메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 107, Issue 6, 2007, Pages 1482-1532

Common law constitutionalism and the limits of reason

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 36549090086     PISSN: 00101958     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (39)

References (189)
  • 2
    • 36549026891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At least not in anything like its current form. See generally Philip A. Hamburger, Revolution and Judicial Review: Chief Justice Holt's Opinion in City of London v. Wood, 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2091, 2137-46 1994, describing 1702 opinion that concluded that acts of Parliament were not subject to judicial review but acts of corporate bodies that did not exercise power of sovereignty can be
    • At least not in anything like its current form. See generally Philip A. Hamburger, Revolution and Judicial Review: Chief Justice Holt's Opinion in City of London v. Wood, 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2091, 2137-46 (1994) (describing 1702 opinion that concluded that acts of Parliament were not subject to judicial review but acts of corporate bodies that did not exercise power of sovereignty can be).
  • 3
    • 84928854618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, Ian Shapiro ed, For responses
    • See Gerry Mackie, Democracy Defended 72-157 (Ian Shapiro ed., 2003). For responses
    • (2003) Democracy Defended , pp. 72-157
    • Mackie, G.1
  • 4
    • 36549080068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Don Herzog, Dragonslaying, 72 U. Chi. L. Rev. 757, 769-74 (2005);
    • see Don Herzog, Dragonslaying, 72 U. Chi. L. Rev. 757, 769-74 (2005);
  • 5
    • 36549008165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Saul Levmore, Public Choice Defended, 72 U. Chi. L. Rev. 777, 782 (2005).
    • Saul Levmore, Public Choice Defended, 72 U. Chi. L. Rev. 777, 782 (2005).
  • 6
    • 0346249767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, on the basis of the value of stability and protecting settled expectations. For an overview of the arguments, see Thomas W. Merrill, Does Public Choice Theory Justify Judicial Activism After All?, 21 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 219, 225-26 (1997) [hereinafter Merrill, Public Choice].
    • For example, on the basis of the value of stability and protecting settled expectations. For an overview of the arguments, see Thomas W. Merrill, Does Public Choice Theory Justify Judicial Activism After All?, 21 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 219, 225-26 (1997) [hereinafter Merrill, Public Choice].
  • 7
    • 0346044956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Thomas W. Merrill, Bork v. Burke, 19 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 509, 511-13 (1996) [hereinafter Merrill, Bork v. Burke] (defending conventionalism and claiming diat it has Burkean roots);
    • See Thomas W. Merrill, Bork v. Burke, 19 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 509, 511-13 (1996) [hereinafter Merrill, Bork v. Burke] (defending "conventionalism" and claiming diat it has Burkean roots);
  • 8
    • 0347419824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David A. Strauss, Common Law Constitutional Interpretation, 63 U. Chi. L. Rev. 877, 893 (1996) [hereinafter Strauss, Common Law Interpretation] ([I]deas . . . commonly associated widi Burke . . . are . . . the underpinnings of the common law approach to precedent);
    • David A. Strauss, Common Law Constitutional Interpretation, 63 U. Chi. L. Rev. 877, 893 (1996) [hereinafter Strauss, Common Law Interpretation] ("[I]deas . . . commonly associated widi Burke . . . are . . . the underpinnings of the common law approach to precedent");
  • 9
    • 34249730115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, 105 Mich. L. Rev. 353 (2006) [hereinafter Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism] (describing Burkean approach to constitutional interpretation);
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, 105 Mich. L. Rev. 353 (2006) [hereinafter Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism] (describing Burkean approach to constitutional interpretation);
  • 10
    • 36549040037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ernest Young, Rediscovering Conservatism: Burkean Political Theory and Constitutional Interpretation, 72 N.C. L. Rev. 619 (1994, same, Common law constitutionalism is also compatible with Friedrich Hayek's claim that the common law, analogously to markets, embodies dispersed or decentralized information that is superior in the aggregate to the information of any of its participants. 1 Friedrich A. Hayek, Law, Legislation and Liberty: Rules and Order 15-16 1973, That claim fits naturally with a Condorcetian interpretation: As I will explain shortly, the Jury Theorem relies on dispersed information for its aggregative effects, and describes conditions under which the information held by the voting or statistical group will be superior to that held by any of the group's members. However, although there is little difference between the Burkean and Hayekian strains as regards any of the claims relevant here, in constitutional theory the self-conception of the central theorists is Burkea
    • Ernest Young, Rediscovering Conservatism: Burkean Political Theory and Constitutional Interpretation, 72 N.C. L. Rev. 619 (1994) (same). Common law constitutionalism is also compatible with Friedrich Hayek's claim that the common law, analogously to markets, embodies dispersed or decentralized information that is superior in the aggregate to the information of any of its participants. 1 Friedrich A. Hayek, Law, Legislation and Liberty: Rules and Order 15-16 (1973). That claim fits naturally with a Condorcetian interpretation: As I will explain shortly, the Jury Theorem relies on dispersed information for its aggregative effects, and describes conditions under which the information held by the voting or statistical group will be superior to that held by any of the group's members. However, although there is little difference between the Burkean and Hayekian strains as regards any of the claims relevant here, in constitutional theory the self-conception of the central theorists is Burkean, not Hayekian. Accordingly, I focus on Burke's dictum rather than its Hayekian relatives.
  • 11
    • 36549070166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anthony Kronman, The Lost Lawyer: Failing Ideals of the Legal Profession 217 (1993) (The constrained creativity of the experienced lawyer . . . comes only with time and experience, and hence with age, and thus constitutes a species of wisdom that the young and inexperienced cannot possess.).
    • Anthony Kronman, The Lost Lawyer: Failing Ideals of the Legal Profession 217 (1993) ("The constrained creativity of the experienced lawyer . . . comes only with time and experience, and hence with age, and thus constitutes a species of wisdom that the young and inexperienced cannot possess.").
  • 12
    • 36549068232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Merrill, Bork v. Burke, supra note 5, at 515 proposing that choice between originalism and Burkean conventionalism should be evaluated by asking which approach is most likely to further a series of values that conservatives commonly embrace
    • See, e.g., Merrill, Bork v. Burke, supra note 5, at 515 (proposing that choice between originalism and Burkean "conventionalism" should be evaluated by asking which approach is most likely to further a series of "values that conservatives commonly embrace").
  • 13
    • 36549068238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 24-29 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 24-29 and accompanying text.
  • 14
    • 36549074603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 892-94 discussing the common-sense notion that one reason for following precedent is that it is simply too time consuming and difficult to reexamine everything from the ground up
    • See, e.g., Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 892-94 (discussing "the common-sense notion that one reason for following precedent is that it is simply too time consuming and difficult to reexamine everything from the ground up").
  • 15
    • 36549086529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 912
    • See id. at 912.
  • 16
    • 36549022086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 895
    • Id. at 895.
  • 17
    • 36549037194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Cass R. Sunstein, Commentary, Incompletely Theorized Agreements, 108 Harv. L. Rev. 1733, 1740-41 (1995) (arguing that participants in legal controversy may agree on results and low-level explanations, but need not agree on fundamental principles).
    • Cf. Cass R. Sunstein, Commentary, Incompletely Theorized Agreements, 108 Harv. L. Rev. 1733, 1740-41 (1995) (arguing that participants in legal controversy may agree on results and low-level explanations, but need not agree on fundamental principles).
  • 18
    • 36549070641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The phrase many minds is taken from Cass R. Sunstein, Infotopia: How Many Minds Produce Knowledge (2006).
    • The phrase "many minds" is taken from Cass R. Sunstein, Infotopia: How Many Minds Produce Knowledge (2006).
  • 19
    • 36549004081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill, Bork v. Burke, supra note 5, at 519-21 (emphasizing that judicial conventionalism comports with skeptic[ism] about the powers of human reason);
    • See Merrill, Bork v. Burke, supra note 5, at 519-21 (emphasizing that judicial "conventionalism" comports with "skeptic[ism] about the powers of human reason");
  • 20
    • 36549066654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 891-92 (noting that central traditionalist idea is caution about rejecting judgments of people acting reflectively and in good faith, especially when those judgments have been reaffirmed or at least accepted over time and that [j]udgments of this kind embody not just serious thought by one group of people, or even one generation, but the accumulated wisdom of many generations) ;
    • Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 891-92 (noting that "central traditionalist idea" is caution about rejecting judgments of people "acting reflectively and in good faith, especially when those judgments have been reaffirmed or at least accepted over time" and that "[j]udgments of this kind embody not just serious thought by one group of people, or even one generation, but the accumulated wisdom of many generations") ;
  • 21
    • 36549035290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 369 (articulating Burkean theory of judicial decisionmaking and suggesting that Burke opposes theories and abstractions, developed by individual minds, to traditions, built up by many minds over long periods);
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 369 (articulating Burkean theory of judicial decisionmaking and suggesting that "Burke opposes theories and abstractions, developed by individual minds, to traditions, built up by many minds over long periods");
  • 22
    • 36549023051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Young, supra note 5, at 644 47 offering Burkean account of limits of human reason
    • Young, supra note 5, at 644 47 (offering Burkean account of limits of human reason).
  • 23
    • 36549063751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the Condorcetian interpretation of Burke, see Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 370-71. Something like the Condorcetian interpretation is plausibly implicit in the other accounts cited in note 5, supra, but those discussions are vague about their epistemic assumptions.
    • For the Condorcetian interpretation of Burke, see Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 370-71. Something like the Condorcetian interpretation is plausibly implicit in the other accounts cited in note 5, supra, but those discussions are vague about their epistemic assumptions.
  • 24
    • 36549075132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally James Surowiecki, The Wisdom of Crowds 176 (2004) (noting that small groups can make very bad decisions, because influence is more direct and immediate and small-group judgments tend to be more volatile and extreme).
    • See generally James Surowiecki, The Wisdom of Crowds 176 (2004) (noting that "small groups can make very bad decisions, because influence is more direct and immediate and small-group judgments tend to be more volatile and extreme").
  • 26
    • 36549032818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • reprinted in Condorcet: Selected Writings 33, 48-49 (K. Baker ed., Bobbs-Merril 1976) [hereinafter Condorcet, Application of Mathematics].
    • reprinted in Condorcet: Selected Writings 33, 48-49 (K. Baker ed., Bobbs-Merril 1976) [hereinafter Condorcet, Application of Mathematics].
  • 27
    • 0035603046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Christian List & Robert E. Goodin, Epistemic Democracy: Generalizing the Condorcet Jury Theorem, 9 J. Pol. Phil. 277 (2001).
    • See Christian List & Robert E. Goodin, Epistemic Democracy: Generalizing the Condorcet Jury Theorem, 9 J. Pol. Phil. 277 (2001).
  • 28
    • 36549086033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the polling model interpretation of the Jury Theorem. See Nicholas R. Miller, Information, Electorates, and Democracy: Some Extensions and Interpretations of the Condorcet Jury Theorem, in Information Pooling and Group Decision Making 173 (Bernard Grofman & Guillermo Owen eds, 1986);
    • This is the "polling model" interpretation of the Jury Theorem. See Nicholas R. Miller, Information, Electorates, and Democracy: Some Extensions and Interpretations of the Condorcet Jury Theorem, in Information Pooling and Group Decision Making 173 (Bernard Grofman & Guillermo Owen eds., 1986);
  • 29
    • 0043171180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul H. Edelman, On Legal Interpretations of the Condorcet Jury Theorem, 31 J. Legal Stud. 327, 332-33 (2002).
    • Paul H. Edelman, On Legal Interpretations of the Condorcet Jury Theorem, 31 J. Legal Stud. 327, 332-33 (2002).
  • 30
    • 36549090031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 371
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 371.
  • 31
    • 36549033814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ronald Dworkin, Hard Cases, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 1057 (1976).
    • See Ronald Dworkin, Hard Cases, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 1057 (1976).
  • 32
    • 36549009094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeterminacy
    • For an overview of different versions of the basic thesis that law is indeterminate, at least in some cases, see, Dennis Patterson ed
    • For an overview of different versions of the basic thesis that law is indeterminate, at least in some cases, see Lawrence B. Solum, Indeterminacy, in A Companion to Philosophy of Law and Legal Theory 488 (Dennis Patterson ed., 1999).
    • (1999) A Companion to Philosophy of Law and Legal Theory , vol.488
    • Solum, L.B.1
  • 34
    • 36548998834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David A. Strauss, Tradition, Precedent and Justice Scalia, 12 Cardozo L. Rev. 1699, 1706 (1991) (Some precedents may be said to be part of a tradition. But not all are. Some are simply the decisions of a group of judges rendered a few years ago.).
    • See David A. Strauss, Tradition, Precedent and Justice Scalia, 12 Cardozo L. Rev. 1699, 1706 (1991) ("Some precedents may be said to be part of a tradition. But not all are. Some are simply the decisions of a group of judges rendered a few years ago.").
  • 35
    • 36549007484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See A.C. Pritchard & Todd J. Zywicki, Finding the Constitution: An Economic Analysis of Tradition's Role in Constitutional Interpretation, 77 N.C. L. Rev. 409, 489-93 (1999).
    • See A.C. Pritchard & Todd J. Zywicki, Finding the Constitution: An Economic Analysis of Tradition's Role in Constitutional Interpretation, 77 N.C. L. Rev. 409, 489-93 (1999).
  • 36
    • 36549000280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 892 (Because, in this view of traditionalism, the age of a practice alone does not warrant its value, relatively new practices that have slowly evolved over time from earlier practices deserve acceptance more than practices that are older but that have not been subject to testing over time.).
    • See, e.g., Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 892 ("Because, in this view of traditionalism, the age of a practice alone does not warrant its value, relatively new practices that have slowly evolved over time from earlier practices deserve acceptance more than practices that are older but that have not been subject to testing over time.").
  • 37
    • 36549046059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David A. Strauss, The Common Law Genius of the Warren Court 5-6 (Univ. of Chi. Pub. Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series, Paper No. 25, 2002), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=315682 (on file with the Columbia Law Review) [hereinafter Strauss, Common Law Genius] (suggesting that [i]t is unwise to try to resolve a problem without deferring, to some degree, to the collected wisdom reflected in what others have done when faced with a similar problem in the past).
    • David A. Strauss, The Common Law Genius of the Warren Court 5-6 (Univ. of Chi. Pub. Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series, Paper No. 25, 2002), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=315682 (on file with the Columbia Law Review) [hereinafter Strauss, Common Law Genius] (suggesting that "[i]t is unwise to try to resolve a problem without deferring, to some degree, to the collected wisdom reflected in what others have done when faced with a similar problem in the past").
  • 38
    • 36549061488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 17-24
    • See id. at 17-24.
  • 39
    • 36549001694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 31-32
    • Id. at 31-32.
  • 40
    • 36549005519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jeremy Bentham, Bentham's Handbook of Political Fallacies 54-56 (Harold A. Larrabee ed., 1952) (1824) [hereinafter Bentham, Handbook];
    • See Jeremy Bentham, Bentham's Handbook of Political Fallacies 54-56 (Harold A. Larrabee ed., 1952) (1824) [hereinafter Bentham, Handbook];
  • 41
    • 36549036197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blaise Pascal, Preface to the Treatise on Vacuum, in Thoughts, Letters, and Minor Works 444, 449 (Charles W. Eliot ed., M.L. Booth et al. trans., 1910).
    • Blaise Pascal, Preface to the Treatise on Vacuum, in Thoughts, Letters, and Minor Works 444, 449 (Charles W. Eliot ed., M.L. Booth et al. trans., 1910).
  • 42
    • 36549023967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This point does not hold for the polling interpretation, which we have put aside (because it is not the interpretation on which common law constitutionalists rely, In that interpretation, voters are each expressing their own preferences. See Edelman, supra note 19, at 332-33 noting that in polling model, what is considered right is the same as the outcome of a majority vote among all of the voters, In the informational interpretation, however, voters are each guessing about a common, exogenously defined right answer
    • This point does not hold for the polling interpretation, which we have put aside (because it is not the interpretation on which common law constitutionalists rely). In that interpretation, voters are each expressing their own preferences. See Edelman, supra note 19, at 332-33 (noting that in polling model, "what is considered right is the same as the outcome of a majority vote among all of the voters"). In the informational interpretation, however, voters are each guessing about a common, exogenously defined right answer.
  • 43
    • 84973937996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David M. Estlund et al., Democratic Theory and the Public Interest: Condorcet and Rousseau Revisited, 83 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 1317, 1322 (1989) (among requirements of the Jury Theorem is that voters must be addressing a common question) (Jeremy Waldron).
    • See David M. Estlund et al., Democratic Theory and the Public Interest: Condorcet and Rousseau Revisited, 83 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 1317, 1322 (1989) (among requirements of the Jury Theorem is that voters must be "addressing a common question") (Jeremy Waldron).
  • 44
    • 36549021593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thanks to Jack Goldsmith for emphasizing this point
    • Thanks to Jack Goldsmith for emphasizing this point.
  • 45
    • 36549006024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Texas v. Johnson, 491 U.S. 397, 420 (1989) (holding that conviction under state flag burning law violates First Amendment).
    • See Texas v. Johnson, 491 U.S. 397, 420 (1989) (holding that conviction under state flag burning law violates First Amendment).
  • 46
    • 36549012735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stenberg v. Carhart, 530 U.S. 914, 945-46 (2000) (holding state partial-birth abortion law unconstitutional).
    • See Stenberg v. Carhart, 530 U.S. 914, 945-46 (2000) (holding state partial-birth abortion law unconstitutional).
  • 47
    • 36549090517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare Johnson, 491 U.S. at 420, with United States v. Eichman, 496 U.S. 310, 319 (1990) (holding that federal flag burning statute violates First Amendment);
    • Compare Johnson, 491 U.S. at 420, with United States v. Eichman, 496 U.S. 310, 319 (1990) (holding that federal flag burning statute violates First Amendment);
  • 48
    • 36549081383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stenberg, 530 U.S. at 945-46, with Gonzales v. Carhart, 127 S. Ct. 1610, 1639 (2007) (upholding federal partial-birth abortion statute).
    • Stenberg, 530 U.S. at 945-46, with Gonzales v. Carhart, 127 S. Ct. 1610, 1639 (2007) (upholding federal partial-birth abortion statute).
  • 49
    • 36549038628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Oliver Wendell Holmes, Law and the Court (1913), reprinted in Collected Legal Papers 291, 295-96 (1920).
    • See Oliver Wendell Holmes, Law and the Court (1913), reprinted in Collected Legal Papers 291, 295-96 (1920).
  • 50
    • 36549025908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trop v. Dulles, 356 U.S. 86, 101 (1958).
    • Trop v. Dulles, 356 U.S. 86, 101 (1958).
  • 51
    • 36549026886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Palko v. Connecticut, 302 U.S. 319, 325 (1937), overruled by Benton v. Maryland, 395 U.S. 784 (1969).
    • Palko v. Connecticut, 302 U.S. 319, 325 (1937), overruled by Benton v. Maryland, 395 U.S. 784 (1969).
  • 52
    • 36549028773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Burke, supra note 1, at 74
    • Burke, supra note 1, at 74.
  • 53
    • 36549023052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Estlund et al., supra note 32, at 1326 (Jeremy Waldron).
    • See Estlund et al., supra note 32, at 1326 (Jeremy Waldron).
  • 54
    • 0010208591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally David Estlund, Opinion Leaders, Independence, and Condorcet's Jury Theorem, 36 Theory & Decision 131 (1994).
    • See generally David Estlund, Opinion Leaders, Independence, and Condorcet's Jury Theorem, 36 Theory & Decision 131 (1994).
  • 55
    • 36549040488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Estlund et al., supra note 32, at 1327 (Jeremy Waldron).
    • See Estlund et al., supra note 32, at 1327 (Jeremy Waldron).
  • 56
    • 0001015501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview, see Sushil Bikhchandani et al., Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades, J. Econ. Persp., Summer 1998, at 151 [hereinafter Bikhchandani et al., Behavior of Others].
    • For an overview, see Sushil Bikhchandani et al., Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades, J. Econ. Persp., Summer 1998, at 151 [hereinafter Bikhchandani et al., Behavior of Others].
  • 58
    • 0042688979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eric Talley, Precedential Cascades: An Appraisal, 73 S. Cal. L. Rev. 87, 92 (1999) (concluding that necessary conditions for precedential cascades are implausible and that it is extremely difficult... to verify whether observed judicial conformity is the byproduct of a cascade or of some omitted third factor that commonly affects all judges).
    • Eric Talley, Precedential Cascades: An Appraisal, 73 S. Cal. L. Rev. 87, 92 (1999) (concluding that necessary conditions for precedential cascades are "implausible" and that "it is extremely difficult... to verify whether observed judicial conformity is the byproduct of a cascade or of some omitted third factor that commonly affects all judges").
  • 59
    • 36549047969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew F. Daughety & Jennifer F. Reinganum, Stampede to Judgment: Persuasive Influence and Herding Behavior by Courts, 1 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 158, 161-65 (1999) (describing precedential cascade involving retroactive reach of Coal Industry Retiree Health Benefit Act of 1992).
    • Andrew F. Daughety & Jennifer F. Reinganum, Stampede to Judgment: Persuasive Influence and Herding Behavior by Courts, 1 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 158, 161-65 (1999) (describing precedential cascade involving retroactive reach of Coal Industry Retiree Health Benefit Act of 1992).
  • 60
    • 0142018830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Cristina Bicchieri & Yoshitaka Fukui, The Great Illusion: Ignorance, Informational Cascades, and the Persistence of Unpopular Norms, 9 Bus. Ethics Q. 127, 147 (1999) (concluding that it may take surprisingly little new public information to reverse the original cascade).
    • See generally Cristina Bicchieri & Yoshitaka Fukui, The Great Illusion: Ignorance, Informational Cascades, and the Persistence of Unpopular Norms, 9 Bus. Ethics Q. 127, 147 (1999) (concluding that "it may take surprisingly little new public information to reverse the original cascade").
  • 61
    • 36549041445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bikhchandani et al, Behavior of Others, supra note 44, at 157-58
    • Bikhchandani et al., Behavior of Others, supra note 44, at 157-58.
  • 62
    • 36549082919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daughety & Reinganum, supra note 47, at 159
    • Daughety & Reinganum, supra note 47, at 159.
  • 63
    • 36549062488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Societies Need
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Why Societies Need Dissent 66-70 (2003).
    • (2003) Dissent , vol.66-70
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 64
    • 0035617862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Antonio E. Bernardo & Ivo Welch, On the Evolution of Overconfidence and Entrepreneurs, 10 J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy 301, 326-27 (2001) (showing conditions under which irrational overconfidence of entrepreneurs in not following actions of others improves quality of aggregated information).
    • Cf. Antonio E. Bernardo & Ivo Welch, On the Evolution of Overconfidence and Entrepreneurs, 10 J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy 301, 326-27 (2001) (showing conditions under which irrational overconfidence of entrepreneurs in not following actions of others improves quality of aggregated information).
  • 65
    • 36549033809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In principle, judges might prevent the Burkean paradox from arising by issuing opinions that record their independent judgments while basing their actual decisions on precedent. In this model, later courts will have both the precedent based decision, which is of low or nil informational value, and the earlier court's independent judgment, which has positive value. Although this may sometimes happen, I believe it is rare, for both an economic reason and a psychological one. The economic reason is that judges decide on die basis of precedent in part to conserve on the costs of decisionmaking for themselves. To incur the costs of forming an independent judgment that, by hypothesis, will not affect the current decision is to provide a benefit only to future judges and is thus a contribution to an informational public good; many judges will free ride, and the informational public good will be underproduced. The psychological reason is that it is hard to keep one's precedent-independent judg
    • In principle, judges might prevent the Burkean paradox from arising by issuing opinions that record their independent judgments while basing their actual decisions on precedent. In this model, later courts will have both the precedent based decision, which is of low or nil informational value, and the earlier court's independent judgment, which has positive value. Although this may sometimes happen, I believe it is rare, for both an economic reason and a psychological one. The economic reason is that judges decide on die basis of precedent in part to conserve on the costs of decisionmaking for themselves. To incur the costs of forming an independent judgment that, by hypothesis, will not affect the current decision is to provide a benefit only to future judges and is thus a contribution to an informational public good; many judges will free ride, and the informational public good will be underproduced. The psychological reason is that it is hard to keep one's precedent-independent judgment from being infected by what many judges and other people in the past have said. Although the claim that the views of people in the past constitute our present identity is mysterious, the claim that those views structure our present thinking is not.
  • 66
    • 34547216791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parts of this subsection draw upon a similar discussion in Adrian Vermeule, Should We Have Lay Justices?, 59 Stan. L. Rev. 1569, 1589-90 (2007).
    • Parts of this subsection draw upon a similar discussion in Adrian Vermeule, Should We Have Lay Justices?, 59 Stan. L. Rev. 1569, 1589-90 (2007).
  • 67
    • 0003213264 scopus 로고
    • Introductory View of the Rationale of Evidence
    • See, John Bowring ed, London, Simkin, Marshall & Co
    • See Jeremy Bentham, Introductory View of the Rationale of Evidence, in 6 The Works of Jeremy Bentham 22-24 (John Bowring ed., London, Simkin, Marshall & Co. 1843).
    • (1843) 6 The Works of Jeremy Bentham , pp. 22-24
    • Bentham, J.1
  • 69
    • 36549050354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a similarity here to Cardozo's idea that [t]he eccentricities of judges balance one another so that out of the attrition of diverse minds there is beaten something which has a[n] . . . average value greater than its component elements. Benjamin N. Cardozo, The Nature of the Judicial Process 177 (1921).
    • There is a similarity here to Cardozo's idea that "[t]he eccentricities of judges balance one another" so that "out of the attrition of diverse minds there is beaten something which has a[n] . . . average value greater than its component elements." Benjamin N. Cardozo, The Nature of the Judicial Process 177 (1921).
  • 70
    • 36549056566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Krishna K. Ladha, The Condorcet Jury Theorem, Free Speech, and Correlated Votes, 36 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 617, 625-30 (1992).
    • See Krishna K. Ladha, The Condorcet Jury Theorem, Free Speech, and Correlated Votes, 36 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 617, 625-30 (1992).
  • 71
    • 36549064723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 628-29
    • See id. at 628-29.
  • 72
    • 36549059650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 629. In Ladha's example, a group of three decisionmakers each competent at the .8 level cannot be certain of getting the right answer whatever the voting rule. However, if the group adds two uninformed, worse-than-random guessers, whose competence is a mere .3, then the group is certain to choose the right answer so long as the guesses of the uninformed are negatively correlated with those of the informed.
    • Id. at 629. In Ladha's example, a group of three decisionmakers each competent at the .8 level cannot be certain of getting the right answer whatever the voting rule. However, if the group adds two uninformed, worse-than-random guessers, whose competence is a mere .3, then the group is certain to choose the right answer so long as the guesses of the uninformed are negatively correlated with those of the informed.
  • 73
    • 36549040958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 77
    • 36549089060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Three relevant hypotheses, in roughly descending order of rigor, are that: (1) legal training gives lawyers a strong status quo orientation and a bias to conventional morality, as compared to similarly educated adults, see Lawrence J. Landwehr, Lawyers as Social Progressives or Reactionaries: The Law and Order Cognitive Orientation of Lawyers, 7 Law & Psychol. Rev. 39, 44-48 (1982);
    • Three relevant hypotheses, in roughly descending order of rigor, are that: (1) legal training gives lawyers a strong status quo orientation and a bias to conventional morality, as compared to similarly educated adults, see Lawrence J. Landwehr, Lawyers as Social Progressives or Reactionaries: The Law and Order Cognitive Orientation of Lawyers, 7 Law & Psychol. Rev. 39, 44-48 (1982);
  • 78
    • 36549080905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 legal training reduces law students' general concern for social justice, see Susan Ann Kay, Socializing the Future Elite: The Nonimpact of a Law School, 59 Soc Sci. Q. 347 (1978) (noting this hypothesis, but then conducting study that suggests that law school does not affect students' outlook on social justice), and reduces their interest in public service or public interest lawyering
    • 2 legal training reduces law students' general concern for social justice, see Susan Ann Kay, Socializing the Future Elite: The Nonimpact of a Law School, 59 Soc Sci. Q. 347 (1978) (noting this hypothesis, but then conducting study that suggests that law school does not affect students' outlook on social justice), and reduces their interest in public service or public interest lawyering
  • 80
    • 36549034310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 3 legal training causes lawyers to favor cumbersome and complicated processes for generating policy, see, e.g., Jerold S. Auerbach, A Plague of Lawyers, Harper's, Oct. 1976, at 37, 40-42.
    • 3 legal training causes lawyers to favor cumbersome and complicated processes for generating policy, see, e.g., Jerold S. Auerbach, A Plague of Lawyers, Harper's, Oct. 1976, at 37, 40-42.
  • 81
    • 36549017627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Auerbach, supra note 64, at 41-42 suggesting that legalization of society places priority on individual procedural rights to detriment of substantive norms
    • Cf. Auerbach, supra note 64, at 41-42 (suggesting that legalization of society places priority on individual procedural rights to detriment of substantive norms).
  • 82
    • 36549066658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I take this public meaning originalism to have become the standard version, superseding the older framers' intentions version of originalism. The differences between them make no difference to the analysis here.
    • I take this "public meaning" originalism to have become the standard version, superseding the older "framers' intentions" version of originalism. The differences between them make no difference to the analysis here.
  • 83
    • 36549086532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gary Lawson, On Reading Recipes . . . and Constitutions, 85 Geo. L.J. 1823, 1833-34 (1997);
    • See Gary Lawson, On Reading Recipes . . . and Constitutions, 85 Geo. L.J. 1823, 1833-34 (1997);
  • 84
    • 36549069739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Radicals in Tweed Jackets: Why Extreme Left-Wing Law Professors Are Wrong for America, 106
    • book review
    • Saikrishna Prakash, Radicals in Tweed Jackets: Why Extreme Left-Wing Law Professors Are Wrong for America, 106 Colum. L. Rev. 2207, 2224 (2006) (book review).
    • (2006) Colum. L. Rev , vol.2207 , pp. 2224
    • Prakash, S.1
  • 86
    • 36549049365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven G. Calabresi, Text, Precedent, and the Constitution: Some Originalist and Normative Arguments for Overruling Planned Parenthood of Southeastern Pennsylvania v. Casey, 22 Const. Comment. 311, 345-46 (2005) ([T] he Supreme Court ought to follow the constitutional text over precedent).
    • Steven G. Calabresi, Text, Precedent, and the Constitution: Some Originalist and Normative Arguments for Overruling Planned Parenthood of Southeastern Pennsylvania v. Casey, 22 Const. Comment. 311, 345-46 (2005) ("[T] he Supreme Court ought to follow the constitutional text over precedent").
  • 87
    • 36549074608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Strauss, Common Law Genius, supra note 27, at 8 (arguing that under common law approach one can break with past if one can show that the . . . old regime did not work very well).
    • Cf. Strauss, Common Law Genius, supra note 27, at 8 (arguing that under common law approach one can break with past if one can "show that the . . . old regime did not work very well").
  • 88
    • 36549042475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John C. Harsanyi, Morality and the Theory of Rational Behaviour, in Utilitarianism and Beyond 39, 44-46 (Amartya Sen & Bernard Williams eds., 1982) (explaining equiprobability model of moral judgments).
    • John C. Harsanyi, Morality and the Theory of Rational Behaviour, in Utilitarianism and Beyond 39, 44-46 (Amartya Sen & Bernard Williams eds., 1982) (explaining equiprobability model of moral judgments).
  • 89
    • 36549050359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See James Bradley Thayer, The Origin and Scope of the American Doctrine of Constitutional Law, 7 Harv. L. Rev. 129, 144 (1893) (arguing that courts can only disregard [an] Act when those who have the right to make laws have not merely made a mistake, but have made a very clear one,-so clear that it is not open to rational question).
    • See James Bradley Thayer, The Origin and Scope of the American Doctrine of Constitutional Law, 7 Harv. L. Rev. 129, 144 (1893) (arguing that courts "can only disregard [an] Act when those who have the right to make laws have not merely made a mistake, but have made a very clear one,-so clear that it is not open to rational question").
  • 90
    • 36549017153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See List & Goodin, supra note 18, at 287 tbl.1. If average competence in the group of 301 falls to .51, barely better than random, the majority's chance of choosing correctly is about sixty-four percent. See id. at 287.
    • See List & Goodin, supra note 18, at 287 tbl.1. If average competence in the group of 301 falls to .51, barely better than random, the majority's chance of choosing correctly is about sixty-four percent. See id. at 287.
  • 91
    • 36549041450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Condorcet, Application of Mathematics, supra note 17, at 49
    • Condorcet, Application of Mathematics, supra note 17, at 49.
  • 92
    • 1142274238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When the House leadership held open voting for three hours to allow time to round up members to vote for a controversial prescription drug bill in 2003, an outcry resulted. See John K. Iglehart, The New Medicare Prescription-Drug Benefit, A Pure Power Play, 350 New Eng. J. Med. 826, 828-29 2004, describing how embittered Democrats denounced vote as a travesty
    • When the House leadership held open voting for three hours to allow time to round up members to vote for a controversial prescription drug bill in 2003, an outcry resulted. See John K. Iglehart, The New Medicare Prescription-Drug Benefit - A Pure Power Play, 350 New Eng. J. Med. 826, 828-29 (2004) (describing how "embittered Democrats" denounced vote as "a travesty").
  • 93
    • 36549061491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new Democratic Congress elected at the end of 2006 limited this practice by providing that votes may not be held open for the sole purpose of reversing the outcome. See House Rule XX, cl. 2(a), available at http://www. rules.house.gov/ruleprec/house_rules.htm (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • The new Democratic Congress elected at the end of 2006 limited this practice by providing that votes may not be held open "for the sole purpose of reversing the outcome." See House Rule XX, cl. 2(a), available at http://www. rules.house.gov/ruleprec/house_rules.htm (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
  • 94
    • 36549046062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jeremy Bentham, Political Tactics 106-07 (Michael James et al. eds., 1999).
    • Jeremy Bentham, Political Tactics 106-07 (Michael James et al. eds., 1999).
  • 95
    • 36548999311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Keith Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organization 142-43 (1991) (arguing that division of labor into committees combined with seniority system fosters expertise).
    • See Keith Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organization 142-43 (1991) (arguing that division of labor into committees combined with seniority system fosters expertise).
  • 96
    • 36549007488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Neil Komesar, Imperfect Alternatives: Choosing Institutions in Law, Economics and Public Policy 141 (1994) (noting tradeoff between information and evenhandedness).
    • See Neil Komesar, Imperfect Alternatives: Choosing Institutions in Law, Economics and Public Policy 141 (1994) (noting tradeoff between information and evenhandedness).
  • 97
    • 84898686607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Christian List & Philip Pettit, An Epistemic Free-Riding Problem?, in Karl Popper: Critical Appraisals 128, 138-40 (Philip Catton & Graham Macdonald eds., 2004) (suggesting that knowledge of Jury Theorem among group's voters may increase temptation to free ride on information of others).
    • Cf. Christian List & Philip Pettit, An Epistemic Free-Riding Problem?, in Karl Popper: Critical Appraisals 128, 138-40 (Philip Catton & Graham Macdonald eds., 2004) (suggesting that knowledge of Jury Theorem among group's voters may increase temptation to free ride on information of others).
  • 98
    • 0038806492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the tradeoff between group size and free riding on the information of others, see generally Drora Karotkin & Jacob Paroush, Optimum Committee Size: Quality-Versus-Quantity Dilemma, 20 Soc. Choice & Welfare 429 (2003).
    • For the tradeoff between group size and free riding on the information of others, see generally Drora Karotkin & Jacob Paroush, Optimum Committee Size: Quality-Versus-Quantity Dilemma, 20 Soc. Choice & Welfare 429 (2003).
  • 100
    • 33744988618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Would Rational Voters Acquire Costly Information?, 129
    • See
    • See César Martinelli, Would Rational Voters Acquire Costly Information?, 129 J. Econ. Theory 225, 240-41 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Econ. Theory , vol.225 , pp. 240-241
    • Martinelli, C.1
  • 101
    • 0000618084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Timothy J. Feddersen & Wolfgang Pesendorfer, The Swing Voters' Curse, 86 Am. Econ. Rev. 408, 408-24 (1996) (discussing conditions under which uninformed voters will rationally abstain).
    • Cf. Timothy J. Feddersen & Wolfgang Pesendorfer, The Swing Voters' Curse, 86 Am. Econ. Rev. 408, 408-24 (1996) (discussing conditions under which uninformed voters will rationally abstain).
  • 102
    • 36549086032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Martinelli, supra note 82, at 226-27;
    • Martinelli, supra note 82, at 226-27;
  • 103
    • 36549037641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Minoru Kitahara & Yohei Sekiguchi, Condorcet Jury Theorem or Rational Ignorance? 4 (rev. Jan. 31, 2006), available at http://wakame.econ. hit-u.ac.jp/~riron/Workshop/2006/sekiguchi06.pdf (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (showing conditions under which [e]ven if the amount of information acquired by each voter is small, the amount of aggregated information can be large enough to [reach] the correct decision).
    • see also Minoru Kitahara & Yohei Sekiguchi, Condorcet Jury Theorem or Rational Ignorance? 4 (rev. Jan. 31, 2006), available at http://wakame.econ. hit-u.ac.jp/~riron/Workshop/2006/sekiguchi06.pdf (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (showing conditions under which "[e]ven if the amount of information acquired by each voter is small, the amount of aggregated information can be large enough to [reach] the correct decision").
  • 104
    • 0041805374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under the conventional view, legislatures may not entrench statutes by making it harder for a future legislature to repeal the statute than it was for the original legislature to enact it. For a critique of this view, see Eric A. Posner & Adrian Vermeule, Legislative Entrenchment: A Reappraisal, 111 Yale L.J. 1665 (2002). For critiques of the critique
    • Under the conventional view, legislatures may not entrench statutes by making it harder for a future legislature to repeal the statute than it was for the original legislature to enact it. For a critique of this view, see Eric A. Posner & Adrian Vermeule, Legislative Entrenchment: A Reappraisal, 111 Yale L.J. 1665 (2002). For critiques of the critique
  • 105
    • 0742323940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see John C. Roberts & Erwin Chemerinsky, Entrenchment of Ordinary Legislation: A Reply to Professors Posner and Vermeule, 91 Cal. L. Rev. 1773 (2003);
    • see John C. Roberts & Erwin Chemerinsky, Entrenchment of Ordinary Legislation: A Reply to Professors Posner and Vermeule, 91 Cal. L. Rev. 1773 (2003);
  • 106
    • 84937297076 scopus 로고
    • The Constitutionality of Legislative Supermajority Requirements: A Defense, 105
    • see also
    • see also John O. McGinnis & Michael B. Rappaport, The Constitutionality of Legislative Supermajority Requirements: A Defense, 105 Yale L.J. 483, 503 (1995).
    • (1995) Yale L.J , vol.483 , pp. 503
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Rappaport, M.B.2
  • 107
    • 36549003610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symmetrically, this implies that on the Condorcetian interpretation of precedent, judges should count overruled cases as information, despite their null legal status
    • Symmetrically, this implies that on the Condorcetian interpretation of precedent, judges should count overruled cases as information, despite their null legal status.
  • 108
    • 36549012732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Suppose that at Time 1, nine Justices voted unanimously for Rule R, but then at Time 2, a different nine Justices voted 5-4 to overrule the Time 1 precedent in favor of rule S. Putting aside the problem that the Justices at Times 1 and 2 were not really addressing the same questions (because only the former was a case of first impression), a Justice sitting at Time 3 should aggregate over the whole group of eighteen Justices, counting the vote as 13-5 in favor of R.
    • Suppose that at Time 1, nine Justices voted unanimously for Rule R, but then at Time 2, a different nine Justices voted 5-4 to overrule the Time 1 precedent in favor of rule S. Putting aside the problem that the Justices at Times 1 and 2 were not really addressing the same questions (because only the former was a case of first impression), a Justice sitting at Time 3 should aggregate over the whole group of eighteen Justices, counting the "vote" as 13-5 in favor of R.
  • 109
    • 77956124761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New American Constitutionalism
    • Richard W. Bauman & Tsvi Kahana eds
    • William N. Eskridge, Jr. & John Ferejohn, Super-Statutes: The New American Constitutionalism, in The Least Examined Branch 320 (Richard W. Bauman & Tsvi Kahana eds., 2006).
    • (2006) The Least Examined Branch , vol.320
    • Eskridge Jr., W.N.1    John Ferejohn, S.2
  • 110
    • 36549055607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For some speculations, see id
    • For some speculations, see id.
  • 111
    • 84858474184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 89-110, 79 Stat. 437 (codified as amended at 42 U.S.C. §§ 1971, 1973 to 1973bb-1 2000
    • Pub. L. No. 89-110, 79 Stat. 437 (codified as amended at 42 U.S.C. §§ 1971, 1973 to 1973bb-1 (2000)).
  • 112
    • 36549037189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Act was renewed with support from the Republican House leadership. It passed the House by a vote of 390-33 and the Senate by a vote of 98-0. See Raymond Hernandez, After Challenges, House Approves Renewal of Voting Act, N.Y. Times, July 14, 2006, at A13 (describing House vote and initial opposition to Act);
    • The Act was renewed with support from the Republican House leadership. It passed the House by a vote of 390-33 and the Senate by a vote of 98-0. See Raymond Hernandez, After Challenges, House Approves Renewal of Voting Act, N.Y. Times, July 14, 2006, at A13 (describing House vote and initial opposition to Act);
  • 113
    • 36549064241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carl Huse, By a Vote of 98-0, Senate Approves 25-Year Extension of Voting Rights Act, N.Y. Times, July 21, 2006, at Al (describing Senate vote).
    • Carl Huse, By a Vote of 98-0, Senate Approves 25-Year Extension of Voting Rights Act, N.Y. Times, July 21, 2006, at Al (describing Senate vote).
  • 114
    • 36549053601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss, Common Law Genius, supra note 27
    • Strauss, Common Law Genius, supra note 27.
  • 115
    • 36549073691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 93-205, 87 Stat. 884 (codified in scattered sections of 16 U.S.C).
    • Pub. L. No. 93-205, 87 Stat. 884 (codified in scattered sections of 16 U.S.C).
  • 116
    • 36549006023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 91-135, 83 Stat. 275 (repealed 1973).
    • Pub. L. No. 91-135, 83 Stat. 275 (repealed 1973).
  • 117
    • 36549072486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 89-669, 80 Stat. 926 (repealed 1973).
    • Pub. L. No. 89-669, 80 Stat. 926 (repealed 1973).
  • 118
    • 36549048383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bradford C. Mank, Can Congress Regulate Intrastate Endangered Species Under the Commerce Clause?, 69 Brook. L. Rev. 923, 933-41 (2004). The Endangered Species Act did break with the past in important ways, especially by applying to nonfederal lands, but it was not created out of thin air.
    • See Bradford C. Mank, Can Congress Regulate Intrastate Endangered Species Under the Commerce Clause?, 69 Brook. L. Rev. 923, 933-41 (2004). The Endangered Species Act did break with the past in important ways, especially by applying to nonfederal lands, but it was not created out of thin air.
  • 119
    • 36549047030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assuming away the internal problems discussed in I.B
    • Assuming away the internal problems discussed in I.B.
  • 120
    • 36549075586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 356
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 356.
  • 121
    • 36549055606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jeremy Waldron, Custom Redeemed by Statute, 51 Current Legal Probs. 93, 100 (1998) (Bentham argued that once they come into the hands of the judges, customs tend to be ill-used and subjected to arbitrary and unpredictable modifications.).
    • Jeremy Waldron, Custom Redeemed by Statute, 51 Current Legal Probs. 93, 100 (1998) ("Bentham argued that once they come into the hands of the judges, customs tend to be ill-used and subjected to arbitrary and unpredictable modifications.").
  • 122
    • 36549033811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Youngstown Sheet & Tube Co. v. Sawyer, 343 U.S. 579, 610-11 (1952) (Frankfurter, J., concurring).
    • Youngstown Sheet & Tube Co. v. Sawyer, 343 U.S. 579, 610-11 (1952) (Frankfurter, J., concurring).
  • 123
    • 36549015684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an example of this issue, compare Furman v. Georgia, 408 U.S. 238, 239-40 (1972) (per curiam) (invalidating Georgia and Texas death penalty schemes), with Gregg v. Georgia, 428 U.S. 153, 169 (1976) (validating death penalty after state reenactments of new schemes).
    • For an example of this issue, compare Furman v. Georgia, 408 U.S. 238, 239-40 (1972) (per curiam) (invalidating Georgia and Texas death penalty schemes), with Gregg v. Georgia, 428 U.S. 153, 169 (1976) (validating death penalty after state reenactments of new schemes).
  • 124
    • 36549018125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the evolutionary interpretation of Burke, see, e.g., Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 879 (arguing for a form of traditionalism, characteristic of the common law method, [that] calls for recognizing the value of conclusions that have been arrived at, over time, by an evolutionary process);
    • For the evolutionary interpretation of Burke, see, e.g., Strauss, Common Law Interpretation, supra note 5, at 879 (arguing for a "form of traditionalism, characteristic of the common law method, [that] calls for recognizing the value of conclusions that have been arrived at, over time, by an evolutionary process");
  • 125
    • 36549039567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 368 (Burkeans might stress not social practices but the slow evolution of judicial doctrine over time .... For these Burkeans, what is particularly important is the judiciary's prior judgments, which should in turn be based on a series of small steps, and should avoid radical departures.);
    • Sunstein, Burkean Minimalism, supra note 5, at 368 ("Burkeans might stress not social practices but the slow evolution of judicial doctrine over time .... For these Burkeans, what is particularly important is the judiciary's prior judgments, which should in turn be based on a series of small steps, and should avoid radical departures.");
  • 126
    • 36549016130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Young, supra note 5, at 653-56 (offering evolutionary interpretation of Burke and connecting Burke's theory of reform to the common-law tradition of evolutionary change).
    • Young, supra note 5, at 653-56 (offering evolutionary interpretation of Burke and connecting "Burke's theory of reform" to "the common-law tradition of evolutionary change").
  • 127
    • 36549015181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is a paraphrase of Adam Ferguson's famous observation that nations stumble upon establishments, which are indeed the result of human action, but not the execution of any human design. Adam Ferguson, An Essay on the History of Civil Society 119 Fania Oz-Salzberger ed, Cambridge Univ. Press 1995, 1767
    • This is a paraphrase of Adam Ferguson's famous observation that "nations stumble upon establishments, which are indeed the result of human action, but not the execution of any human design." Adam Ferguson, An Essay on the History of Civil Society 119 (Fania Oz-Salzberger ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1995) (1767).
  • 128
    • 36549032821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert N. Brandon, Concepts and Methods in Evolutionary Biology 47 (1996) (defining natural selection according to these criteria).
    • See Robert N. Brandon, Concepts and Methods in Evolutionary Biology 47 (1996) (defining natural selection according to these criteria).
  • 129
    • 33644678626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For supply-side analysis based on competition among institutions providing legal rules, see generally Todd J. Zywicki, The Rise and Fall of Efficiency in the Common Law: A Supply-Side Analysis, 97 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1551, 1620 (2003) [hereinafter Zywicki, Rise and Fall] (arguing that competition among different courts with overlapping jurisdictions during formative era of common law led to innovation and incentives to provide efficient legal rules). Zywicki also argues that an increase in the strength of precedent in the nineteenth century exacerbated various problems with the common law, such as rent seeking.
    • For supply-side analysis based on competition among institutions providing legal rules, see generally Todd J. Zywicki, The Rise and Fall of Efficiency in the Common Law: A Supply-Side Analysis, 97 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1551, 1620 (2003) [hereinafter Zywicki, Rise and Fall] (arguing that competition among different courts with overlapping jurisdictions during formative era of common law "led to innovation and incentives to provide efficient legal rules"). Zywicki also argues that an increase in the strength of precedent in the nineteenth century exacerbated various problems with the common law, such as rent seeking.
  • 130
    • 36549063469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1565
    • See id. at 1565.
  • 131
    • 36549056570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a recent summary, see Paul H. Rubin, Why Was the Common Law Efficient? 2-9 (Emory Law & Econ. Research Paper Series, Paper No. 04-06, 2004), available at http:/ /papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=498645 (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • For a recent summary, see Paul H. Rubin, Why Was the Common Law Efficient? 2-9 (Emory Law & Econ. Research Paper Series, Paper No. 04-06, 2004), available at http:/ /papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=498645 (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
  • 132
    • 36549002681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul H. Rubin, Why is the Common Law Efficient?, 6J. Legal Stud. 51, 53 (1977) [hereinafter, Rubin, Why Efficient];
    • Paul H. Rubin, Why is the Common Law Efficient?, 6J. Legal Stud. 51, 53 (1977) [hereinafter, Rubin, Why Efficient];
  • 133
    • 0001913043 scopus 로고
    • The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6
    • see also
    • see also George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. Legal Stud. 65 (1977).
    • (1977) J. Legal Stud , vol.65
    • Priest, G.L.1
  • 134
    • 36549071579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a critique drawing on behavioral economics, see Adam J. Hirsch, Evolutionary Theories of Common Law Efficiency: Reasons for (Cognitive) Skepticism, 32 FIa. St. U. L. Rev. 425 (2005);
    • For a critique drawing on behavioral economics, see Adam J. Hirsch, Evolutionary Theories of Common Law Efficiency: Reasons for (Cognitive) Skepticism, 32 FIa. St. U. L. Rev. 425 (2005);
  • 135
    • 36549039072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for a different critique, see Gillian K. Hadfield, Bias in the Evolution of Legal Rules, 80 Geo. LJ. 583, 616 (1992) (arguing that claims about efficiency of common law are based on a weak concept of efficiency). I will bracket such issues in the discussion here.
    • for a different critique, see Gillian K. Hadfield, Bias in the Evolution of Legal Rules, 80 Geo. LJ. 583, 616 (1992) (arguing that claims about efficiency of common law are based on "a weak concept of efficiency"). I will bracket such issues in the discussion here.
  • 136
    • 84874816001 scopus 로고
    • Adjudication as a Private Good, 8
    • See
    • See William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Adjudication as a Private Good, 8 J. Legal Stud. 235, 273 (1979).
    • (1979) J. Legal Stud , vol.235 , pp. 273
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 137
    • 36549010034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The authors of the basic model recognized this point. See Rubin, Why Efficient, supra note 106, at 53-57
    • The authors of the basic model recognized this point. See Rubin, Why Efficient, supra note 106, at 53-57.
  • 138
    • 36549059652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gordon Tullock, The Case Against the Common Law 15 (1997) (arguing that entire legal system is influenced by interest groups);
    • See Gordon Tullock, The Case Against the Common Law 15 (1997) (arguing that entire legal system is influenced by interest groups);
  • 139
    • 36549027396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101 Yale L.J. 31, 34 (1991) (arguing that [t]he litigation process cannot be treated as exogenous to interest group theory because that process is also subject to forms of interest group influence).
    • Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101 Yale L.J. 31, 34 (1991) (arguing that "[t]he litigation process cannot be treated as exogenous to interest group theory because that process is also subject to forms of interest group influence").
  • 140
    • 36549035292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Tullock, supra note 110, at 52;
    • See Tullock, supra note 110, at 52;
  • 141
    • 36549064242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul H. Rubin, Common Law and Statute Law, 11 J. Legal Stud. 205, 211-19 (1982) [hereinafter, Rubin, Common Law and Statute Law].
    • Paul H. Rubin, Common Law and Statute Law, 11 J. Legal Stud. 205, 211-19 (1982) [hereinafter, Rubin, Common Law and Statute Law].
  • 142
    • 36549069734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Zywicki, Rise and Fall, supra note 104, at 1620-21
    • See Zywicki, Rise and Fall, supra note 104, at 1620-21.
  • 143
    • 33646180701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Keith N. Hylton, Information, Litigation, and Common Law Evolution, 8 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 33, 57 (2006).
    • See, e.g., Keith N. Hylton, Information, Litigation, and Common Law Evolution, 8 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 33, 57 (2006).
  • 144
    • 36549070642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jon Elster, Ulysses and the Sirens 6 (rev. ed. 1984).
    • See Jon Elster, Ulysses and the Sirens 6 (rev. ed. 1984).
  • 145
    • 36549072489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The best discussion is Elhauge, supra note 110, at 48-66.
    • The best discussion is Elhauge, supra note 110, at 48-66.
  • 146
    • 36549008635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Ronald Dworkin, Is Wealth a Value?, 9 J. Legal Stud. 191 (1980) (arguing that wealth cannot be understood as a value).
    • See generally Ronald Dworkin, Is Wealth a Value?, 9 J. Legal Stud. 191 (1980) (arguing that wealth cannot be understood as a value).
  • 148
    • 36549042967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Louis Kaplow & Steven M. Shavell, Why the Legal System is Less Efficient than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income, 23 J. Legal Stud. 667, 674-76 (1994).
    • See Louis Kaplow & Steven M. Shavell, Why the Legal System is Less Efficient than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income, 23 J. Legal Stud. 667, 674-76 (1994).
  • 149
    • 36549042473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Richard A. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law 99 (1st ed. 1972) (In searching for a reasonably objective and impartial standard, as the traditions of the bench require him to do, the judge can hardly fail to consider whether the loss was the product of wasteful, uneconomical resource use.). For a critique of the intentional version of the common law efficiency thesis, especially as applied to public law
    • See Richard A. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law 99 (1st ed. 1972) ("In searching for a reasonably objective and impartial standard, as the traditions of the bench require him to do, the judge can hardly fail to consider whether the loss was the product of wasteful, uneconomical resource use."). For a critique of the intentional version of the common law efficiency thesis, especially as applied to public law
  • 150
    • 36549023442 scopus 로고
    • Statutes, and the Theory of Efficient Adjudication, 9
    • see Frank I. Michelman, Constitutions, Statutes, and the Theory of Efficient Adjudication, 9 J. Legal Stud. 431 (1980).
    • (1980) J. Legal Stud , vol.431
    • see Frank, I.1    Michelman, C.2
  • 151
    • 36549034309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gary S. Becker, A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, 98 Q.J. Econ. 371, 375 (1983).
    • See Gary S. Becker, A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, 98 Q.J. Econ. 371, 375 (1983).
  • 153
    • 36549071125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rubin, Why Efficient, supra note 106, at 61 discussing parallels between efficient legislation and efficient common law
    • Rubin, Why Efficient, supra note 106, at 61 (discussing parallels between efficient legislation and efficient common law).
  • 155
    • 36549065697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Elhauge, supra note 110, at 34;
    • See Elhauge, supra note 110, at 34;
  • 156
    • 0346208515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Frank B. Cross, The Judiciary and Public Choice, 50 Hastings L.J. 355, 360-68 (1999);
    • see also Frank B. Cross, The Judiciary and Public Choice, 50 Hastings L.J. 355, 360-68 (1999);
  • 157
    • 36549042969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lewis A. Kornhauser, Legal Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law 15-16 (May 31, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Columbia Law Review), available at http://www.law.nyu.edu/clppt/program 2006/readings/D_N_W_colloquium_excerpt.pdf.
    • Lewis A. Kornhauser, Legal Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law 15-16 (May 31, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Columbia Law Review), available at http://www.law.nyu.edu/clppt/program 2006/readings/D_N_W_colloquium_excerpt.pdf.
  • 158
    • 36549036724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pritchard & Zywicki, supra note 25, at 494-501 discussing rent seeking through Supreme Court litigation and decisionmaking in constitutional cases
    • See Pritchard & Zywicki, supra note 25, at 494-501 (discussing rent seeking through Supreme Court litigation and decisionmaking in constitutional cases).
  • 159
    • 36548999309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill, Public Choice, supra note 4, at 221-22 (arguing that there is greater minimum bid limitation for legislature than judiciary);
    • See Merrill, Public Choice, supra note 4, at 221-22 (arguing that there is greater "minimum bid limitation" for legislature than judiciary);
  • 160
    • 36549068234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Todd. J. Zywicki, Gordon Tullock's Critique of the Common Law 46 (George Mason L. & Econ. Research Paper No. 07-13, 2007), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=964781 (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (discussing differences in rent-seeking pressures on legislature and judiciary).
    • cf. Todd. J. Zywicki, Gordon Tullock's Critique of the Common Law 46 (George Mason L. & Econ. Research Paper No. 07-13, 2007), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=964781 (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (discussing differences in "rent-seeking pressures" on legislature and judiciary).
  • 161
    • 36549073694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For further discussion, see generally Cross, supra note 123
    • For further discussion, see generally Cross, supra note 123.
  • 162
    • 36549066182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardozo, supra note 57, at 177. The Cardozo Theorem is named, and discussed, in Nicola Gennaioli & Andrei Shleifer, The Evolution of Common Law, 115 J. Pol. Econ. 43, 44, 60-61 (2007) [hereinafter Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law].
    • Cardozo, supra note 57, at 177. The Cardozo Theorem is named, and discussed, in Nicola Gennaioli & Andrei Shleifer, The Evolution of Common Law, 115 J. Pol. Econ. 43, 44, 60-61 (2007) [hereinafter Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law].
  • 163
    • 33947515578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A companion paper is Nicola Gennaioli & Andrei Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, 35 J. Comp. Econ. 309 (2007) [hereinafter Gennaioli & Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law].
    • A companion paper is Nicola Gennaioli & Andrei Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, 35 J. Comp. Econ. 309 (2007) [hereinafter Gennaioli & Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law].
  • 164
    • 36549047476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although Gennaioli and Shleifer do consider how their model of overruling can be extended to incorporate demand-side effects, they do not do so for their model of distinguishing. See Gennaioli & Shliefer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, supra note 127, at 320-22. In any event, the distinctive and novel feature of their approach is the focus on the supply side-on efficiency as the unintended byproduct of uncoordinated decisionmaking by a series of biased judges over time
    • Although Gennaioli and Shleifer do consider how their model of overruling can be extended to incorporate demand-side effects, they do not do so for their model of distinguishing. See Gennaioli & Shliefer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, supra note 127, at 320-22. In any event, the distinctive and novel feature of their approach is the focus on the supply side-on efficiency as the unintended byproduct of uncoordinated decisionmaking by a series of biased judges over time.
  • 165
    • 36549037192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 62
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 62.
  • 166
    • 36549013641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distinguishing is addressed in Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 43. Overruling is addressed in Gennaioli & Shliefer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, supra note 127, at 309.
    • Distinguishing is addressed in Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 43. Overruling is addressed in Gennaioli & Shliefer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, supra note 127, at 309.
  • 167
    • 36549086772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tends toward efficiency, but is unlikely to converge to full efficiency. Gennaioli and Shleifer do not claim that distinguishing produces the full efficiency of judge-made law. Rather, they make the weaker claim that legal evolution is beneficial on average, because the informational benefit of distinguishing improves the quality of the law. Gennaioli & Shliefer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 47.
    • Tends toward efficiency, but is unlikely to converge to full efficiency. Gennaioli and Shleifer do not claim that distinguishing produces the full efficiency of judge-made law. Rather, they make the weaker claim that legal evolution is beneficial on average, because "the informational benefit of distinguishing improves the quality of the law." Gennaioli & Shliefer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 47.
  • 168
    • 36549079583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 54-56
    • See id. at 54-56.
  • 169
    • 36549054690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 62-63
    • Id. at 62-63.
  • 170
    • 36549049837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, supra note 127, at 317-18 (Proposition 4).
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law,
  • 171
    • 36549065225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 323
    • Id. at 323.
  • 172
    • 36549054060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Karl N. Llewellyn, The Common Law Tradition 287 (1960) ('[A] distinction widiout a difference' is a stench ....).
    • See Karl N. Llewellyn, The Common Law Tradition 287 (1960) ("'[A] distinction widiout a difference' is a stench ....").
  • 174
    • 36549076980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I use Eleventh Amendment only as a shorthand, bracketing the question whether the Court is here developing a body of law rooted in the Amendment's text or radier in background structural principles of federalism.
    • I use "Eleventh Amendment" only as a shorthand, bracketing the question whether the Court is here developing a body of law rooted in the Amendment's text or radier in background structural principles of federalism.
  • 175
    • 36549069738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of these complex and often counterintuitive interpretations of the Eleventh Amendment, see 1 Laurence H. Tribe, American Constitutional Law 519-66 (3ded. 2000).
    • For an overview of these "complex and often counterintuitive interpretations" of the Eleventh Amendment, see 1 Laurence H. Tribe, American Constitutional Law 519-66 (3ded. 2000).
  • 176
    • 36549063753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, supra note 127, at 324
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Overruling and the Instability of Law, supra note 127, at 324.
  • 177
    • 36549013644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 426 U.S. 833, 850-52 (1976).
    • 426 U.S. 833, 850-52 (1976).
  • 178
    • 36549070644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 469 U.S. 528, 557 (1985).
    • 469 U.S. 528, 557 (1985).
  • 179
    • 36549053605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 469 U.S. at 580 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting);
    • See 469 U.S. at 580 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting);
  • 180
    • 36549045084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. at 589 (O'Connor, J., dissenting).
    • U.S. at 589 (O'Connor, J., dissenting).
  • 181
    • 36549059175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Printz v. United States, 521 U.S. 898, 925 (1997) ([T]he Federal Government may not compel the States to implement, by legislation or executive action, federal regulatory programs.).
    • Printz v. United States, 521 U.S. 898, 925 (1997) ("[T]he Federal Government may not compel the States to implement, by legislation or executive action, federal regulatory programs.").
  • 182
    • 36549078650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 60-62
    • See Gennaioli & Shleifer, Evolution of Common Law, supra note 127, at 60-62.
  • 183
    • 36549005044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 184
    • 36549073191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 185
    • 36549079584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 61-62
    • Id. at 61-62.
  • 186
    • 36549086031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Poe v. Ullmann, 367 U.S. 497, 543 (1961) (Harlan, J., dissenting) (discussing scope of liberty guaranteed by Due Process Clause of Constitution).
    • See, e.g., Poe v. Ullmann, 367 U.S. 497, 543 (1961) (Harlan, J., dissenting) (discussing scope of "liberty" guaranteed by Due Process Clause of Constitution).
  • 187
    • 36549057049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Frederick Schauer, Easy Cases, 58 S. Cal. L. Rev. 399, 407 (1985) (arguing that constitutional provisions that are rarely litigated are still important part of constitutional law).
    • Cf. Frederick Schauer, Easy Cases, 58 S. Cal. L. Rev. 399, 407 (1985) (arguing that constitutional provisions that are rarely litigated are still important part of constitutional law).
  • 188
    • 0036735373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Howard Gillman, How Political Parties Can Use the Courts to Advance Their Agendas: Federal Courts in the United States, 1875-1891, 96 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 511, 521 (2002) (describing Republican Party's successful efforts to entrench its policy agenda in courts during late nineteenth century).
    • See, e.g., Howard Gillman, How Political Parties Can Use the Courts to Advance Their Agendas: Federal Courts in the United States, 1875-1891, 96 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 511, 521 (2002) (describing Republican Party's successful efforts to entrench its policy agenda in courts during late nineteenth century).
  • 189
    • 33644880047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Keith E. Whittington, Interpose Your Friendly Hand: Political Supports for the Exercise of Judicial Review by the United States Supreme Court, 99 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 583, 591-93 (2005) (When faced with such issues, elected officials may actively seek to turn over controversial political questions to the courts so as to circumvent a paralyzed legislature and avoid the political fallout that would come with taking direct action themselves.).
    • See Keith E. Whittington, "Interpose Your Friendly Hand": Political Supports for the Exercise of Judicial Review by the United States Supreme Court, 99 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 583, 591-93 (2005) ("When faced with such issues, elected officials may actively seek to turn over controversial political questions to the courts so as to circumvent a paralyzed legislature and avoid the political fallout that would come with taking direct action themselves.").


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.