.1-2. Lari notes that the French tax code was intended to benefit the traditional one-earner family. Lari, supra note 77, at 240.
    • Splitting income allows the shift that is inherent in the stacking effect. See supra Part I.A.1-2. Lari notes that the French tax code was intended to benefit the traditional one-earner family. Lari, supra note 77, at 240.
  • 91
    • 46049096412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In France, substantial marriage penalties exist for dual-earning couples, just as they do in the United States. Lari, supra note 77, at 241
    • In France, substantial marriage penalties exist for dual-earning couples, just as they do in the United States. Lari, supra note 77, at 241.
  • 92
    • 46049109384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59.
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59.
  • 93
    • 46049091808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marriage bonuses are due to the large brackets for joint taxpayers in Germany
    • Id. Marriage bonuses are due to the large brackets for joint taxpayers in Germany. Id.
    • Id
  • 94
    • 46049091212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 95
    • 46049121382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 60
    • Id. at 60.
  • 96
    • 46049095295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 59-60
    • Id. at 59-60.
  • 97
    • 46049103036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 98
    • 46049115525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 59
    • Id. at 59.
  • 99
    • 46049090248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (finding that most countries tax income on an individual basis).
    • Id. (finding that most countries tax income on an individual basis).
  • 100
    • 46049099650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.A.
    • See infra Part IV.A.
  • 101
    • 46049102249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Zelenak, supra note 72, at 46-47
    • See Zelenak, supra note 72, at 46-47.
  • 102
    • 46049116325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59-60.
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 59-60.
  • 103
    • 46049085249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.A.
    • See infra Part IV.A.
  • 104
    • 46049093654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.B-C.
    • See infra Part IV.B-C.
  • 105
    • 46049114931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Not all dual-earning couples necessarily face a marriage penalty. A penalty only results when the combined income of the spouses reaches a higher tax bracket than it would if the spouses filed as single taxpayers. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007); CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1 (discussing marriage penalties).
    • Not all dual-earning couples necessarily face a marriage penalty. A penalty only results when the combined income of the spouses reaches a higher tax bracket than it would if the spouses filed as single taxpayers. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007); CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1 (discussing marriage penalties).
  • 107
    • 46049097014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1022. For example, imagine a couple where each spouse has $85,000 of taxable income each year. Under the 2008 rate tables, before marriage their total tax bill would have been $35,557 (two single taxpayers). After their marriage, their tax bill rises to $36,344 ($170,000 on a joint return). The additional $787 in tax is the marriage penalty on that couple. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (using 2008 Rate Tables).
    • Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1022. For example, imagine a couple where each spouse has $85,000 of taxable income each year. Under the 2008 rate tables, before marriage their total tax bill would have been $35,557 (two single taxpayers). After their marriage, their tax bill rises to $36,344 ($170,000 on a joint return). The additional $787 in tax is the marriage penalty on that couple. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (using 2008 Rate Tables).
  • 108
    • 46049098015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 23-26. This result should be expected because with two incomes, the couple cannot split one of the incomes into a lower tax bracket as traditional families do.
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 23-26. This result should be expected because with two incomes, the couple cannot split one of the incomes into a lower tax bracket as traditional families do.
  • 109
    • 46049102842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.A.1-2.
    • See supra Part I.A.1-2.
  • 110
    • 46049092231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1.
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1.
  • 111
    • 46049112280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 112
    • 46049111064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1022
    • Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1022.
  • 113
    • 46049107200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007) (separate filing status allowed).
    • See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007) (separate filing status allowed).
  • 114
    • 46049083256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SAMUEL A. DONALDSON, FEDERAL INCOME TAXATION OF INDIVIDUALS 7 (2005, In the vast majority of cases, married couples pay less total tax if they file a joint-return, Filing separately does not allow the higher-earning spouse to shift income to the lower-earning spouse; instead, each spouse uses half of the marital brackets to file his or her income. Yet the tax brackets for each individual spouse are smaller than those for a single taxpayer, so the couple is not filing in the same brackets as a single person would. Unless the couple's salaries are substantially equal, if they file separately, one of their incomes will likely fall into a higher tax bracket than it otherwise would, resulting in more total tax for that couple. See I.R.C. § 1; Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables, MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 66 referencing income splitting, Howeve
    • See SAMUEL A. DONALDSON, FEDERAL INCOME TAXATION OF INDIVIDUALS 7 (2005) ("In the vast majority of cases, married couples pay less total tax if they file a joint-return.") Filing separately does not allow the higher-earning spouse to shift income to the lower-earning spouse; instead, each spouse uses half of the marital brackets to file his or her income. Yet the tax brackets for each individual spouse are smaller than those for a single taxpayer, so the couple is not filing in the same brackets as a single person would. Unless the couple's salaries are substantially equal, if they file separately, one of their incomes will likely fall into a higher tax bracket than it otherwise would, resulting in more total tax for that couple. See I.R.C. § 1; Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables); MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 66 (referencing income splitting). However, the separate tax brackets for married taxpayers are smaller than those for single taxpayers. See I.R.C. § 1.
  • 115
    • 46049111681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See I.R.C. § 1; Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
    • See I.R.C. § 1; Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
  • 116
    • 46049095519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This follows from the fact that without income shifting, the spouses' highest tax rate applies to more income than it would with the combined brackets. See I.R.C. § 1; Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 2008 Rate Tables
    • This follows from the fact that without income shifting, the spouses' highest tax rate applies to more income than it would with the combined brackets. See I.R.C. § 1; Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
  • 117
    • 46049083608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Professor Zelenak summarizes Professor McCaffery's argument, At lower income levels, the need for cash income is so great and the marriage penalties are so severe that the most likely effect of the tax rules is not that wives stay home but that marriages fall apart. Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1022-23
    • As Professor Zelenak summarizes Professor McCaffery's argument, "At lower income levels, the need for cash income is so great and the marriage penalties are so severe that the most likely effect of the tax rules is not that wives stay home but that marriages fall apart." Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1022-23.
  • 118
    • 46049106791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 138-42, 145-50
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 138-42, 145-50.
  • 119
    • 46049092621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Steuerle Addresses Marriage Penalties at Ways and Means Panel Hearing, TAX NOTES TODAY, May 23, 2001, http://www.taxanalysts.com.
    • See Steuerle Addresses Marriage Penalties at Ways and Means Panel Hearing, TAX NOTES TODAY, May 23, 2001, http://www.taxanalysts.com.
  • 120
    • 0000621240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anne L. Alstott, The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Limitations of Tax-Based Welfare Reform, 108 HARV. L. REV. 533, 558-64 (1995) (noting that under a joint return, credits like the Earned Income Tax Credit automatically include trade-offs like marriage penalties); Zelenak, supra note 72, at 46-47;
    • Anne L. Alstott, The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Limitations of Tax-Based Welfare Reform, 108 HARV. L. REV. 533, 558-64 (1995) (noting that under a joint return, credits like the Earned Income Tax Credit automatically include trade-offs like marriage penalties); Zelenak, supra note 72, at 46-47;
  • 121
    • 46049093250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Lawrence Zelenak, Redesigning the Earned Income Tax Credit as a Family-Size Adjustment to the Minimum Wage, 57 TAX L. REV. 301 (2004) (proposing that the Earned Income Tax Credit be directly tied to wages and family size).
    • see also Lawrence Zelenak, Redesigning the Earned Income Tax Credit as a Family-Size Adjustment to the Minimum Wage, 57 TAX L. REV. 301 (2004) (proposing that the Earned Income Tax Credit be directly tied to wages and family size).
  • 122
    • 46049093039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 138-42, 145-50
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 138-42, 145-50.
  • 123
    • 84869249947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Welfare to Work, last visited Mar. 15
    • See, e.g., Welfare to Work, http://www.opm.gov/wtw/index.htm#intro (last visited Mar. 15, 2008).
    • (2008) See, e.g
  • 124
    • 46049087193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 138-42, 145-50
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 138-42, 145-50.
  • 125
    • 46049100822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See I.R.C. § 32 2000, prior to the Bush-administration tax reforms, In other words, if the taxpayer married another person with an income, the phaseout amount did not change, but, of course, the amount of income on their joint return increased because the family had two incomes instead of one. This makes sense if the low-income taxpayer married a wealthy individual but makes less sense if both of the taxpayers relied on the credit before marriage. The couple already lost one credit by marriage, but their remaining credit could also phase out if their combined incomes reach the phaseout range. This creates a double setback for low-income taxpayers contemplating marriage. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 17-18. For a discussion on how the recent tax cuts slightly changed the Earned Income Tax Credit, see infra Part III.B
    • See I.R.C. § 32 (2000) (prior to the Bush-administration tax reforms). In other words, if the taxpayer married another person with an income, the phaseout amount did not change, but, of course, the amount of income on their joint return increased because the family had two incomes instead of one. This makes sense if the low-income taxpayer married a wealthy individual but makes less sense if both of the taxpayers relied on the credit before marriage. The couple already lost one credit by marriage, but their remaining credit could also phase out if their combined incomes reach the phaseout range. This creates a double setback for low-income taxpayers contemplating marriage. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 17-18. For a discussion on how the recent tax cuts slightly changed the Earned Income Tax Credit, see infra Part III.B.
  • 126
    • 46049110154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 32 (2000) (prior to the Bush-administration tax reforms). For a full description of the pre-2001 penalties, see CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 17-20, and Alstott, supra note 108, at 559-64.
    • I.R.C. § 32 (2000) (prior to the Bush-administration tax reforms). For a full description of the pre-2001 penalties, see CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 17-20, and Alstott, supra note 108, at 559-64.
  • 127
    • 46049109383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III.B.
    • See infra Part III.B.
  • 128
    • 46049120077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 32 (2000) (prior to the Bush-administration tax reforms).
    • I.R.C. § 32 (2000) (prior to the Bush-administration tax reforms).
  • 129
    • 46049119479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 23. Under the 1996 tax laws, the report finds a marriage penalty of $6,001 for married taxpayers with four children, with each spouse earning $11,610. Id. This is a hefty penalty for a family of four with a household income under $25,000. Considering that the minimum wage in 1996 was $4.75 per hour, for an annual income of $9,880 (working full time, two taxpayers that earned just above the minimum wage would lose $6,000 just by getting married. See 29 U.S.C. 206 1996, setting the minimum wage at not less than $4.75 an hour during the year beginning on October 1, 1996, In his calculations for 2003, Professor Hoffman found a marriage penalty of $6,886 for married taxpayers with four children, with each spouse earning $15,000. Saul D. Hoffman, Marriage Tax Relief in the Earned Income Tax Credit, 104 TAX
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 23. Under the 1996 tax laws, the report finds a marriage penalty of $6,001 for married taxpayers with four children, with each spouse earning $11,610. Id. This is a hefty penalty for a family of four with a household income under $25,000. Considering that the minimum wage in 1996 was $4.75 per hour, for an annual income of $9,880 (working full time), two taxpayers that earned just above the minimum wage would lose $6,000 just by getting married. See 29 U.S.C. 206 (1996) (setting the minimum wage at "not less than $4.75 an hour during the year beginning on October 1, 1996"). In his calculations for 2003, Professor Hoffman found a marriage penalty of $6,886 for married taxpayers with four children, with each spouse earning $15,000. Saul D. Hoffman, Marriage Tax Relief in the Earned Income Tax Credit, 104 TAX NOTES 935 (2004). While it may be argued that the couple's expenses are less because they share living expenses, it is unlikely that this offsets a more than $5,000 tax penalty (over $400 a month), especially considering that the expenses for the children will remain relatively constant.
  • 130
    • 27944443275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Adam Carasso & C. Eugene Steuerle, The Hefty Penalty on Marriage Facing Many Households with Children, THE FUTURE OF CHILDREN, Fall 2005, at 157, 157-61 (noting that poor households face high marriage penalties, yet marriage is beneficial to fight poverty);
    • See Adam Carasso & C. Eugene Steuerle, The Hefty Penalty on Marriage Facing Many Households with Children, THE FUTURE OF CHILDREN, Fall 2005, at 157, 157-61 (noting that poor households face high marriage penalties, yet marriage is beneficial to fight poverty);
  • 131
    • 34247198222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Not to Be Poor
    • most federal aid goes to unwed parents, Oct. 24, at
    • Robert Rector, How Not to Be Poor, NAT'L REV., Oct. 24, 2005, at 26 (most federal aid goes to unwed parents).
    • (2005) NAT'L REV , pp. 26
    • Rector, R.1
  • 132
    • 46049117100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poverty Report
    • discussing the Clinton-administration welfare reforms, sources cited supra note 117 noting that marriage is beneficial to fight poverty, See, e.g, Sept. 28, at
    • See, e.g., A Good Poverty Report, WASH. POST, Sept. 28, 2000, at A30 (discussing the Clinton-administration welfare reforms); sources cited supra note 117 (noting that marriage is beneficial to fight poverty).
    • (2000) WASH. POST
    • Good, A.1
  • 133
    • 46049109372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Out of Love with Marriage?
    • B]oth Republicans and Democrats think marriage matters, See, e.g, Dec. 26, at
    • See, e.g., Cheryl Wetzstein, U.S. Out of Love with Marriage?, WASH. TIMES, Dec. 26, 2006, at A1 ("[B]oth Republicans and Democrats think marriage matters . . . .").
    • (2006) WASH. TIMES
    • Wetzstein, C.1
  • 134
    • 46049109164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1021-22
    • Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1021-22.
  • 135
    • 46049088937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Alstott, supra note 31, at 2009; supra notes 13-15 and accompanying text.
    • See Alstott, supra note 31, at 2009; supra notes 13-15 and accompanying text.
  • 136
    • 46049115709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 19
    • See sources cited supra note 19.
  • 137
    • 46049108794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This benefit often comes at a cost. The stay-at-home parent is not compensated for his or her work and often reenters the workforce at a lower salary. See infra Part I.C.4
    • This benefit often comes at a cost. The stay-at-home parent is not compensated for his or her work and often reenters the workforce at a lower salary. See infra Part I.C.4.
  • 138
    • 46049086422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This result seems intolerable considering that a sizeable percentage of married couples earn two incomes. See sources cited supra note 11. Although many families have two earners, the tax code's impact on the decision to work should not be overlooked. The Reagan-administration tax reforms significantly, though inadvertently, benefited the secondary earner and probably caused many women to reenter the workforce. See Nada Eissa, Taxation and Labor Supply of Married Women: The Tax Reform Act of 1986 as a Natural Experiment NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 5023, 1995, available at
    • This result seems intolerable considering that a sizeable percentage of married couples earn two incomes. See sources cited supra note 11. Although many families have two earners, the tax code's impact on the decision to work should not be overlooked. The Reagan-administration tax reforms significantly, though inadvertently, benefited the secondary earner and probably caused many women to reenter the workforce. See Nada Eissa, Taxation and Labor Supply of Married Women: The Tax Reform Act of 1986 as a Natural Experiment (NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 5023, 1995), available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w5023.
  • 139
    • 46049093428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 17
    • See sources cited supra note 17.
  • 140
    • 46049103209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 17
    • See sources cited supra note 17.
  • 141
    • 46049118074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Alstott, supra note 31, at 2009; sources cited supra note 17.
    • See Alstott, supra note 31, at 2009; sources cited supra note 17.
  • 142
    • 46049100823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A.
    • See infra Part II.A.
  • 143
    • 46049114923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 19
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 19.
  • 144
    • 46049100637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A.
    • See infra Part II.A.
  • 145
    • 46049119066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1.
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 1.
  • 146
    • 46049095083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is because the secondary earner is still taxed on the margins, even if the family ultimately gets a marriage bonus. See, e.g, Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1021-22 comparing marriage bonus to the stacking effect
    • This is because the secondary earner is still taxed on the margins, even if the family ultimately gets a marriage bonus. See, e.g., Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1021-22 (comparing marriage bonus to the stacking effect).
  • 147
    • 46049115708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The married spouses must use a marital tax bracket when they file, and they only get one bracket. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007); supra Part I.A. If they file separately, they only get half the marital bracket instead of the full single bracket. See supra Part I.B.2.
    • The married spouses must use a marital tax bracket when they file, and they only get one bracket. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007); supra Part I.A. If they file separately, they only get half the marital bracket instead of the full single bracket. See supra Part I.B.2.
  • 148
    • 46049085843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1021-22 (comparing the marriage bonus to the stacking effect).
    • See, e.g., Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1021-22 (comparing the marriage bonus to the stacking effect).
  • 149
    • 46049090434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (explaining McCaffery's view of the stacking effect).
    • Id. (explaining McCaffery's view of the stacking effect).
  • 150
    • 46049106583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The husband's share of the tax liability would be $8,198. This result accounts for the fact that only one salary falls into the lower rate brackets, bumping the other salary into higher rate brackets. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables). This calculation is simplified; it is based on taxable income and assumes that all deductions, credits, and other nuances have been accounted for.
    • The husband's share of the tax liability would be $8,198. This result accounts for the fact that only one salary falls into the lower rate brackets, bumping the other salary into higher rate brackets. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables). This calculation is simplified; it is based on taxable income and assumes that all deductions, credits, and other nuances have been accounted for.
  • 151
    • 46049092833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The wife contributes 45 percent of the couple's total taxable income of $110,000 while she pays 59 percent of the couple's tax liability, according to secondary-earner theory. See I.R.C. § 1; MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 23-25.
    • The wife contributes 45 percent of the couple's total taxable income of $110,000 while she pays 59 percent of the couple's tax liability, according to secondary-earner theory. See I.R.C. § 1; MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 23-25.
  • 152
    • 46049115121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This result worsens when considering the pay gap women already face. See, e.g, Kyles, supra note 18; see also Heather Boushey, Op-Ed, Narrowing the Pay Gap, BOSTON GLOBE, Apr. 20, 2004, at A15, proposing that women get a tax credit for the wage gap, Notice that a couple with only one working spouse earning $110,000 would owe the same taxes, but there is no secondary earner because one spouse earns the entire income. In that case, a couple pays less tax than a single person earning the same amount. See I.R.C. § 1. While many justify the income split on the basis of marital income pooling, there is no logical reason to limit this to just married couples when many other groups also benefit from resource pooling. See Motro, supra note 3 arguing that the income-splitting benefit should be expanded to all couples that share their income, regardless of marital status, Other commentators, however, have argued
    • This result worsens when considering the pay gap women already face. See, e.g., Kyles, supra note 18; see also Heather Boushey, Op-Ed., Narrowing the Pay Gap, BOSTON GLOBE, Apr. 20, 2004, at A15. (proposing that women get a tax credit for the wage gap). Notice that a couple with only one working spouse earning $110,000 would owe the same taxes, but there is no secondary earner because one spouse earns the entire income. In that case, a couple pays less tax than a single person earning the same amount. See I.R.C. § 1. While many justify the income split on the basis of marital income pooling, there is no logical reason to limit this to just married couples when many other groups also benefit from resource pooling. See Motro, supra note 3 (arguing that the income-splitting benefit should be expanded to all couples that share their income, regardless of marital status). Other commentators, however, have argued that the marital tax bill should not be divided; it should be viewed as a whole. See, e.g., MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 23-24 (discussing McIntyre's view, among others).
  • 154
    • 33846917142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 19; McCaffery, supra note 7, at 985 (noting that women's entrance into the workplace seems largely to have added extra workplace responsibilities to the wife's burdens, while holding most of the husband's activities and the wife's nonmarket production constant). But see Mick Cunningham, Influences of Women's Employment on the Gendered Division of Household Labor over the Life Course: Evidence from a 31-Year Panel Study, 28 J. FAM. ISSUES 422 (2007) (finding that the division of household labor is becoming more equal).
    • See sources cited supra note 19; McCaffery, supra note 7, at 985 (noting that women's entrance into the workplace seems "largely to have added extra workplace responsibilities to the wife's burdens, while holding most of the husband's activities and the wife's nonmarket production constant"). But see Mick Cunningham, Influences of Women's Employment on the Gendered Division of Household Labor over the Life Course: Evidence from a 31-Year Panel Study, 28 J. FAM. ISSUES 422 (2007) (finding that the division of household labor is becoming more equal).
  • 155
    • 46049116905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, picture a couple with two children. If the husband makes $100,000 a year and the wife makes $20,000, the couple will probably view the child-care expenses as coming from the wife's salary because her job earns less money. If the child-care expenses are too expensive for the family, it is clearly the wife who will quit her job to take care of the children. So her salary is the one burdened with the child-care expenses.
    • For example, picture a couple with two children. If the husband makes $100,000 a year and the wife makes $20,000, the couple will probably view the child-care expenses as coming from the wife's salary because her job earns less money. If the child-care expenses are too expensive for the family, it is clearly the wife who will quit her job to take care of the children. So her salary is the one "burdened" with the child-care expenses.
  • 156
    • 46049100648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stay-at-Home Fathers Face Isolation and a Lingering Stigma
    • reporting that stay-at-home fathers are still in the minority, See, Dec. 22, at
    • See Jennifer Medina, Stay-at-Home Fathers Face Isolation and a Lingering Stigma, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 22, 2004, at B1 (reporting that stay-at-home fathers are still in the minority);
    • (2004) N.Y. TIMES
    • Medina, J.1
  • 158
    • 33947712364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 19 citing statistics
    • See supra note 19 (citing statistics).
    • See supra
  • 159
    • 46049105572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally McCaffery, supra note 7, at 984, 1020-25
    • See generally McCaffery, supra note 7, at 984, 1020-25.
  • 160
    • 46049100249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1005-11. Examples of mixed business-personal use items would be home computers, cell phones, home-office supplies, etc. See I.R.C. § 212 (West 2007) (allowing deduction for expenses incurred to produce income). The code, however, does provide for a child-care credit. See infra Part II.C.2.
    • Id. at 1005-11. Examples of mixed business-personal use items would be home computers, cell phones, home-office supplies, etc. See I.R.C. § 212 (West 2007) (allowing deduction for expenses incurred to produce income). The code, however, does provide for a child-care credit. See infra Part II.C.2.
  • 161
    • 46049089265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally McCaffery, supra note 7 at 1020-25
    • See generally McCaffery, supra note 7 at 1020-25.
  • 162
    • 46049084641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • After paying their taxes and child-care bills, many taxpayers are left with surprisingly little take-home pay. See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, 145-50.
    • After paying their taxes and child-care bills, many taxpayers are left with surprisingly little take-home pay. See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, 145-50.
  • 163
    • 46049107395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Women, Fairness, and Social Security, 82
    • cf. Staudt, supra note 21 suggesting that Social Security account for housework, See
    • See Karen C. Burke & Grayson M.P. McCouch, Women, Fairness, and Social Security, 82 IOWA L. REV. 1209, 1217 (1997); cf. Staudt, supra note 21 (suggesting that Social Security account for housework).
    • (1997) IOWA L. REV , vol.1209 , pp. 1217
    • Burke, K.C.1    McCouch, G.M.P.2
  • 164
    • 46049085647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McCaffery, supra note 7, at 996-1001 noting that Social Security taxes come close to matching the government revenues from the income tax
    • See McCaffery, supra note 7, at 996-1001 (noting that Social Security taxes come close to matching the government revenues from the income tax).
  • 165
    • 46049099007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 166
    • 46049092223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 167
    • 46049105160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (noting that the law works well for widows but becomes more complicated for divorced or remarried women because the rules change for such individuals).
    • Id. (noting that the law works well for widows but becomes more complicated for divorced or remarried women because the rules change for such individuals).
  • 168
    • 46049086046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 169
    • 46049111264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The benefits formula is complicated, and the secondary earner's average salary and time spent in the workforce will determine the amount of his or her Social Security benefits. Id.
    • The benefits formula is complicated, and the secondary earner's average salary and time spent in the workforce will determine the amount of his or her Social Security benefits. Id.
  • 170
    • 46049107577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 171
    • 46049098412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is because, whether or not he or she worked, the secondary earner may always elect the spouse's benefit. Id
    • This is because, whether or not he or she worked, the secondary earner may always elect the spouse's benefit. Id.
  • 172
    • 46049086997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., SocialSecurity.gov, Frequently Asked Retirement Questions, http://www.socialsecurity.gov/planners/faqs.htm (last visited Mar. 3, 2008) (explaining that the calculation is based on all covered earnings for years spent in the workforce).
    • See, e.g., SocialSecurity.gov, Frequently Asked Retirement Questions, http://www.socialsecurity.gov/planners/faqs.htm (last visited Mar. 3, 2008) (explaining that the calculation is based on all covered earnings for years spent in the workforce).
  • 173
    • 46049101049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 19
    • See sources cited supra note 19.
  • 174
    • 46049121380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Staudt, supra note 21, at 1576 n. 18.
    • See Staudt, supra note 21, at 1576 n. 18.
  • 175
    • 46049095096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.C.1.
    • See supra Part II.C.1.
  • 176
    • 46049094030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Staudt, supra note 21, at 1576
    • See Staudt, supra note 21, at 1576.
  • 177
    • 46049083435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Zelenak points out that, in most cases, secondary earners can still make money, albeit in surprisingly small amounts. Zelenak, Tax and the Married Woman, supra note 34, at 1026
    • Professor Zelenak points out that, in most cases, secondary earners can still make money, albeit in surprisingly small amounts. Zelenak, Tax and the Married Woman, supra note 34, at 1026.
  • 178
    • 46049102239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because imputed income is not taxed, taxpayers may prefer to clean their own home or take care of their own children rather than pay someone else to do so. See Staudt, supra note 21, at 1576.
    • Because imputed income is not taxed, taxpayers may prefer to clean their own home or take care of their own children rather than pay someone else to do so. See Staudt, supra note 21, at 1576.
  • 179
    • 46049116508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a woman who earns taxable income of $40,000 while her husband earns $70,000 in taxable income actually takes home approximately $30,000. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables). If she spends $1,000 a month on child care, her taxable income is reduced to $18,000. Other work-related expenses, such as clothes and meals, might further reduce this amount so that working outside the home is not an attractive economic option. See McCaffery, supra note 7, at 984, 1020-25.
    • For example, a woman who earns taxable income of $40,000 while her husband earns $70,000 in taxable income actually takes home approximately $30,000. See Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables). If she spends $1,000 a month on child care, her taxable income is reduced to $18,000. Other work-related expenses, such as clothes and meals, might further reduce this amount so that working outside the home is not an attractive economic option. See McCaffery, supra note 7, at 984, 1020-25.
  • 180
    • 46049089662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 196, 250-51. A number of factors could upset this economic balance. For example, the couple could divorce or the primary earner could become unable to work or unemployed. See also Meghan O'Rourke, A Working Girl Can Win, SLATE, June 26, 2006, http://www.slate.com/id/2144505;
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 196, 250-51. A number of factors could upset this economic balance. For example, the couple could divorce or the primary earner could become unable to work or unemployed. See also Meghan O'Rourke, A Working Girl Can Win, SLATE, June 26, 2006, http://www.slate.com/id/2144505;
  • 182
    • 46049106193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Joel S. Hollingsworth, Save the Cleavers: Taxation of the Traditional Family, 13 REGENT U. L. REV. 29 (2001-2002). Hollingsworth argues that the traditional family should face a lower tax burden and that mothers should not be encouraged to work. See id. This, however, ignores current demographics, as most families have two incomes and the joint return imposes tax burdens on these families. See sources cited supra note 11 (showing that dual-income families are a reality and are often necessary).
    • See Joel S. Hollingsworth, Save the Cleavers: Taxation of the Traditional Family, 13 REGENT U. L. REV. 29 (2001-2002). Hollingsworth argues that the traditional family should face a lower tax burden and that mothers should not be encouraged to work. See id. This, however, ignores current demographics, as most families have two incomes and the joint return imposes tax burdens on these families. See sources cited supra note 11 (showing that dual-income families are a reality and are often necessary).
  • 183
    • 46049112072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 196, 250-51
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 196, 250-51.
  • 184
    • 46049087570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Motro, supra note 3, at 1515
    • See Motro, supra note 3, at 1515.
  • 185
    • 46049095084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 186
    • 46049106195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 187
    • 46049108195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kornhauser, supra note 31, at 84
    • See Kornhauser, supra note 31, at 84.
  • 188
    • 46049104231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, to reduce the use of plastic grocery bags, Ireland imposed a $0.33 tax per bag. After the tax took effect, nearly everyone . . . bought reusable cloth bags, and plastic bag use dropped 94 percent. Elisabeth Rosenthal, With Irish Tax, Plastic Bags Go the Way of the Snakes, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 2, 2008, at 3A.
    • For example, to reduce the use of plastic grocery bags, Ireland imposed a $0.33 tax per bag. After the tax took effect, "nearly everyone . . . bought reusable cloth bags," and "plastic bag use dropped 94 percent." Elisabeth Rosenthal, With Irish Tax, Plastic Bags Go the Way of the Snakes, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 2, 2008, at 3A.
  • 189
    • 46049097405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President George W. Bush, Inaugural Address (Jan. 20, 2001), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/inaugural-address.html ([W]e will reduce taxes, to recover the momentum of our economy and reward the effort and enterprise of working Americans.).
    • President George W. Bush, Inaugural Address (Jan. 20, 2001), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/inaugural-address.html ("[W]e will reduce taxes, to recover the momentum of our economy and reward the effort and enterprise of working Americans.").
  • 190
    • 46049098821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 35
    • See supra note 35.
  • 191
    • 46049093238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A-C.
    • See infra Part II.A-C.
  • 192
    • 46049116510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A.
    • See infra Part II.A.
  • 193
    • 46049100442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C.
    • See infra Part II.C.
  • 194
    • 46049101491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B.
    • See infra Part II.B.
  • 195
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part III
    • See infra Part III.
    • See infra
  • 196
    • 46049084223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part IV
    • See infra Part IV.
    • See infra
  • 197
    • 46049102238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, § 101(a), 115 Stat. 38, 41 (amending section 1(i)(1) of the Internal Revenue Code). The 10 percent rate bracket went into retroactive effect for 2000, generating the 2001 tax-rebate checks promised by the Bush administration. See id.; Karen Masterson, Tax Cut Bill Given Final Approval, Congress Delivers Big Victory to Bush, HOUST. CHRON., May 27, 2001, at A1.
    • See Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, § 101(a), 115 Stat. 38, 41 (amending section 1(i)(1) of the Internal Revenue Code). The 10 percent rate bracket went into retroactive effect for 2000, generating the 2001 tax-rebate checks promised by the Bush administration. See id.; Karen Masterson, Tax Cut Bill Given Final Approval, Congress Delivers Big Victory to Bush, HOUST. CHRON., May 27, 2001, at A1.
  • 198
    • 46049083255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The highest tax rate fell from 39.6 percent to 35.0 percent. Before the 2001 Act, the tax rate brackets were 15.0 percent, 28.0 percent, 31.0 percent, 36.0 percent, and 39.6 percent. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2000, After the act, the rate brackets were 10 percent (new bracket, 15 percent, 25 percent, 28 percent, 33 percent, and 35 percent. See Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 101(a, amending section 1(i)(1) of the Internal Revenue Code, Thus, the 2001 Act reduced the rates for all brackets above the 15 percent bracket and added a new bracket that reduced the rate on income that used to fall into the 15 percent bracket. The 2001 Act created a gradual phase in of the reductions from 2001 to 2006. Id. However, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 accelerated the reductions to 2003. Pub. L. No. 108-27, 117 Stat. 752. Most provisions in these acts are set to sunset in 2011 specifically, December 31, 2010, See sou
    • The highest tax rate fell from 39.6 percent to 35.0 percent. Before the 2001 Act, the tax rate brackets were 15.0 percent, 28.0 percent, 31.0 percent, 36.0 percent, and 39.6 percent. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2000). After the act, the rate brackets were 10 percent (new bracket), 15 percent, 25 percent, 28 percent, 33 percent, and 35 percent. See Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 101(a) (amending section 1(i)(1) of the Internal Revenue Code). Thus, the 2001 Act reduced the rates for all brackets above the 15 percent bracket and added a new bracket that reduced the rate on income that used to fall into the 15 percent bracket. The 2001 Act created a gradual phase in of the reductions from 2001 to 2006. Id. However, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 accelerated the reductions to 2003. Pub. L. No. 108-27, 117 Stat. 752. Most provisions in these acts are set to sunset in 2011 (specifically, December 31, 2010). See sources cited supra note 35 (various sunset provisions within tax bills).
  • 199
    • 46049116107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax Cuts Offer Most for Very Rich, Study Finds
    • Jan. 8, at
    • Edmund L. Andrews, Tax Cuts Offer Most for Very Rich, Study Finds, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 8, 2007, at A16.
    • (2007) N.Y. TIMES
    • Andrews, E.L.1
  • 200
    • 46049092830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion on the stacking effect and how it results in taxing women at the margins, see supra Part I.C.1.
    • For a discussion on the stacking effect and how it results in taxing women at the margins, see supra Part I.C.1.
  • 201
    • 46049104443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eissa, supra note 124; see also supra Part I.C.1 (stating why the secondary earner is usually a woman).
    • Eissa, supra note 124; see also supra Part I.C.1 (stating why the secondary earner is usually a woman).
  • 202
    • 46049094021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. Law. No. 99-514, 100 Stat. 2085 (amending scattered sections of the tax code).
    • Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. Law. No. 99-514, 100 Stat. 2085 (amending scattered sections of the tax code).
  • 203
    • 46049093648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Eissa supra note 124, at 5
    • See Eissa supra note 124, at 5.
  • 204
    • 46049089661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is what Professor McCaffery suggests. MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 182-83; see also id. at 170-83 discussing the elasticities of labor participation for women
    • This is what Professor McCaffery suggests. MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 182-83; see also id. at 170-83 (discussing the elasticities of labor participation for women).
  • 205
    • 46049112732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Since the Bush-administration reforms were not as dramatic as the Reagan-administration reforms, the effects may be slighter. It is also hard to gauge the effect of marginal rates when most secondary earners probably consider many factors before leaving their job for work in the home
    • Since the Bush-administration reforms were not as dramatic as the Reagan-administration reforms, the effects may be slighter. It is also hard to gauge the effect of marginal rates when most secondary earners probably consider many factors before leaving their job for work in the home.
  • 206
    • 46049086426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, THE EFFECT OF TAX CHANGES ON LABOR SUPPLY IN CBO'S MICROSIMULATION TAX MODEL 6, 16 (2007), available at http://cbo.gov/ftpdocs/79xx/doc7996/04-12- laborsupply.pdf.
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, THE EFFECT OF TAX CHANGES ON LABOR SUPPLY IN CBO'S MICROSIMULATION TAX MODEL 6, 16 (2007), available at http://cbo.gov/ftpdocs/79xx/doc7996/04-12- laborsupply.pdf.
  • 207
    • 46049104232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see JOINT COMM. ON FIN., OVERVIEW OF PRESENT LAW AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS RELATING TO MARGINAL TAX RATES AND THE PRESIDENT'S INCOME TAX RATE PROPOSALS (2001), available at http://www.house.gov/jct/x-6-01. pdf (There is disagreement among economists on the extent to which labor supply decisions are affected by the effective marginal tax rate. . . . [T]here may be more effect on an individual currently not in the labor force than on an individual already in the labor force. (citing Professors Triest and Eissa)).
    • But see JOINT COMM. ON FIN., OVERVIEW OF PRESENT LAW AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS RELATING TO MARGINAL TAX RATES AND THE PRESIDENT'S INCOME TAX RATE PROPOSALS (2001), available at http://www.house.gov/jct/x-6-01. pdf ("There is disagreement among economists on the extent to which labor supply decisions are affected by the effective marginal tax rate. . . . [T]here may be more effect on an individual currently not in the labor force than on an individual already in the labor force." (citing Professors Triest and Eissa)).
  • 208
    • 46049110968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a good discussion of labor elasticity for women, see Cicconi, supra note 31, at 260-64 (noting that female labor supply rose sharply from 1950 to 1990, reaching a peak in 1999); see also James J. Heckman, What Has Been Learned about Labor Supply in the Past Twenty Years?, AM. ECON. REV., MAY 1993, at 116, 117 (stating that the female labor supply is more elastic);
    • For a good discussion of labor elasticity for women, see Cicconi, supra note 31, at 260-64 (noting that female labor supply rose sharply from 1950 to 1990, reaching a peak in 1999); see also James J. Heckman, What Has Been Learned about Labor Supply in the Past Twenty Years?, AM. ECON. REV., MAY 1993, at 116, 117 (stating that the female labor supply is more elastic);
  • 209
    • 46049104741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alberto Alesina et al., Gender Based Taxation and the Division of Family Chores (Harvard Inst. of Econ. Res., Discussion Paper No. 2145, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1033020 (same).
    • Alberto Alesina et al., Gender Based Taxation and the Division of Family Chores (Harvard Inst. of Econ. Res., Discussion Paper No. 2145, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1033020 (same).
  • 210
    • 46049118076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOINT ECON. COMM., 105TH CONG., REDUCING MARRIAGE TAXES: ISSUES AND PROPOSALS 5-6 (Comm. Print 1998) (discussing labor supply of secondary earners), available at http://www.house.gov/jec/fiscal/tx- grwth/marriage/marriage.pdf.
    • JOINT ECON. COMM., 105TH CONG., REDUCING MARRIAGE TAXES: ISSUES AND PROPOSALS 5-6 (Comm. Print 1998) (discussing labor supply of secondary earners), available at http://www.house.gov/jec/fiscal/tx- grwth/marriage/marriage.pdf.
  • 211
    • 46049097002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note, however, that Professor Eissa studied the highest income group and that the Reagan-administration reforms lowered the highest marginal rate more significantly than the Bush-administration tax cuts did. See Eissa, supra note 124; Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, 115 Stat. 38; Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. Law. No. 99-514, § 101, 100 Stat. 2085, 2096 (lowering rates); TruthAndPolitics.org, Top US Marginal Income Tax Rates, 1913-2003, http://www.truthandpolitics.org/ top-rates.php (last visited Feb. 27, 2008).
    • Note, however, that Professor Eissa studied the highest income group and that the Reagan-administration reforms lowered the highest marginal rate more significantly than the Bush-administration tax cuts did. See Eissa, supra note 124; Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, 115 Stat. 38; Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. Law. No. 99-514, § 101, 100 Stat. 2085, 2096 (lowering rates); TruthAndPolitics.org, Top US Marginal Income Tax Rates, 1913-2003, http://www.truthandpolitics.org/ top-rates.php (last visited Feb. 27, 2008).
  • 212
    • 46049104743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C.
    • See supra Part I.C.
  • 213
    • 46049108407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The 2001 Act called for a gradual phase in of the increase in the 15 percent bracket beginning in 2005. Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 302(a). However, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 accelerated this relief for 2003 and 2004. Pub. L. No. 108-27, 117 Stat. 752. The Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 extended this acceleration from 2005 to 2007, eliminating the marriage penalty in this bracket until the tax cuts expire in 2011. Pub. L. No. 108-311, § 101, 118 Stat. 1166, 1167-68.
    • The 2001 Act called for a gradual phase in of the increase in the 15 percent bracket beginning in 2005. Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 302(a). However, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 accelerated this relief for 2003 and 2004. Pub. L. No. 108-27, 117 Stat. 752. The Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 extended this acceleration from 2005 to 2007, eliminating the marriage penalty in this bracket until the tax cuts expire in 2011. Pub. L. No. 108-311, § 101, 118 Stat. 1166, 1167-68.
  • 214
    • 46049086995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 101(a).
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 101(a).
  • 215
    • 46049114327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The marriage penalty for these couples is still reduced, however, because more of their income falls into the lower 10 and 15 percent brackets before reaching the brackets with marriage penalties. See I.R.C § 1 (2001); Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
    • The marriage penalty for these couples is still reduced, however, because more of their income falls into the lower 10 and 15 percent brackets before reaching the brackets with marriage penalties. See I.R.C § 1 (2001); Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 971-72 (2008 Rate Tables).
  • 216
    • 46049112926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 51.
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 51.
  • 217
    • 46049086423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 218
    • 46049097605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 219
    • 46049111670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 63 (2000).
    • I.R.C. § 63 (2000).
  • 220
    • 46049109957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 301(b). The act substituted an applicable percentage rather than a deduction amount, so that the deduction gradually increases from 2005 to 2009 until the joint deduction is 200 percent of the single's deduction. Id.
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 301(b). The act substituted an "applicable percentage" rather than a deduction amount, so that the deduction gradually increases from 2005 to 2009 until the joint deduction is 200 percent of the single's deduction. Id.
  • 221
    • 46049119668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Treas. Reg. § 1.151-1 (2001).
    • See Treas. Reg. § 1.151-1 (2001).
  • 222
    • 46049090243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 51.
    • See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 51.
  • 223
    • 46049102242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 303(a)-(b) (amending section 32 of the Internal Revenue Code).
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 303(a)-(b) (amending section 32 of the Internal Revenue Code).
  • 224
    • 46049110155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.B.3.
    • See supra Part I.B.3.
  • 225
    • 46049115917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 32 (West 2001). Taxpayers with a modified adjusted gross income below the phaseout amount received the full credit, while taxpayers with incomes above the phaseout amount will have a reduced credit until the credit completely phases out. In 2006, the credit completely phases out at $36,348 for a married taxpayer with two children. See id. (as adjusted for inflation).
    • I.R.C. § 32 (West 2001). Taxpayers with a modified adjusted gross income below the phaseout amount received the full credit, while taxpayers with incomes above the phaseout amount will have a reduced credit until the credit completely phases out. In 2006, the credit completely phases out at $36,348 for a married taxpayer with two children. See id. (as adjusted for inflation).
  • 226
    • 46049108408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 303(a). The phaseout is increased yearly by $1,000 from 2002 to 2004, by $2,000 from 2005 to 2007, and $3,000 in the years after 2007. See id.
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 303(a). The phaseout is increased yearly by $1,000 from 2002 to 2004, by $2,000 from 2005 to 2007, and $3,000 in the years after 2007. See id.
  • 227
    • 46049094447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.3.
    • See supra Part II.B.3.
  • 228
    • 46049102240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 303(a)(2, amending section 32(j)(1)(B)(ii) of the Internal Revenue Code, Note that only the $3,000 increase is tied to inflation, while the interim $1,000 and $2,000 increases do not change with inflation. Id. Thus, taxpayers will not realize the full benefits of this provision until 2009
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 303(a)(2) (amending section 32(j)(1)(B)(ii) of the Internal Revenue Code). Note that only the $3,000 increase is tied to inflation, while the interim $1,000 and $2,000 increases do not change with inflation. Id. Thus, taxpayers will not realize the full benefits of this provision until 2009.
  • 229
    • 46049113550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 205. Since a family can claim the child tax credit whether or not both spouses work, the credit does not provide an incentive for the secondary earner to participate in the workforce
    • See
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 205. Since a family can claim the child tax credit whether or not both spouses work, the credit does not provide an incentive for the secondary earner to participate in the workforce. Id.
    • Id
    • MCCAFFERY1
  • 230
    • 46049119481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C.2.
    • See supra Part I.C.2.
  • 231
    • 46049103211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C.1-3.
    • See infra Part II.C.1-3.
  • 232
    • 46049102837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 24 (West 1998).
    • I.R.C. § 24 (West 1998).
  • 233
    • 46049107579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 201(a) (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code). The 2001 Act immediately increased the child tax credit from $500 to $600 and planned gradual increases to reach a credit of $1,000 by 2010. Id. However, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 accelerated the credit so that qualifying families could claim the $1,000 credit in 2003 and 2004. Pub. L. 108-27, § 101(a), 117 Stat. 752, 753 (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code). The Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 similarly allowed the $1,000 credit for 2005 and beyond. Pub. L. 108-311, § 101(a), 118 Stat. 1166, 1167 (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code).
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 201(a) (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code). The 2001 Act immediately increased the child tax credit from $500 to $600 and planned gradual increases to reach a credit of $1,000 by 2010. Id. However, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 accelerated the credit so that qualifying families could claim the $1,000 credit in 2003 and 2004. Pub. L. 108-27, § 101(a), 117 Stat. 752, 753 (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code). The Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 similarly allowed the $1,000 credit for 2005 and beyond. Pub. L. 108-311, § 101(a), 118 Stat. 1166, 1167 (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code).
  • 234
    • 46049095283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 201(b)-(c) (amending section 24(d) of the Internal Revenue Code). Prior to 2001, the credit was generally nonrefundable. See I.R.C. § 24 (West 2000). The 2001 Act allowed the credit to be refundable to all taxpayers. See Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 201(b)-(c) (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code).
    • Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 201(b)-(c) (amending section 24(d) of the Internal Revenue Code). Prior to 2001, the credit was generally nonrefundable. See I.R.C. § 24 (West 2000). The 2001 Act allowed the credit to be refundable to all taxpayers. See Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 201(b)-(c) (amending section 24 of the Internal Revenue Code).
  • 235
    • 46049106390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From 2001 to 2003, this amount was set at 10 percent of the taxpayer's earned income in excess of $10,000 (the child-tax-income figure). IRC § 24(d) (West 2001). In 2005 and beyond (until the provisions of the 2001 Act sunset), the amount allowed is 15 percent of the taxpayer's earned income in excess of the child-tax-income figure. I.R.C. § 24(d) (West 2004). However, under section 1 of the Internal Revenue Code, the child-tax-income figure is tied to inflation. For the 2007 inflation-adjusted amount, see Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 973. See also ANDREW LEE & ROBERT GREENSTEIN, HOW THE NEW TAX LAW ALTERS THE CHILD TAX CREDIT AND HOW LOW-INCOME FAMILIES ARE AFFECTED (2003) (discussing the impact of recent tax changes on the child tax credit), available at http://www.cbpp.org/5-28-03tax3.pdf.
    • From 2001 to 2003, this amount was set at 10 percent of the taxpayer's earned income in excess of $10,000 (the "child-tax-income figure"). IRC § 24(d) (West 2001). In 2005 and beyond (until the provisions of the 2001 Act sunset), the amount allowed is 15 percent of the taxpayer's earned income in excess of the child-tax-income figure. I.R.C. § 24(d) (West 2004). However, under section 1 of the Internal Revenue Code, the child-tax-income figure is tied to inflation. For the 2007 inflation-adjusted amount, see Rev. Proc. 2007-66, 2007-45 I.R.B. 970, 973. See also ANDREW LEE & ROBERT GREENSTEIN, HOW THE NEW TAX LAW ALTERS THE CHILD TAX CREDIT AND HOW LOW-INCOME FAMILIES ARE AFFECTED (2003) (discussing the impact of recent tax changes on the child tax credit), available at http://www.cbpp.org/5-28-03tax3.pdf.
  • 236
    • 46049115124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.R. REP. NO. 107-84, at 8-10 (2001). The committee noted that many taxpayers do not currently get the benefit of the credit. Id. at 131-33.
    • H.R. REP. NO. 107-84, at 8-10 (2001). The committee noted that many taxpayers do not currently get the benefit of the credit. Id. at 131-33.
  • 237
    • 46049107399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 205
    • See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 205.
  • 238
    • 46049101493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 24 (West 2001) (child-care arrangements do not affect the credit).
    • I.R.C. § 24 (West 2001) (child-care arrangements do not affect the credit).
  • 239
    • 46049087182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The help to families may also be short-lived, however, as the Bush-administration tax cuts sunset in 2011. Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 901(a). Additionally, even if the $1,000 credit is extended, the credit is not adjusted for inflation and thus will lose its value over time. See I.R.C. § 24 (West 2000). More secondary earners are affected by the phaseout of the credit than they are by the refundability of the credit. CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 192, at 13.
    • The help to families may also be short-lived, however, as the Bush-administration tax cuts sunset in 2011. Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act § 901(a). Additionally, even if the $1,000 credit is extended, the credit is not adjusted for inflation and thus will lose its value over time. See I.R.C. § 24 (West 2000). More secondary earners are affected by the phaseout of the credit than they are by the refundability of the credit. CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 192, at 13.
  • 240
    • 46049089266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C.2.
    • See supra Part I.C.2.
  • 241
    • 46049114920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.C; cf. Hollingsworth, supra note 166, at 53, 62 (arguing that the child-care credit injures the traditional family and that it should only be offered to dual-earning families that have financial need).
    • See supra Part II.C; cf. Hollingsworth, supra note 166, at 53, 62 (arguing that the child-care credit "injures the traditional family" and that it should only be offered to dual-earning families that have financial need).
  • 242
    • 46049101275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See I.R.C. § 21 West 2000, Before 2001, section 21 of the code allowed a maximum credit of 30 percent of child-care expenses, not to exceed $2,400 for one child or $4,800 for two or more children. Id. The 30 percent credit began to phase out when adjusted gross income exceeded $10,000, but the credit could not be decreased below 20 percent no matter how high the taxpayer's income went. Id. Thus, a taxpayer with one qualifying child and the maximum amount of child-care expenses would get a credit between $480 and $720, depending on the taxpayer's income. For a taxpayer with two children and maximum expenses, the credit would be between $960 and $1,440, depending on the taxpayer's income. See id. Note that a deduction under section 21 may apply to other qualifying individuals besides children, such as handicapped dependants and spouses unable to take care of themselves. Id
    • See I.R.C. § 21 (West 2000). Before 2001, section 21 of the code allowed a maximum credit of 30 percent of child-care expenses, not to exceed $2,400 for one child or $4,800 for two or more children. Id. The 30 percent credit began to phase out when adjusted gross income exceeded $10,000, but the credit could not be decreased below 20 percent no matter how high the taxpayer's income went. Id. Thus, a taxpayer with one qualifying child and the maximum amount of child-care expenses would get a credit between $480 and $720, depending on the taxpayer's income. For a taxpayer with two children and maximum expenses, the credit would be between $960 and $1,440, depending on the taxpayer's income. See id. Note that a deduction under section 21 may apply to other qualifying individuals besides children, such as handicapped dependants and spouses unable to take care of themselves. Id.
  • 243
    • 46049096164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 244
    • 46049108581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 245
    • 46049099639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The phaseout began at $15,000 instead of $10,000. Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, § 204(b), 115 Stat. 38, 49 (amending section 21 of the Internal Revenue Code).
    • The phaseout began at $15,000 instead of $10,000. Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-16, § 204(b), 115 Stat. 38, 49 (amending section 21 of the Internal Revenue Code).
  • 246
    • 46049112276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 204.
    • See id. § 204.
  • 247
    • 46049118458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 204(a). The allowed expenses increased from $2,400 to $3,000 for one child and from $4,800 to $6,000 for two or more children
    • Id. § 204(a). The allowed expenses increased from $2,400 to $3,000 for one child and from $4,800 to $6,000 for two or more children. Id.
    • Id
  • 248
    • 46049084441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.A.
    • See supra Part II.A.
  • 249
    • 46049102430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.
    • See supra Part II.B.
  • 250
    • 46049086228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.C.
    • See supra Part II.C.
  • 251
    • 46049103832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.
    • See supra Part II.B.
  • 252
    • 46049089849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is true unless the couple's entire income falls within the 10 and 15 percent brackets, which minimize marriage penalties. See supra notes 195-96 and accompanying text. For a discussion regarding how the joint return affects the secondary earner and an explanation of the stacking effect, see supra Part I.C
    • This is true unless the couple's entire income falls within the 10 and 15 percent brackets, which minimize marriage penalties. See supra notes 195-96 and accompanying text. For a discussion regarding how the joint return affects the secondary earner and an explanation of the stacking effect, see supra Part I.C.
  • 253
    • 46049100638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edmund L. Andrews, Tax Cuts, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 5, 2006, at 3; Douglas Holtz-Eakin, Editorial, Out on a Limb; Look Out! Here Comes Yet Another Unrealistic Budget, WASH. POST, Feb. 5, 2006, at B1.
    • See Edmund L. Andrews, Tax Cuts, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 5, 2006, at 3; Douglas Holtz-Eakin, Editorial, Out on a Limb; Look Out! Here Comes Yet Another Unrealistic Budget, WASH. POST, Feb. 5, 2006, at B1.
  • 254
    • 46049089850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1024
    • See Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1024.
  • 255
    • 46049089468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. CONST. amend. XVI; TruthAndPolitics.org, supra note 193.
    • U.S. CONST. amend. XVI; TruthAndPolitics.org, supra note 193.
  • 256
    • 46049113728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts I.C, II.A.
    • See supra Parts I.C, II.A.
  • 257
    • 46049103210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What's Next
    • See, Mar. 1, at
    • See Janice Revell, What's Next, MONEY, Mar. 1, 2008, at 84, 88.
    • (2008) MONEY
    • Revell, J.1
  • 258
    • 46049093430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The marginal rates used to be much higher. TruthAndPolitics.org, supra note 193
    • The marginal rates used to be much higher. TruthAndPolitics.org, supra note 193.
  • 259
    • 46049098014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, BUDGET OF THE UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT, FISCAL YEAR 2009, THE NATION'S FISCAL OUTLOOK 18-20 (2008), available at http://www.gpoaccess.gov/usbudget/fy09/pdf/budget/outlook.pdf; Martin Crutsinger, CBO Projects $1.76 Trillion in Deficits over Decade, CHI. TRIB., Aug. 18, 2006, at C5.
    • See OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, BUDGET OF THE UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT, FISCAL YEAR 2009, THE NATION'S FISCAL OUTLOOK 18-20 (2008), available at http://www.gpoaccess.gov/usbudget/fy09/pdf/budget/outlook.pdf; Martin Crutsinger, CBO Projects $1.76 Trillion in Deficits over Decade, CHI. TRIB., Aug. 18, 2006, at C5.
  • 260
    • 46049091404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DEP'T OF TREAS., 2007 FINANCIAL REPORT OF THE UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT, 118, 123-28 (2007), available at http://fms.treas.gov/fr/07frusg/07frusg.pdf (showing that the costs of Social Security and Medicare are skyrocketing); OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, supra note 241.
    • See DEP'T OF TREAS., 2007 FINANCIAL REPORT OF THE UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT, 118, 123-28 (2007), available at http://fms.treas.gov/fr/07frusg/07frusg.pdf (showing that the costs of Social Security and Medicare are skyrocketing); OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, supra note 241.
  • 261
    • 46049102836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The deficits must be financed eventually and could be offset by any measure that raises revenue or reduces spending. See William G. Gale & Peter B. Orszag, An Economic Assessment of Tax Policy in the Bush Administration, 2001-2004, 45 B.C. L. REV. 1157, 1193 (2004) ([A]ny permanent tax cut must be financed by some combination of future spending cuts or future tax increases.).
    • The deficits must be financed eventually and could be offset by any measure that raises revenue or reduces spending. See William G. Gale & Peter B. Orszag, An Economic Assessment of Tax Policy in the Bush Administration, 2001-2004, 45 B.C. L. REV. 1157, 1193 (2004) ("[A]ny permanent tax cut must be financed by some combination of future spending cuts or future tax increases.").
  • 262
    • 46049117537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allen Schick, A Surplus, If We Can Keep It, BROOKINGS REV., Winter 2000, at 36, 39 (noting that the marginal rate increase pumped up federal revenues);
    • Allen Schick, "A Surplus, If We Can Keep It," BROOKINGS REV., Winter 2000, at 36, 39 (noting that the marginal rate increase "pumped up" federal revenues);
  • 263
    • 46049114328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cragg Hines, Clinton Will Target Trims in Deficit, Jobs Creation, HOUST. CHRON., Feb. 14, 1993, at A1 (outlining the Clinton-administration plan to decrease the deficit with an inevitable tax increase).
    • Cragg Hines, Clinton Will Target Trims in Deficit, Jobs Creation, HOUST. CHRON., Feb. 14, 1993, at A1 (outlining the Clinton-administration plan to decrease the deficit with an inevitable tax increase).
  • 264
    • 46049120476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CBPP Says Budget Outiook Grimmer Than CBO Projections Suggest, 2004 TAX NOTES, Jan. 29, 2004. The deficit projections worsen if the Bush-administration tax cuts are extended past 2011. Id. Critics have complained that the sunset provisions hide the true costs of the tax cuts since allowing the tax cuts to sunset in 2011 will be politically risky. Id.
    • See CBPP Says Budget Outiook "Grimmer" Than CBO Projections Suggest, 2004 TAX NOTES, Jan. 29, 2004. The deficit projections worsen if the Bush-administration tax cuts are extended past 2011. Id. Critics have complained that the sunset provisions hide the true costs of the tax cuts since allowing the tax cuts to sunset in 2011 will be politically risky. Id.
  • 265
    • 46049113128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Raising the marginal rates was one strategy that the Clinton administration used to cut the deficit. See Hines, supra note 244, at A1
    • Raising the marginal rates was one strategy that the Clinton administration used to cut the deficit. See Hines, supra note 244, at A1.
  • 266
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 185-89 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 185-89 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 267
    • 46049090046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.3
    • See supra Part II.B.3
  • 268
    • 46049107874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.3.
    • See supra Part II.B.3.
  • 269
    • 46049115513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The tax benefits of imputed income can surprisingly make it cheaper for low-income taxpayers to live on one income instead of two. See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 145-50.
    • The tax benefits of imputed income can surprisingly make it cheaper for low-income taxpayers to live on one income instead of two. See MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 145-50.
  • 270
    • 46049109761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President Bush's Budget Plan; A Bid for Permanent Tax Cuts
    • See, Feb. 8, at
    • See Peter G. Gosselin, President Bush's Budget Plan; A Bid for Permanent Tax Cuts, L.A. TIMES, Feb. 8, 2005, at A18.
    • (2005) L.A. TIMES
    • Gosselin, P.G.1
  • 271
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 241-42 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 241-42 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 272
    • 34547827575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 35 listing numerous tax acts passed during the Bush administration
    • See supra note 35 (listing numerous tax acts passed during the Bush administration).
    • See supra
  • 273
    • 46049095087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edward J. McCaffery, The Missing Links in Tax Reform, 2 CHAP. L. REV. 233, 233-36 (1999).
    • See Edward J. McCaffery, The Missing Links in Tax Reform, 2 CHAP. L. REV. 233, 233-36 (1999).
  • 274
    • 46049100054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fundamental reforms require broad political support, making them politically difficult to achieve. See, e.g., Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1046-47 (analyzing McCaffery's proposals against political realities); Zelenak, Critical Tax Theory, supra note 31 (criticizing some proposed reforms as being unrealistic).
    • Fundamental reforms require broad political support, making them politically difficult to achieve. See, e.g., Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1046-47 (analyzing McCaffery's proposals against political realities); Zelenak, Critical Tax Theory, supra note 31 (criticizing some proposed reforms as being unrealistic).
  • 275
    • 46049108972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Critics charge that the 2011 sunset provision hides the true cost of the recent tax reforms. See supra note 245.
    • Critics charge that the 2011 sunset provision hides the true cost of the recent tax reforms. See supra note 245.
  • 276
    • 34547814457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 221 noting that the child-care credit is not tied to inflation
    • See, e.g., supra note 221 (noting that the child-care credit is not tied to inflation).
    • See, e.g., supra
  • 277
    • 46049109958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JOINT ECON. COMM., supra note 192 (discussing various reforms).
    • See JOINT ECON. COMM., supra note 192 (discussing various reforms).
  • 278
    • 46049086607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C.2. The number of children living with unmarried couples is increasing. See U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, supra note 19, at 16-18.
    • See infra Part I.C.2. The number of children living with unmarried couples is increasing. See U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, supra note 19, at 16-18.
  • 279
    • 46049111878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Same-sex couples may not file a joint return
    • Same-sex couples may not file a joint return.
  • 280
    • 46049103831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Dorothy A. Brown, Race, Class, and Gender Essentialism in Tax Literature: The Joint Return, 54 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1469, 1501-04 (1997) (finding that blacks are disproportionately affected by the stacking effect);
    • See, e.g., Dorothy A. Brown, Race, Class, and Gender Essentialism in Tax Literature: The Joint Return, 54 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1469, 1501-04 (1997) (finding that blacks are disproportionately affected by the stacking effect);
  • 281
    • 0345877419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beverly I. Moran & William Whitford, A Black Critique of the Internal Revenue Code, 1996 WIS. L. REV. 751, 791-800 (finding that black couples are less likely to get a marital bonus through joint filing).
    • Beverly I. Moran & William Whitford, A Black Critique of the Internal Revenue Code, 1996 WIS. L. REV. 751, 791-800 (finding that black couples are less likely to get a marital bonus through joint filing).
  • 282
    • 46049114921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Several commentators have proposed an elimination of the joint return. See sources cited supra note 31
    • Several commentators have proposed an elimination of the joint return. See sources cited supra note 31.
  • 283
    • 46049085063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to the concerns discussed in Section IV.A, Congress would also have to consider the lost revenues from eliminating the marriage penalty as well as how to divide deductions and credits that might be claimed by both spouses on two separate returns. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 54-55.
    • In addition to the concerns discussed in Section IV.A, Congress would also have to consider the lost revenues from eliminating the marriage penalty as well as how to divide deductions and credits that might be claimed by both spouses on two separate returns. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 54-55.
  • 284
    • 46049110369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Zelenak criticizes the joint return for taking sides in the marriage debate by rewarding traditional one-earner families and punishing families where both spouses work. Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1033-34. However, the opposite result is reached when the joint return is eliminated. Professor Alstott points out that a switch to individual filing burdens caregivers that work in the home. Alstott, supra note 31, at 2014-16; see also CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 54 (noting that instituting separate filing could be considered antifamily because it could influence parents to leave their children in daycare, But see Zelenak, supra note 72, at 3 n. 11 I previously wrote in support of mandatory separate filing, and I believe it is a serious political possibility in the longer run
    • Professor Zelenak criticizes the joint return for taking sides in the marriage debate by rewarding traditional one-earner families and punishing families where both spouses work. Zelenak, supra note 34, at 1033-34. However, the opposite result is reached when the joint return is eliminated. Professor Alstott points out that a switch to individual filing burdens caregivers that work in the home. Alstott, supra note 31, at 2014-16; see also CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 54 (noting that instituting separate filing "could be considered antifamily" because it could influence parents to leave their children in daycare). But see Zelenak, supra note 72, at 3 n. 11 ("I previously wrote in support of mandatory separate filing, and I believe it is a serious political possibility in the longer run.").
  • 285
    • 46049100438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because all of their income would be on one tax return, traditional families would only use the tax brackets once. Dual-earning couples would file two tax returns and thus would receive more benefits from the progressive rate brackets. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007) (ignoring marital brackets because only single filers are allowed for purposes of this example). For example, a couple with two earners and $100,000 of total taxable income evenly divided between them would pay less tax than a family with only one earner making the same amount. See id. (again ignoring marital brackets). The dual earners each file a return with $50,000, and the family with a single earner files one return with $100,000 and pays more tax.
    • Because all of their income would be on one tax return, traditional families would only use the tax brackets once. Dual-earning couples would file two tax returns and thus would receive more benefits from the progressive rate brackets. See I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007) (ignoring marital brackets because only single filers are allowed for purposes of this example). For example, a couple with two earners and $100,000 of total taxable income evenly divided between them would pay less tax than a family with only one earner making the same amount. See id. (again ignoring marital brackets). The dual earners each file a return with $50,000, and the family with a single earner files one return with $100,000 and pays more tax.
  • 286
    • 46049109375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zelenak, supra note 72, at 18
    • Zelenak, supra note 72, at 18.
  • 287
    • 46049088936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perhaps for this reason, some have suggested a compromise that would allow taxpayers to choose the most beneficial filing status. Id. at 12. However, this would just be another piecemeal change to the tax code that would not completely correct the underlying bias. See id.
    • Perhaps for this reason, some have suggested a compromise that would allow taxpayers to choose the most beneficial filing status. Id. at 12. However, this would just be another piecemeal change to the tax code that would not completely correct the underlying bias. See id.
  • 288
    • 46049109959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 6-7. To keep complete neutrality in this respect, the tax code would always have to consider marital status
    • Id. at 6-7. To keep complete neutrality in this respect, the tax code would always have to consider marital status. Id.
    • Id
  • 289
    • 46049109564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 4
    • Id. at 4.
  • 290
    • 46049085848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a couple that takes home $100,000 via two incomes of $50,000 will pay different taxes than a couple in which one spouse earns $75,000 and the other earns $25,000
    • For example, a couple that takes home $100,000 via two incomes of $50,000 will pay different taxes than a couple in which one spouse earns $75,000 and the other earns $25,000.
  • 291
    • 46049120294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While beyond the scope of this Comment, Congress also retains enormous flexibility to enact credits, deductions, and penalties that would affect the tax bill. For example, Congress could enact a stay-at-home-spouse credit or deduction, which would reduce taxes for traditional families with one income. See, e.g, JOINT ECON. COMM, supra note 192 discussing reforms
    • While beyond the scope of this Comment, Congress also retains enormous flexibility to enact credits, deductions, and penalties that would affect the tax bill. For example, Congress could enact a "stay-at-home-spouse" credit or deduction, which would reduce taxes for traditional families with one income. See, e.g., JOINT ECON. COMM., supra note 192 (discussing reforms).
  • 292
    • 46049099642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 58. The joint return was instituted in 1948 initially to equalize tax filing between states with different community-property laws. See supra note 7 and accompanying text. Later on, the joint return was justified by income pooling. See Zelenak, supra note 72, at 3 (noting that the elimination of the joint return was politically unpopular).
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 58. The joint return was instituted in 1948 initially to equalize tax filing between states with different community-property laws. See supra note 7 and accompanying text. Later on, the joint return was justified by income pooling. See Zelenak, supra note 72, at 3 (noting that the elimination of the joint return was politically unpopular).
  • 293
    • 46049097810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 58
    • MCCAFFERY, supra note 2, at 58.
  • 294
    • 46049099837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 28.
    • CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, supra note 37, at 28.
  • 295
    • 46049095282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, this analogy assumes that the justification for couples neutrality should also apply to other unmarried couples who presumably also share income. See Motro, supra note 3
    • Of course, this analogy assumes that the justification for couples neutrality should also apply to other unmarried couples who presumably also share income. See Motro, supra note 3.
  • 296
    • 46049101492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1543.
    • See id. at 1543.
  • 297
    • 46049114740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1543-44; cf. Kornhauser, supra note 31, at 104 (noting that many married taxpayers do not, in fact, pool income).
    • Id. at 1543-44; cf. Kornhauser, supra note 31, at 104 (noting that many married taxpayers do not, in fact, pool income).
  • 298
    • 46049108196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Motro, supra note 3, at 1543-44. Professor Motro notes that her proposal is aligned with the views of many Americans on marriage, including President Bush, who supports civil unions. Id. at 1515 n.11. Motro cites an interview of Bush in which he confirms his support for civil unions, stating, I view the definition of marriage different from legal arrangements that enable people to have rights. Id. Professor McCaffery notes, The tax law refuses to consider that some couples who are not married may pool their incomes, possibly even more fairly than many married couples do. McCaffery, supra note 2, at 63. This results in unfair tax treatment and the innocent-spouse problem. Id, A wife cannot sue her husband to get one-half of the family's economic pool on the grounds that the tax laws say she owns it
    • Motro, supra note 3, at 1543-44. Professor Motro notes that her proposal is aligned with the views of many Americans on marriage, including President Bush, who supports civil unions. Id. at 1515 n.11. Motro cites an interview of Bush in which he confirms his support for civil unions, stating, "I view the definition of marriage different from legal arrangements that enable people to have rights." Id. Professor McCaffery notes, "The tax law refuses to consider that some couples who are not married may pool their incomes, possibly even more fairly than many married couples do." McCaffery, supra note 2, at 63. This results in unfair tax treatment and the innocent-spouse problem. Id. ("A wife cannot sue her husband to get one-half of the family's economic pool on the grounds that the tax laws say she owns it.").
  • 299
    • 0345847773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DONALDSON, supra note 102, at 10-13. The tax code taxes higher incomes at higher rates, which makes it progressive. Id. This concept is often referred to as vertical equity because it puts more taxes on those with a greater ability to pay them. See Nancy C. Staudt, The Hidden Costs of the Progressivity Debate, 50 VAND. L. REV. 919, 933-36 (1997).
    • See DONALDSON, supra note 102, at 10-13. The tax code taxes higher incomes at higher rates, which makes it progressive. Id. This concept is often referred to as vertical equity because it puts more taxes on those with a greater ability to pay them. See Nancy C. Staudt, The Hidden Costs of the Progressivity Debate, 50 VAND. L. REV. 919, 933-36 (1997).
  • 300
    • 46049088179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This concept is known as horizontal equity. See Staudt, supra note 279, at 925-32
    • This concept is known as horizontal equity. See Staudt, supra note 279, at 925-32.
  • 301
    • 46049102835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Motro, supra note 3, at 1543. This in itself is an improvement over the joint-return system, which sometimes causes tax liability for taxpayers that never had a legal right to the income. Id. at 1532-33.
    • Motro, supra note 3, at 1543. This in itself is an improvement over the joint-return system, which sometimes causes tax liability for taxpayers that never had a legal right to the income. Id. at 1532-33.
  • 302
    • 46049108409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, while Congress could choose to make joint filing separate or mandatory for these different groups, in reality most taxpayers would have a choice. To share or not share legal entitlement to income, taxpayers could enter into many different types of contractual arrangements. See, e.g, Lucas v. Earl, 281 U.S. 111 1930, holding that a California couple attempted to assign their income by contract
    • Of course, while Congress could choose to make joint filing separate or mandatory for these different groups, in reality most taxpayers would have a choice. To share or not share legal entitlement to income, taxpayers could enter into many different types of contractual arrangements. See, e.g., Lucas v. Earl, 281 U.S. 111 (1930) (holding that a California couple attempted to assign their income by contract).
  • 303
    • 46049088557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part IV.B.
    • See supra Part IV.B.
  • 304
    • 46049105363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recall that the current categories are Married individuals filing joint returns and surviving spouses, Heads of households, Unmarried individuals, and Married individuals filing separate returns. I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007). Married taxpayers are limited to the married category, while singles may choose to file as heads of households if they meet the requirements. Id. §§ 1, 2(b).
    • Recall that the current categories are "Married individuals filing joint returns and surviving spouses," "Heads of households," "Unmarried individuals," and "Married individuals filing separate returns." I.R.C. § 1 (West 2007). Married taxpayers are limited to the married category, while singles may choose to file as heads of households if they meet the requirements. Id. §§ 1, 2(b).
  • 305
    • 46049091608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recall that a married person now only has two filing options: a joint-married return or a separate-married return. Married persons are thus excluded from the tax brackets for single persons. See id. § 1. This proposal would add a third option.
    • Recall that a married person now only has two filing options: a joint-married return or a separate-married return. Married persons are thus excluded from the tax brackets for single persons. See id. § 1. This proposal would add a third option.
  • 306
    • 46049109374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Bruce Bartlett, The Marriage Penalty: Origins, Effects, and Solutions, 80 TAX NOTES 1341, 1347 (1998). Bartlett proposes that Congress provide taxpayers with a choice between filing under the marital brackets or the single brackets. Id. This, of course, could significantly impact revenues. See id. at 1347-48.
    • Cf. Bruce Bartlett, The Marriage Penalty: Origins, Effects, and Solutions, 80 TAX NOTES 1341, 1347 (1998). Bartlett proposes that Congress provide taxpayers with a choice between filing under the marital brackets or the single brackets. Id. This, of course, could significantly impact revenues. See id. at 1347-48.
  • 307
    • 46049083437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. also Boris I. Bittker, Federal Income Taxation and the Family, 27 STAN. L. REV. 1389, 1431-44 (1975) (opposing reforms that encourage bedchamber transactions).
    • Cf. also Boris I. Bittker, Federal Income Taxation and the Family, 27 STAN. L. REV. 1389, 1431-44 (1975) (opposing reforms that encourage "bedchamber" transactions).
  • 308
    • 46049107984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, Congress could collect the same amount of revenue by decreasing the tax brackets for married couples, so that traditional families receive a smaller bonus, or decreasing the tax brackets for single taxpayers. While this might appear as raising taxes on one group, it is really just an example of how Congress must continually balance competing interests when it comes to tax policy. For example, when the 2001 Act added the new 10 percent bracket, Congress balanced competing interests when setting the income levels for this bracket. See supra Part II.B.
    • For example, Congress could collect the same amount of revenue by decreasing the tax brackets for married couples, so that traditional families receive a smaller bonus, or decreasing the tax brackets for single taxpayers. While this might appear as "raising taxes" on one group, it is really just an example of how Congress must continually balance competing interests when it comes to tax policy. For example, when the 2001 Act added the new 10 percent bracket, Congress balanced competing interests when setting the income levels for this bracket. See supra Part II.B.
  • 309
    • 34547814457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 261 and accompanying text
    • See, e.g., supra note 261 and accompanying text.
    • See, e.g., supra
  • 310
    • 46049089268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bartlett, supra note 286, at 1347 (Indeed, growth of the marriage penalty is as much due to demographic changes as changes in the tax law.).
    • See Bartlett, supra note 286, at 1347 ("Indeed, growth of the marriage penalty is as much due to demographic changes as changes in the tax law.").


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.